Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 5

The NEW ENGLA ND JOURNAL of MEDICINE

Perspective march 15, 2012

2 0 0 th Anniversary Ar ticle

Major Trends in the U.S. Health Economy since 1950


Victor R. Fuchs, Ph.D.

R apid advances in medical science and technology,


substantial gains in health outcomes attribut-
able to medical care, and budget-busting increases
of one 2-year pause in the mid-
1990s, when the effect of man-
aged care was at its peak1 (see
line graph). The absolute rate of
in health care expenditures fueled by private and growth has been increasing over
time, as evidenced by the con-
public insurance have marked and state governments and has cave shape of the curve in the
the past six decades of health resulted in stagnation of wages graph. The relative rate of in-
care in the United States. As the in most industries. In 1950, health crease was greater between 1950
country struggles to emerge from expenditures accounted for only and 1980 than between 1980 and
a multiyear financial and eco- 4.6% of the gross domestic prod- 2009 — 4.6% versus 4.1% per
nomic crisis, policymakers and uct (GDP). In 2009, they account- year — primarily because of the
the public have increasingly homed ed for more than 17%, a larger introduction of Medicare and Med-
in on those skyrocketing health share than all manufacturing, or icaid in 1965.
care expenditures. What lessons wholesale and retail trade, or fi- Unfortunately, the slight slow-
can be drawn from the evolu- nance and insurance, or the com- ing in the rate of growth of
tion, since 1950, in the sources bination of agriculture, mining, health expenditures since 1980
of payment and objects of expen- and construction. According to was accompanied by even greater
ditures in the health care arena? public finance experts such as slowing in the growth of the GDP
Alan Blinder and Alice Rivlin, (per capita adjusted for inflation),
He alth E xpenditures control of health care expendi- from 2.6% per year in 1950–1980
The rapid growth of health ex- tures is the greatest fiscal policy to 1.8% per year in 1980–2009.
penditures is one of the most im- challenge facing the United States. Thus, the gap between the rate
portant economic trends in the From 1950 through 2009, there of growth of health expenditures
United States in the post–World was an almost continuous increase and that of GDP increased from
War II era. It has implications for in annual real per capita health 2.0% to 2.3% per year between
the financial viability of federal expenditures, with the exception the two periods. Most experts be-

n engl j med 366;11  nejm.org  march 15, 2012 973


The New England Journal of Medicine
Downloaded from nejm.org on October 7, 2017. For personal use only. No other uses without permission.
Copyright © 2012 Massachusetts Medical Society. All rights reserved.
PERSPE C T I V E Major Trends in the U.S. Health Economy since 1950

ber who must pay payroll taxes.

Real Per Capita Expenditures (2009-adjusted U.S. $)


9,000 These increases have made tax-
8,000
exempt employer-based health
insurance more attractive. A shift
7,000 from individual to group insur-
6,000 ance has also contributed to the
5,000
spread of coverage by reducing
marketing and administrative
4,000
costs and, thanks to compulsory
3,000 participation within firms, limit-
2,000 ing the risk of adverse selection
for insurance companies.
1,000
The growth of government’s
0 share, and especially the federal
share, can be explained by the
19 0
19 3
19 6
19 9
19 2
19 5
19 8
19 1
19 4
19 7
19 0
19 3
19 6
19 9
19 2
19 5
20 8
20 1
20 4
07
5
5
5
5
6
6
6
7
7
7
8
8
8
8
9
9
9
0
0
19

public’s desire to cover more of


U.S. Per Capita Health Expenditures, 1950–2007. the public with insurance and pri-
vate insurers’ difficulty in provid-
lieve that such a gap is not sus- of care, because the content of a ing coverage for the elderly and
tainable over the long term, be- day in the hospital or a visit to the poor. Federal legislation also
cause health expenditures would a physician keeps changing. No substantially extended public cov-
cut too drastically into the avail- doubt some of the increase in ex- erage for children.
ability of other essential goods penditures reflects an increase in
and services. the quantity of medical care, if Objec t s of E xpenditures
The most important explana- quantity is adjusted for improve- Throughout the period since 1950,
tion for the increase in real per ments in the quality of care. health expenditures have gone pri-
capita health expenditures is the marily to hospitals, physicians,
availability of new medical tech- Sources of Payment and drugs. Moreover, the rate of
nology2 and the increased special- The sources of payment for med- growth of expenditures in each
ization that accompanies it. Be- ical care have changed signifi- of these categories between 1950
tween 1974 and 2010 alone, the cantly since 1950 (see table). The and 2009 has been fairly close to
number of U.S. patents for phar- most important trends have been the rate of growth of total health
maceutical and surgical innova- a decline in out-of-pocket payment expenditures (see bar graph). Drug
tions increased by a factor of six. and a rise in third-party payment expenditures may appear to have
Second in importance is the spread (both private and public), an in- grown more slowly, but that’s
of public and private health insur- crease in government’s share of probably due to a data mismatch:
ance, which diminishes the effect payment and a decrease in the the 1950 figure includes sundries,
of health care prices on demand.3 private share, and an increase in whereas the 1980 and 2009 fig-
There is a positive-feedback loop the federal government’s share as ures are for prescription drugs
between new technology and the compared with that of state and only. Such stability in the share
spread of health insurance: new local governments. of these categories is remarkable,
technology stimulates the demand Third-party payment has grown given the great changes that have
for insurance, and the spread of partly because of expensive inter- occurred in medical technologies,
insurance stimulates the demand ventions that expose individuals sources of payment, and health
for new technology.4 Finally, a to large financial risk and partly policy since 1950. As a rule of
small portion of the increase, typ- because employers’ contributions thumb, the ratio 3:2:1 does a
ically 0.1 or 0.2 percentage points to employee health insurance are fairly good job of describing the
per year, is attributable to the ag- not considered part of employ- relative importance (in dollar
ing of the population. It’s not pos- ees’ taxable income. Since World terms) of hospitals, physicians,
sible to estimate how much of the War II, there has been a large in- and drugs. The “other” expendi-
increase in expenditures reflects crease in the number of workers tures are divided among many
higher health care prices and how who must pay income tax and an categories, the most important of
much reflects greater quantities even greater increase in the num- which are public administration

974 n engl j med 366;11 nejm.org march 15, 2012

The New England Journal of Medicine


Downloaded from nejm.org on October 7, 2017. For personal use only. No other uses without permission.
Copyright © 2012 Massachusetts Medical Society. All rights reserved.
PERSPECTIVE Major Trends in the U.S. Health Economy since 1950

Communit y Hospital s
Personal Health Care Expenditures in the United States from 1950 through 2009.*
Community hospitals (including
Variable Year or Period academic medical centers), the re-
1950 1980 2009 cipients of the largest share of
Per capita expenditures (2009 dollars) 407 2,050 6,807 health expenditures, have seen
Source of payment (%) dramatic shifts in demand for
Out-of-pocket 56 27 14 and supply of inpatient care since
Third-party 44 73 86 1950. During the first three de­
Private or public (%)
cades of this period, the number
of inpatient days per 1000 popu-
Private 73 60 53
lation increased by more than a
Public 27 40 47
third, driven by Medicare and
Federal 13 26 35
Medicaid, the spread of employer-
State and local 14 14 12
based insurance, and lax utiliza-
1950–1980 1980–2009 1950–2009 tion controls by public and private
Average annual rate of change payers (see Table 1 in the Supple-
(% in 2009 dollars)
mentary Appendix, available with
Out-of-pocket 3.0 1.9 2.4
the full text of this article at
Third-party 7.1 4.7 5.9 NEJM.org). A slight decline in the
Private 4.7 3.7 4.2 average length of stay was more
Public 6.7 4.7 5.7 than offset by a 50% increase in
Federal 7.8 5.0 6.4 the number of admissions per
State and local 5.2 3.8 4.6 1000 population. The industry’s
31% increase in the number of
* The percentage of payments by the federal government was calculated on the basis of National beds per 1000 population, abet-
Health Care Expenditure data. Data are from the Department of Health and Human Services
and the U.S. Census Bureau. ted by consultants’ predictions of
ever-growing demand, proved to
be an expensive mistake. In the
and the net cost (premiums minus atric hospitals virtually emptied late 1960s and early 1970s, there
benefits paid) of private health out. Admission rates to acute care was mounting evidence that many
insurance, nursing homes, and hospitals (“community” hospitals) hospital admissions were ill-­
dental services. dropped precipitously after 1970, advised and that lengths of stay
There have been periods in the as did the average length of stay. for many patients were overly long
past 60 years when individual As a result, the average daily cen- (see the Supplementary Appendix).
categories accounted for greater sus, adjusted for population Between 1980 and 2009, the
or lesser proportions of expendi- growth, has decreased by almost number of inpatient days per
tures. Spending for hospital care 50% over the past four decades. 1000 population fell by almost
and physicians received a boost Hospitals have maintained and half, with declines in admissions
between 1950 and 1980 from the increased their revenues in part and average length of stay con-
introduction of Medicare and through more intensive treatment tributing almost equally. The de-
Medicaid. Spending for drugs ac- of inpatients. Despite shorter cline in length of stay was par-
celerated sharply after 1980 fol- stays, the cost per case (in 2009 ticularly spectacular in some major
lowing the introduction of a host dollars) jumped from $6,600 in categories of patients. For exam-
of new products for treating heart 1997 to $9,200 in 2009.5 Hos­ ple, stays for uncomplicated myo-
diseases, mental illness, gastroin- pitals’ total incomes were also cardial infarction dropped from
testinal disorders, and cancer and preserved through expansion of 3 weeks to 3 days; for uncompli-
a large increase in private and pub- outpatient services, including cated vaginal delivery, from 1 week
lic insurance coverage for drugs. same-day surgery, magnetic res- to 1 day; and for herniorrhaphy,
The ability of hospitals to onance imaging and computed from 6 days to same-day surgery.
maintain their high share is par- tomography, and outpatient clin- The average decrease among all
ticularly noteworthy, because be- ics for diagnosing and treating patients, however, was smaller
tween 1950 and 2009 the industry cancer, heart disease, and other than those for individual causes
had several large shocks. Psychi- illnesses. of admission, because the aver-

n engl j med 366;11  nejm.org  march 15, 2012 975


The New England Journal of Medicine
Downloaded from nejm.org on October 7, 2017. For personal use only. No other uses without permission.
Copyright © 2012 Massachusetts Medical Society. All rights reserved.
PERSPE C T I V E Major Trends in the U.S. Health Economy since 1950

who treat outpatients and others,


9,000
called hospitalists, who treat only
8,000 Hospital care inpatients. The number of hospi-
7,000 Physicians talists has grown rapidly, from
Per Capita Expenditures
(2009-adjusted U.S. $)
Drugs
6,000 no more than 1000 15 years ago
Other
5,000 to 7000 10 years ago to approxi-
4,000 mately 30,000 in 2011, according
3,000
to physician-economist David
Meltzer of the University of Chi-
2,000
cago. Hospitalists are said to im-
1,000
prove both the efficiency of care
0
1950 1980 2009
(mostly through reducing lengths
of stay) and its quality. Though
Per Capita Health Care Expenditures in 1950, 1980, and 2009, According to Category. primary care physicians initially
Data are from the U.S. Census Bureau. resisted this change in profession-
al responsibilities, many now pre-
age severity of patients’ conditions sponsibilities, female physicians fer the new system because they
on admission increased. The hos- tend to differ from their male perceive that hospital visits were
pital industry responded to the peers in preferences regarding not an efficient use of their time.
drop in demand by closing some annual hours of work, night cov- Another trend attracting wide
hospitals (net decrease of 18%) erage, self-employment, special- attention is the use of electronic
and closing off some beds as un- ty choice, and other aspects of medical records (EMRs) in physi-
available, but even so, the aver- practice. cians’ offices. Opinions vary re-
age occupancy rate fell by 10 per- The increase in the proportion garding the effects of EMRs on
centage points to the inefficient of physicians who are specialists the efficiency and quality of care.
level of 65.5%. and subspecialists has resulted in a I believe a well-organized health
considerable increase in the num- care system can benefit substan-
Physicians ber of years the average physician tially from EMRs, but the frag-
The number of active physicians spends in training, although a re- mented nonsystem of U.S. medical
in the United States increased by structuring of medical education care is not likely to derive enough
a factor of approximately four be- could change that.6 There has benefit to justify the cost.
tween 1950 and 2009 (see Table 2 been a large increase in the num- During this period, another
in the Supplementary Appendix). ber of specialists and an even larg- change that affected hospitals
As the population grew, the num- er increase in the number of spe- and physicians was the develop-
ber of active physicians per 1000 cialties and subspecialties, from ment of managed care. Until about
population increased from 1.41 a few dozen 50 years ago to more 1990, most insured patients could
to 2.73, an annual growth rate of than 150 now. choose freely among providers,
1.1%. That figure may overstate The shift away from office- physicians’ decisions were not sub-
the growth of physicians’ avail- based practice, along with possi- ject to frequent questions by in-
ability, however, since the num- ble changes in payment systems, surers, and payment was typically
ber of hours the average physi- may portend a time when most fee for service. The rapid growth
cian worked probably decreased medical care will be delivered by of health care expenditures in the
appreciably between 1950 and teams of physicians and other late 1980s, combined with slug-
2009. Major trends in the physi- health care providers (e.g., nurse gish growth of the GDP, fueled a
cian supply that had important practitioners and physician assis- demand for change.1 In the 1990s,
implications for the health econ- tants) working in accountable care insurers selectively contracted with
omy were large increases in the organizations. providers, fees and prices were
percentages of female physicians, negotiated in advance, physicians’
specialist physicians, and hospital- Changes in Organiz ation decisions became subject to insur-
based physicians. and Delivery ance-company review, and patients
Because women, even profes- An important recent trend affect- faced financial penalties for ob-
sional women, still bear a dispro- ing hospitals and physicians is a taining out-of-plan care. The effect
portionate share of domestic re- sharp division between physicians on health care expenditures was

976 n engl j med 366;11  nejm.org  march 15, 2012

The New England Journal of Medicine


Downloaded from nejm.org on October 7, 2017. For personal use only. No other uses without permission.
Copyright © 2012 Massachusetts Medical Society. All rights reserved.
PERSPECTIVE Major Trends in the U.S. Health Economy since 1950

dramatic: growth rates fell to 2% Pa s t and Future result of political gridlock regard-
per year by the mid-1990s. At the The six decades since 1950 have ing the form that curbs on expen-
same time, GDP growth acceler- been remarkable for the U.S. health ditures should take. There is no
ated to about 3% per year. Both economy in many ways, especial­ public consensus about how much
physicians and patients, however, ly the extraordinary increase in care should be provided for the
grew increasingly critical of man- health care expenditures. Future poor and sick or how it should
aged care. Physicians complained historians may, with some irony, be done. Similarly, there’s no pub-
about a squeeze on their incomes refer to this period as a golden lic consensus regarding efforts to
and interference with their auton- age for U.S. medicine because increase the efficiency of care.
omy. Patients resented restrictions health care’s share of the GDP A rational approach to the financ-
on their choice of providers and quadrupled from 4.6% in 1950 to ing, organization, and delivery of
worried that cuts in spending more than 17% in 2009; in most care seems politically impossible.
would necessarily result in a peer countries, the share is 9 to However, the observation by de
poorer quality of care. The com- 11%. Other noteworthy trends in Tocqueville that in the United
plaint by physicians and patients the health economy have been States “events can move from the
that health outcomes were ad- the spread of private and public impossible to the inevitable with-
versely affected by managed care, health insurance to the point out ever stopping at the proba-
fueled by many anecdotes, has where almost 90% of the total ble” may prove to be prescient.
not been supported by systematic bill for care is paid by third par- Disclosure forms provided by the author
evidence. ties; the increased role of the fed- are available with the full text of this arti-
The term “managed care” still eral government in funding health cle at NEJM.org.
carries negative connotations for care; the decline in inpatient use From Stanford University, Stanford, CA.
many observers, but as long as of hospitals (fewer admissions
concern about cost is strong, it’s and shorter stays) and the expan- 1. Fuchs VR. The future of managed care:
Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Re-
difficult to imagine a widespread sion of hospital outpatient ser- search policy brief. Stanford, CA: Stanford
call for unmanaged care. Stake- vices; the shift in the physician University, December 2000.
holders will disagree about who workforce toward more women, 2. Pauly MV. Competition and new technol-
ogy. Health Aff (Millwood) 2005;24:1523-35.
should do the managing, about more specialists, and more hos- 3. Newhouse JP. Free for all? Lessons from
the relative roles of regulation pital-based physicians; and the the RAND health insurance experiment. Cam-
and competition, and what form deluge of new medical technolo- bridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1993.
4. Weisbrod BA. The health care quadrilem-
competition should take. Per- gies confronting clinicians with a ma: an essay on technological change, insur-
haps the most important future menu of 6000 drugs and 4000 ance, quality of care, and cost containment.
trend, too nascent to quantify, procedures to choose from. J Econ Lit 1991;29:523-52.
5. Stranges E, Kowlessar N, Elixhauser A.
let alone evaluate, is the replace- It is difficult to see how the Components of growth in inpatient hospital
ment of the current system of health sector can continue to ex- costs, 1997-2009. Statistical brief no. 123.
organization and delivery with pand rapidly at the expense of the Rockville, MD: Agency for Health Care Re-
search and Quality, November 2011.
competition among large account- rest of the economy, but every past 6. Fuchs VR. Alan Gregg Lecture: The struc-
able care organizations serving prediction of a sustained slowing ture of medical education — it’s time for a
defined populations for risk-­ of the growth of health expendi- change. Presented at the Annual Meeting of
the American Association of Medical Col-
adjusted per capita annual pay- tures has been proved wrong. leges, Denver, November 6, 2011.
ments. Rapid growth may continue as a Copyright © 2012 Massachusetts Medical Society.

Supreme Court Review of the Health Care Reform Law


Gregory D. Curfman, M.D., Brendan S. Abel, B.A., and Renée M. Landers, J.D.

L ater this month, the U.S. Su-


preme Court will examine the
constitutionality of the Afford-
Court allocates 1 hour for oral
argument — 30 minutes for each
side. For the health care reform
more than 45 years. These argu-
ments will take place on March
26, 27, and 28 (see box), and the
able Care Act (ACA),1 potentially case, the Court has scheduled Court’s ruling will probably be
producing a landmark decision. 6 hours for oral argument — the announced in June.
For most cases, the Supreme most time devoted to a case in Setting the foundation for the

n engl j med 366;11  nejm.org  march 15, 2012 977


The New England Journal of Medicine
Downloaded from nejm.org on October 7, 2017. For personal use only. No other uses without permission.
Copyright © 2012 Massachusetts Medical Society. All rights reserved.

Вам также может понравиться