Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 17

World Development 111 (2018) 113–129

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

World Development
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev

Historical legacies of colonial indirect rule: Princely states and Maoist


insurgency in central India q
Shivaji Mukherjee
University of Toronto, Canada

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: What are the long term effects of colonial institutions on insurgency? The literature on civil wars has not
Accepted 13 June 2018 explored the historical legacies of colonial institutions for insurgency. I address this gap in the literature,
Available online 17 July 2018 by exploiting sub-national variation in the most important internal security threat in the world’s largest
democracy—the Maoist insurgency in India. Within India, I focus on the crucial case of the Maoist rebels
Keywords: in the tribal state of Chhattisgarh in central India which epitomizes the causal mechanism of indirect rule
Maoist insurgency through native princely states creating enclaves of weak state capacity, low development and tribal grie-
Indirect rule
vances due to natural resource exploitation. I test my theory on a new dataset at the sub district level
Colonial legacies
India
within Chhattisgarh, and use instrumental variable regression to address endogeneity due to selection
Bastar bias, combined with historical analysis and interview data to demonstrate path dependence. This study
Princely state demonstrates historical origins of weak state capacity and ethnic grievances due to natural resource
Chhattisgarh exploitation, which are important explanations for civil war onset. It also sets the agenda for further
research on other cases where colonial indirect rule creates conditions for insurgency, like the Taliban
in FATA in Pakistan, the ethnic insurgencies in Burma’s peripheries, and leftist insurgencies in Nepal,
Peru and Colombia.
Ó 2018 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction state penetration (Robinson, 2013). The type of land tenure system
created is partly the result of colonial institutions of direct/indirect
What is the long term effect of colonial institutions in creating rule, and could explain the level of sons of the soil land related con-
historical legacies that influence spatial variation in rebel control in flict in Africa (Boone, 2017). This article sets a new research agenda
insurgency? Why is it that the Taliban in Pakistan was more suc- by proposing that historical institutions are omitted factors that
cessful in areas of former British indirect rule in the FATA area of need to be taken seriously by the civil war literature to explain
NWFP, than in the British direct rule districts (Naseemullah, the persistence and recurrence of conflict.
2014)? Some of the secessionist insurgencies in India’s North East There are various reasons for taking historical institutions
like Mizoram, Nagaland, and Manipur can be traced back to discon- seriously for the study of civil war and insurgency. First, the civil
tent and identity formation emerging from indirect rule and war literature does not explain very well why sometimes there is
chieftaincy system set up by the British (Baruah, 2005). The leftist persistence and recurrence of conflict from colonial and pre-
FARC insurgency in Colombia occurs in areas of historically low colonial times in certain regions of countries. Dell (2010) finds that
districts in Peru which were part of the exploitative mita labor
system under the Spanish tend to have lower levels of public goods
q
I would like to thank the following for their comments and advise on this today, and Guardado (2016) shows that these districts with mita
project—Noel Anderson, Catherine Boone, Melani Cammett, Mario Chacon, Kanchan system also had more anti colonial rebellions and also more
Chandra, Thad Dunning, Aditya Dasgupta, Roberto Foa, Kishore Gawande, Guy
support for the Sendero Luminoso insurgency. Besley and Reynal-
Grossman, Ronald Herring, Devesh Kapur, Anirudh Krishna, Atul Kohli, Matthew
Lange, Alex Lee, Jason Lyall, James Mahoney, Jason Miklian, Anoop Sarbahi, Shankar Querol (2014) find persistence of conflict from pre-colonial times
Satyanath, Paul Staniland, Kenneth Scheve, Jake Shapiro, Jan Pierskalla, James in certain zones in Africa. Focusing on the role of historical institu-
Robinson, Manny Teitelbaum, Tariq Thachil, Ashutosh Varshney, Steven Wilkinson, tions and also past conflict allows us to analyze why certain con-
Joseph Wong, Elisabeth Wood, and two anonymous reviewers. I would also like to flicts recur in different time periods.
thank participants in the Comparative Politics Workshop at Yale university, 2013,
the Workshop on Maoist Insurgency at Princeton, February 2014, and Comparative
Also, there is potential omitted variable bias in different
Colonialisms Workshop at OSU, April 2016. All errors remain my own. quantitative models of civil war onset using cross national
E-mail address: shivaji.mukherjee@utoronto.ca datasets, since some omitted factors like institutional quality

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2018.06.013
0305-750X/Ó 2018 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
114 S. Mukherjee / World Development 111 (2018) 113–129

may be driving both economic/ethnic outcomes, as well as conflict In the rest of the paper, I first engage with complementary and
(Miguel, Satyanath and Sergenti (2004: 726). Colonial institutions alternate explanations for Maoist insurgency in India. I then out-
are one such potential omitted variable that influence both the line theory and mechanisms through which colonial indirect rule
sub-national variation in proximate levels of state capacity and sets up the structural conditions for Maoist insurgency. I then dis-
ethnic exclusion, and also the chances of conflict (Acemoglu, cuss the history of indirect rule and its effects on the Maoist move-
Johnson, & Robinson, 2001), so including them in models of civil ment in Chhattisgarh. Finally, I present IV-2SLS analysis to show
war will partly reduce such omitted variable bias. that princely state has a positive correlation with Maoist control,
Another analytical advantage of bringing historical institutions even after addressing selection effects, and conclude by discussing
back into the study of insurgencies is that the cross-national liter- generalizability of the theory.
ature on civil war does not address well the issue of endogeneity of
socio-economic factors to the process of conflict (Hegre and
Sambanis (2006: 513-514). By analyzing the effects of historical 2. Complementary and rival explanations for Maoist insurgency
institutions which are causally and temporally prior to current
conflict dynamics, and using an instrument for such historical 2.1. Complementary explanations for Maoist insurgency
institutions to address possible selection bias, my study addresses
such endogeneity issues.1 There are several excellent emerging studies of India’s Maoist
Given the dearth of research on this less understood link insurgency using district level econometric analyses. Gawande,
between colonial institutions and their long term effects on insur- Kapur and Satyanath (2017) and Vanden Eynde (2017) explain
gency, it would be profitable to focus on one type of colonial insti- variation in patterns of Maoist and state violence by focusing on
tution and carefully study its effect on some important cases of how rainfall shocks change forest cover and have an adverse effect
insurgency using fine-grained sub-national data, before extending on opportunity costs to rebel recruitment. Dasgupta, Gawande and
the analysis to a cross-national level.2 A particularly fruitful direc- Kapur (2017) analyze the effects of government employment
tion of research would be to analyze the colonial institution of indi- programs like the National Rural Employment Guarantee
rect rule, which is an important colonial institution with long term Scheme (NREGS) on Maoist recruitment, and find that it reduces
effects. Studies like Lange (2009); Mahoney (2010); Kohli (2004); violence in strong states like Andhra Pradesh and Chhattisgarh
Mamdani (1996) analyze the effects of colonial indirect rule on devel- by reducing opportunity costs and grievances of unemployed
opment, state capacity, and ethnic genocide, but not on insurgency. youth. Gomes (2015) finds that districts with landlord tenure also
I fill this gap by exploring the effects of colonial indirect rule on tend to have more Maoist conflict, building on Banerjee and Iyer
the most important internal security threat in the world’s largest (2005)’s theory, and also that districts with more land inequality,
democracy—the Maoist insurgency in India.3 I focus on the crucial forest cover, and scheduled castes (SCs) and scheduled tribes
case (Gerring, 2007) of the Maoists in the tribal state of Chhattisgarh (STs) create conditions for Maoist insurgency. Echoing these find-
in central India where formal indirect rule through princely states ings, Hoelscher, Miklian, and Vadlamannati (2012) find that min-
created weak state capacity and natural resource extraction and con- ing, scheduled castes/tribes, and NREGS all have an effect on
flict (Sundar, 2007). While indirect rule through princely states was Maoist violence.
abolished following Indian independence in 1947, the effects of My article makes several contributions which make it distinct
these institutions in the forms of weak state capacity, extraction of from the micro-econometrics literature on India’s Maoist insur-
natural resources, and rebellious tribes excluded from the process gency (Gawande et al., 2017; Dasgupta et al., 2017; Vanden
of modern nation-state formation, persisted through path dependent Eynde, 2017; Gomes, 2015; Hoelscher et al., 2012; Chandra &
processes into the 1980s in these areas in central India. These histor- Garcia-Ponce, 2014). First, while these studies use Maoist violence
ically created state weakness and tribal grievances were exploited by as their dependent variable, my paper uses a different dependent
the People’s War Group (PWG) Maoists, paving the way for very high variable of Maoist control measured using novel data from State
levels of Maoist rebel control in these areas by late 1990s. Election Commission.5 Second, my theory focuses on how colonial
I combine quantitative analysis of an original dataset at the sub indirect rule creates structural constraints for rebel leaders before
district level within Chhattisgarh, with qualitative analysis show- the insurgency suddenly expands following unification of the PWG
ing path dependence, to demonstrate how historical institutions and MCC factions in 2004, and is distinct from these studies which
create current levels of state capacity, and ethnic inequalities in explain violence in the latter phase of insurgency (2005–2012).
central India. While my larger project presents historical evidence Third, most of these recent studies of Maoist insurgency use district
for process tracing and path dependence of mechanisms, this arti- level datasets. In contrast, I develop a sub-district Assembly Con-
cle focuses on addressing selection bias by using an instrument for stituency (AC) level dataset for the state of Chhattisgarh, which is
the British choice of indirect rule through princely state. This also the first such micro level dataset.
addresses the issue of endogeneity of more proximate factors like My paper is also complementary to these other studies which
state capacity, tribal grievances, to ongoing conflict which affects analyze the effects of proximate opportunity factors like forest
other econometric studies of Maoist insurgency, and moves cover, lower caste and tribal grievances, ethnic parties, land
beyond correlations to search for long term causal effects of histor- inequalities and NREGS on levels and patterns of violence. In con-
ical institutions on insurgency.4 trast, my study analyzes the omitted variable of colonial indirect
rule which created structural conditions that enabled Maoists to
1
mobilize more successfully in areas of former indirect rule. Once
Wucherpfennig et al. (2015) similarly address the criticism that ethnic exclusion
the British chose colonial institutions of indirect rule for particular
is affected by reverse causality from conflict, by developing an instrument based on
the different types of relations with indigenous elites used by the British and French areas, these institutions had an independent effect on probability
colonial rule. of leftist insurgency, beyond that created by proximate opportu-
2
A few studies like Lange & Dawson (2009) have developed broad measures of nity structures like forest cover and hilly terrain. Colonial indirect
colonial institutions to show its effect on rebellion using cross-national analysis.
3
rule created tribal grievance due to natural resource extraction,
The ex-Indian Prime Minister, Manhoman Singh, called it India’s ‘‘number one
internal security threat” in 2006.
4 5
The other study on Maoists addressing endogeneity is Gawande et al. (2017) This data is not publicly available and was collected through field-trips to the
which uses rainfall variation as an instrument for changes in forest cover and State Election Commission, and also by filing official requests through the Right to
therefore employment in these forested Maoist affected areas of India. Information Act (RTIs), and represents new data.
S. Mukherjee / World Development 111 (2018) 113–129 115

lower levels of state capacity and public good distribution, which is variation between different types of princely states, as recent
then became the intermediating mechanisms that are exploited studies by Foa (2016) and Lee (2017) propose.8 In this paper, move
later by Maoist rebels. So colonial indirect rule in conjunction with in the direction of disaggregating the concept of indirect rule by first
these more proximate factors explains spatial variation in Maoist pointing out two different types of indirect rule broadly within India,
control. and secondly by analyzing the feudatory princely states in Chhattis-
garh which allows us a glimpse into this diversity of princely state
types.
2.2. Addressing rival explanations based on colonial institutions
3. Variation in colonial indirect rule in India and historical
A working paper by Teitelbaum and Verghese (2016) suggests
legacies for Maoist insurgency
that districts under former colonial direct rule have more Maoist
insurgency in India. Verghese (2016a,b) analyzes the Bastar prin-
In his classic study of the effects of colonialism on development,
cely state which he interprets as British direct rule and has Maoist
Mahoney (2010) suggests that were 4 types of British colonial
insurgency. These papers suffer from several empirical and theo-
rule – (1) settlement, (2) indirect, (3) direct, and (4) hybrid. While
retical problems.
most African countries like Nigeria, Uganda, Sierra Leone were low
First, Teitelbaum and Verghese (2016) cannot explain why the
population density and almost fully indirect rule, the largest British
People’s War Group (PWG) Maoists were successful in creating
colony of India had higher population density with complex pre-
some of the strongest core areas of guerilla zones in the southern
colonial institutions and was in the hybrid category, since it had
epicenter of the insurgency in former princely state (indirect rule)
a mix of direct and indirect rule within its territory. Lange (2009)
areas of Hyderabad (Telangana) in Andhra Pradesh, and Bastar/
notes that while the British colonizers chose direct rule in certain
Kanker states in Chhattisgarh and former feudatory states in
areas of India where they set up their own institutions of revenue
Orissa.6 Verghese’s (2016a,b) suggestion that Bastar princely state
collection, administration, and laws, in other areas they chose to
was direct rule because the British intervened often is not satisfac-
rule indirectly through pre-existing native rulers called princes,
tory, since that was the case with most princely states where the Bri-
nizams, or rajas, and this resulted in official (de jure) colonial
tish used the Residency system to control and intervene (Fisher,
indirect rule through princely or native states.
1991). This does not imply that these are direct rule like in Madras
I build on the suggestion of Mahoney (2010), Gerring et al.
and Bombay presidency where the British used their own bureau-
(2011: 378), and Wilkinson (2017) to think of direct vs. indirect
cracy, police, and judiciary, and allowed provincial elections since
rule as a non-dichotomous category. To explain both the northern
1920s (Tudor, 2013).
and southern epicenters of the Maoist insurgency which studies
The second empirical problem with the Teitelbaum and
like Verghese (2016a,b), Teitelbaum and Verghese (2016) fail to
Verghese (2016) paper is that there is relatively higher develop-
do, in a different paper I propose that there were two different
ment and no Maoist insurgency in the western and southern states
forms of indirect rule within India, which coincided with the two
of Maharashtra, Tamil Nadu which were formerly colonial direct
epicenters of Maoist insurgency in India, and created separate cau-
rule with ryotwari land tenure systems in Bombay and Madras
sal pathways leading to insurgency.9
presidency respectively, which contradicts the paper’s prediction.
A third conceptual problem is that Teitelbaum and Verghese
(2016) and Verghese (2016a,b) interpret the zamindari landlord 3.1. Type 1: Informal (de facto) indirect rule/indirect revenue collection
tenure in the northern epicenter of the Maoist insurgency in Ben- through zamindari land tenure system
gal/Bihar/Jharkhand zone as British direct rule.7 This interpretation
is incorrect because it was the British indirect revenue collection sys- One causal pathway coincides with the northern districts of
tems through landlords or zamindars used in Bengal/Bihar/Jharkhand Bihar/Bengal/Jharkhand, where the British used an informal or de
that created land and caste inequalities and led to Maoist insurgency. facto form of indirect rule or revenue collection (Kohli, 2004;
Kohli (2004: 225–26), Dirks (2001), Lange (2009) and Mahoney (2010) Lange, 2009; Mahoney, 2010), by depending on upper caste land-
acknowledge the zamindari tenure system in Bengal/Bihar as another lords, called zamindars or malguzars, to collect land revenue on
shade of indirect rule, in which the overburdened colonial state their behalf. While officially part of direct rule, zamindari and other
depended on native intermediaries to collect land revenues on their such landlord or intermediary based land revenue systems were de
behalf, instead of collecting it directly as in the ryotwari (non landlord) facto indirect rule or revenue collection, since revenue was not col-
tenure system in Bombay and Madras. In contrast, areas in Bombay or lected directly through British officials, but indirectly through
Madras provinces in the south-west of India, where the British used landlords (Lange, 2009; Dirks, 2001; Kohli, 2004: 225–26). This
direct and equitable ryotwari land tenure system which were truly resulted in land/caste inequality which persisted and created
direct rule and direct revenue collection, did not see tribal/peasant structural conditions for Maoist insurgency in the northern
rebellions in colonial or post-colonial times. Bihar-Jharkhand epicenter (Gomes, 2015; Banerjee & Iyer, 2005).
Summarizing, there are two problems with these studies. The
first is that they treat indirect rule vs. direct rule as a dichotomous 3.2. Type 2: Formal (de jure) indirect rule through princely states
category, when in reality, as Lange (2009), Mahoney (2010),
Gerring, Daniel, Van Gorp, and Julian (2011) and Wilkinson The second causal pathway to Maoist insurgency in India, which
(2017) have suggested it is a more continuous category and there is the focus of this paper, coincides with the southern epicenter
are different types of indirect rule. Second, they assume all princely near Chhattisgarh-Andhra Pradesh-Orissa, where there was formal
states as uniformly having benevolent rulers, when in reality there or de jure colonial indirect rule through various princely states,
which were allowed substantial autonomy in the sphere of admin-
6
Similarly, Verghese (2016, p. 1623, footnote 9) mentions ‘‘Bastar is not the only
8
former princely state that experiences tribal conflict – the Naxalites are also active in Foa (2016) develops a typology of indirect rule and pre-colonial states in South
Orissa and Telangana”, but does not have an explanation for why these areas of Asia. Lee (2017) also makes this point of outsider rulers not being benevolent towards
former indirect rule through princely states, had and continue to have tribal rebellion. subjects.
7 9
Verghese (2016: 1621) notes that these ‘‘tribal conflicts continued to occur . . . Mukherjee (2018). ‘‘Colonial Origins of Maoist Insurgency in India: Historical
especially in former areas of direct British rule (emphasis mine) like Bengal, Bihar, and Institutions and Civil War”, Journal of Conflict Resolution, published online September
Jharkhand”. 2017 at http://journals.sagepub.com/doi/full/10.1177/0022002717727818.
116 S. Mukherjee / World Development 111 (2018) 113–129

istration, taxation, land revenue and law, while keeping foreign and natural resources from Gond tribes, which created grievances
policy under the direct control of the colonial administration that were exploited by Maoist rebels to create zones of rebel control
(Fisher, 1991; Lee-Warner, 1910). in the heart of India (Sundar, 2007). In Chhattisgarh, the insurgency
occurred in the districts which were part of the princely states of
There are several mechanisms created by colonial indirect rule which Kanker and Bastar in the south and Surguja, Koriya, Changbhakar,
could shape structural conditions for rebellion Udaipur, and Jashpur in the north. The central districts of Raipur,
Bilaspur, were annexed in 1854 into British direct ruled Central
First, colonial indirect rule through princely states tended to pro- Provinces, and do not have insurgency (See Fig. 1B below).
duce lower levels of development, weaker bureaucratic and police I briefly outline the two mechanisms:
capacity (Acemoglu et al., 2001; Kohli, 2004; Lange, 2009).10 Sec-
ond, as Mahoney (2010, p. 240) notes, ‘‘In the indirectly ruled areas, (1) Indirect rule created low state capacity and development
the British actively protected oppressive local elites, who otherwise
likely would have faced major rebellion from the rural producers Using indirect rule allowed the British to avoid governing these
they exploited. . ..” and this allowed despotic extraction of natural areas which had different Gond tribal groups in the Dandakaranya
resources, revenue, and labor from peasants and tribals (Boone, forests in south Chhattisgarh, who preferred to maintain their own
1994; Boone, 2013; Mamdani, 1996), which would not have been indigenous customs and institutions, and had historically been
possible in areas of British direct rule. resistant to centralized state-formation, similar to Scott’s (2009)
zomia lands in South East Asia.12 The renowned human rights acti-
Further variation within formal indirect rule vist, K. Balagopal, mentioned this decision by the British to avoid
using direct rule in this area: ‘‘ . . . Abujhmarh in Chhattisgarh area
It is difficult to generalize across such a large variation in size . . . was experimentally allowed to be ungoverned, and unsurveyed
and type of princely states, and there is further heterogeneity also. . . . And the neighboring areas of today’s Kanker, Bastar and
between princely states. Building on Ramusack (2004), Foa Dantewada are so backward that administering was possible by
(2016) suggests that the tributary/feudatory states in Orissa, and the Maoists . . . ”13
Chhattisgarh areas often had outsider Rajput princes who were This effect of British indirect rule can be seen from the fact that
protected by the British and tended to be extractive. This was in at the time of independence of India from British rule in 1947, the
contrast to warrior states like Travancore and Mysore which were southern region of Bastar and the northern region of Surguja prin-
ruled by kings of same ethnicity/region who challenged the British cely states in Chhattisgarh areas were really low state penetration,
and Dutch, built armies and bureaucracies, provided more public and low levels of governance and public goods, while the central
goods to their subjects. Also, there were the successor states of regions of Bilaspur and Raipur districts which had been part of
Hyderabad and Bengal which had Muslim rulers who were for- direct colonial rule as Central provinces was much higher state
merly vassals of the Mughal emperor, but later became suzereign penetration. Fig. 1A from the Census of India (1951) shows that
rulers, and were also despotic. the spread of railway lines and electricity stations soon after India’s
In this paper, I focus on the feudatory princely states of Bastar, independence in Madhya Pradesh state which was earlier Central
Kanker, in Chhattisgarh, which exemplify the mechanisms of lower Provinces. It can be compared with the historical map of colonial
state capacity and development (Lange, 2009; Kohli, 2004; districts and princely states of Central Provinces in Fig. 1B to show
Mahoney, 2010), as well as land and natural resource exploitation that railway and electricity stations were lowest in the highly
from their ancient tribal lands (Boone, 1994, 2017; Mamdani, backward areas of Bastar and Surguja princely state areas in the
1996; Banerjee & Iyer, 2005). south and north respectively of the eastern part of Madhya Pra-
desh, which later became Chhattisgarh state.
Further evidence for the long term difference in effects of direct
4. Colonial indirect rule and Maoist insurgency in Chhattisgarh
vs. indirect rule comes in Tables 1A & 1B below, which shows that
the constituencies that were part of direct rule tend to have more
4.1. Case selection – the crucial pathway case of Chhattisgarh for
roads and bus facilities, and more schools, water tanks and tube-
testing this theory
wells, and more access to electricity, which are all crucial public
goods (2001 Census data).
I test the larger theory of different types of indirect rule using an
all-India district dataset based analysis in a different paper
(2) Indirect rule caused exploitation of forest and natural resources
(Mukherjee, 2018). Nested within this broader all India district
from tribes
level analysis (Lieberman, 2005), in this paper I focus on the prin-
cely states in Chhattisgarh, as a crucial pathway case (Gerring, 2007)
One of the main interests of the British colonial state was the
to trace the less studied causal pathway of how the more formal
rich natural resources in the Bastar region, and indirect rule
type of indirect rule through princely states can create weak state
through the prince and local landlords would allow the colonial
capacity (Fearon & Laitin, 2003), and land and natural resource
state to get these revenues on the cheap. The British introduced
extraction (Boone, 1994).11
the Forest Act, 1878, which gave the state the right to reserved for-
ests and prevented the original sons of the soil tribes living in these
4.2. Legacies of colonial indirect rule in Chhattisgarh areas the right to access to minor forest products which they had
historically used for their livelihood.14 Sundar (2007: 114) men-
Formal indirect rule through the feudatory princely states in tions that while the official reason for reserving almost two-thirds
Chhattisgarh created weak state capacity, and exploitation of land of the total forest areas of the state was to ‘‘conserve commercially

10
In contrast, Iyer (2010) suggests indirect rule produces better developmental
12
outcomes in India, though her IV2SLS analysis using an all India dataset has flaws, There were tribal rebellions against the British in earlier periods, for example the
which I explain below. Bhumkal rebellion of 1910 under the leadership of Gunda Dhar (Sundar, 2007).
11 13
The indirect revenue collection system through zamindars in the northern Interview with K. Balagopal, Hyderabad, February 8, 2008.
14
epicenter in Bihar/ Bengal, have been more studied (Bhatia, 2005, Banerjee & Iyer, Ramachandra Guha (1983). ‘‘Forestry in British and Post-British India: A
2005). Historical Analysis.” Economic and Political Weekly 18: 45/46.
S. Mukherjee / World Development 111 (2018) 113–129 117

Fig. 1A. Map showing road, railway, and electricity generating stations in Madhya Pradesh (earlier Central Provinces) in 1951. Source: Census of India, 1951, Volume VII,
Madhya Pradesh, Part 1-A Report. Nagpur, Government Printing, 1953.

Fig. 1B. Map of Princely states and British direct rule in Central Provinces: princely states are colored yellow, while British direct rule districts are colored pink. Source: The
Imperial Gazetteer of India: Volume 26—Atlas, Plate 39. 1909. Available at Digital South Asia Library, U Chicago, http://dsal.uchicago.edu/reference/gaz_atlas_1909/fullscreen.
html?object=45 . Also at http://enacademic.com/pictures/enwiki/73/IGI1908CPandBerar2.jpg. (For interpretation of the references to colour in this figure legend, the reader is
referred to the web version of this article.)

valuable forests before they were destroyed”, the real purpose Besides timber, there was also attempts by various companies
behind forest reservation was revenue generation, and exporting to prospect for and find iron ore and other mineral resources in
timber for meeting needs of adjoining states and British districts. the Bastar area. One of the major companies which started looking
118 S. Mukherjee / World Development 111 (2018) 113–129

Table 1A
Summary statistics and difference in means by princely state.

Variable No. of constituencies Mean Difference in Means (s.e)


Total British Empire princely States Total British Empire Princely States (British Empire)-(princely State)
Maoist Rebel Control
% High Sensitive 90 52 38 10.66 2.17 22.26 20.09*** (3.30)
Polling Stations
Geography
Forest Cover % 90 52 38 30.83 19.18 45.68 25.70*** (5.52)
Elevation (meters) 90 52 38 389.52 318.49 486.71 168.22*** (24.83)
Demography
Scheduled Caste% 90 52 38 11.88 15.51 6.93 8.58*** (1.34)
Scheduled Tribe% 90 52 38 33.24 20.03 51.31 31.28*** (4.03)
Population Density 90 52 38 293.93 366.47 194.69 171.78*** (50.73)
Rural % 90 52 38 84.70 81.48 89.12 7.64 (4.83)
Socio-Economic
Total Literacy 90 52 38 63.622 67.33 58.55 8.77*** (2.39)
Male Literacy 90 52 38 76.65 81.21 70.41 10.79*** (2.19)
Female Literacy 90 52 38 50.61 53.46 46.69 6.77** (2.65)
Male Unemployment 90 52 38 56.88 59.44 53.38 6.07*** (0.79)
Per Capita Income 90 52 38 603.29 747.55 405.89 341.66 (493.32)
State Capacity
Post Office 90 52 38 0.18 0.19 0.15 0.04** (0.02)
Dist from Town (km) 90 52 38 31.36 22.58 43.39 20.81*** (4.69)
Paved Road 90 52 38 0.36 0.41 0.30 0.11*** (0.04)
Railway Facility 90 52 38 0.007 0.008 0.005 0.003 (0.002)
Bus Facility 90 52 38 0.17 0.19 0.15 0.04** (0.02)
Education
Middle School 90 52 38 0.29 0.31 0.26 0.05** (0.02)
Secondary School 90 52 38 0.09 0.11 0.07 0.04*** (0.01)
Water
Tanks 90 52 38 0.384 0.518 0.202 0.316*** (0.094)
Tubewells 90 52 38 0.306 0.465 0.087 0.377*** (0.102)
Power
Electricity 90 52 38 0.344 0.408 0.256 0.152*** (0.043)

Source: All public goods and demography data from Census of India 2001.
*
p < 0.10, **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01. Standard Errors in parentheses.

Table 1B
OLS estimates of impact of colonial institutions on development and state capacity.
Dependent Variable: Various measures of development and state capacity.

Development and public good measures State capacity measures


Model 1A – Model 1B – Model 1C – Model 1D – Model 2A – Model 2B – Model 2C – Dist. Model 2D –
Male Literacy Electricity Tubewells Middle Schools Paved Road Post Office from Town Railway Station
Princely State 10.80** 0.152** 0.377* 0.0511** 0.105** 0.0432* 20.81*** 0.00308
(0.029) (0.013) (0.081) (0.049) (0.046) (0.093) (0.006) (0.202)
Constant 81.21*** 0.408*** 0.465** 0.310*** 0.408*** 0.198*** 22.58*** 0.00853***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.031) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
Observations 90 90 90 90 90 90 90 90
R2 0.216 0.122 0.135 0.048 0.088 0.060 0.182 0.022
Adjusted R2 0.207 0.112 0.125 0.037 0.078 0.049 0.173 0.011

p-values in parentheses. *p < 0.10, **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01.
Robust Std. Errors adjusted for 17 clusters by district.

and mining for iron ore deposits was Tata Sons who got the first of bauxite and iron ore found in this area, and so the foundation for
mining lease to prospect for minerals and iron ore in the area its extraction were already laid in the colonial period.
around 1916.15 There was no railway tracks linking the Bastar
region, and the iron ore deposits were inaccessible, but since it ‘‘pro- 4.3. Persistence of the effects of these institutions into post-colonial
vides some revenue for the Bastar state in license fees”, the Depart- times
ment of Industry and Labor continued to renew the prospecting lease
for the Tatas in 1920–30s.16 In the 1960s, there were large deposits Following India’s independence in 1947, the princely states and
zamindars were officially abolished by the 1950s. However, due to
path dependence of the effects of these institutions, low state pene-
15
‘‘Grant of prospecting license to the Tata Iron and Steel Company Limited, to tration and extraction of rich iron ore resources in these areas con-
prospect for iron ore in the Bastar State.” NAI, Foreign and Political Department,
tinued. As a consequence, the northern and southern parts of
Branch Internal-B, Progs. January 1917, Nos. 126.
16
‘‘Renewal of the prospecting license for iron ore in the Bastar State to Messrs. Tata
Chhattisgarh, which were former princely states, remained areas of
Sons, Limited, Bombay for a period of one year” NAI, Foreign and Political Department, low levels of development, with continuing exploitation of natural
Reforms Branch, File No. 281-R/1932. resources.
S. Mukherjee / World Development 111 (2018) 113–129 119

Path dependent mechanism 1: areas treated as administrative


backwaters
One mechanism through which the low levels of colonial bureau-
cratic and police capacity continued into post-colonial times, was
because these areas are still considered ‘punishment postings’ to
which poor quality officers, or those being punished for their recal-
citrant political positions were sent by politicians.17 According to a
police officer who works in Maoist affected south Chhattisgarh:
‘‘. . .in a batch of ASIs, those who are the toppers in the batch or best
officers, . . . are not sent to the Naxal areas, the others who are not
the best officers are sent.”18 Such interviews suggested that the colo-
nial policy of treating these areas as administrative backwaters was
continued by the Indian bureaucracy and police.19

Path dependent mechanism 2: continuation of resource exploitation


creating grievances
Fig. 2. Annual fatalities from Maoist insurgency in Chhattisgarh: 1990–2008.
Following independence, the princes and zamindars were abol-
Source: Data from 1990 to 99 is from Madhya Pradesh police records and from 2000
ished, and there was a Congress Party government in the state of to 08 is from Chhattisgarh police records.
Madhya Pradesh for most of the 1950–80s period. However, much
like the colonial state, there has been a continuing interest of the forest and natural resources. These Maoist rebels started addressing
post-colonial Indian state in these peripheral areas to exploit the these grievances of these tribals, and started recruiting and
rich deposits of bauxite and iron ore in southern Chhattisgarh, thus mobilizing them to form rebel groups.26
showing another continuity in state policy (Kennedy & Once the PWG settled into the area of Bastar/Kanker in South
Purushotham, 2012: 840). This extraction occurred through the Chhattisgarh in 1980–90s, they started the Dandakaranya Adivasi
National Mineral Development Corporation since the 1960s, and Kisan Majdoor Sangh (DAKMS) or the Tribal peasant and workers
more recently through MNCs like Essar in the Kirandul/Bacheli association, and the Krantikari Adivasi Mahila Sangh (KAMS) or
area in Dantewada district, without building adequate roads and the Revolutionary tribal women’s association, through which they
providing sufficient development.20 These iron ore plants near recruited the adivasi tribals.27 An important contribution of the
Kirandul release a lot of pollution and negatively affect health out- Maoists was to force the government and contractors to increase
comes of neighboring villages.21 Human rights activists note that the price that the tribals received for picking tendu leaves. This was
the controversial Salwa Judum vigilante movement was used to an important form of livelihood, and the PWG Maoists pressurized
make land easily available for mining projects by private companies the traders and the government to increase the wages, else threat-
who were interested in the rich iron ore resources in the Dantewada ened labor strikes. While for over two decades, ‘‘the wages remained
area.22 at 3 paise to 8 paise per gaddi (a bundle of 50 leaves)” . . . from about
Another continuing form of exploitation is in minor forest prod- ‘‘1982 it has risen dramatically to 30 paise in 1988, while the rest of
ucts like tendu leaves which is used to make local cigarettes or the state remained at 9 paise.”28
bidis, and which has a very strong lobby of contractors and traders By 1990s, the PWG succeeded in developing rebel control deep
with a lot of influence on the state politicians. The tribals were paid inside the Abujhmarh forest areas of former Bastar princely state
really low wages for picking tendu leaves and delivering them to in the south of Chhattisgarh, by exploiting these historically cre-
the non tribal contractors (PUCL, p. 13).23 ated structural conditions of weak state capacity and ethnic grie-
vances. Except for a few short escalations in the 1990s, violence
4.4. Maoist rebel agents exploit these structural conditions of weak remained low in this area which had become a Maoist stronghold.
state capacity and inequality It was only when there was sudden escalation of violence in 2005
due to the emergence of an anti-Maoist vigilante movement called
I briefly mention the history of the Maoists in southern the Salwa Judum, led by the Congress leader Mahendra Karma, that
Chhattisgarh here.24 The People’s War Group (PWG) Maoists the central government took notice of the Maoists in this corner of
emerged under the leadership of K. Sitaramaiah in Telangana region India. The center launched a counter insurgency operation called
of Andhra Pradesh in 1980. In early 1980s, some PWG squads from Green Hunt in 2009 with the goal of eliminating Maoist power in
Andhra Pradesh crossed the state border into Dandakaranya forest their core areas of Maoist control, but this was not fully successful
zone in south Chhattisgarh area.25 They found areas of deep forests (see Fig. 2 for violence patterns).
and Gond tribes with grievances due to exploitation of their
4.5. Scope conditions: timing of onset of insurgency, and theory not
17
Interview with Superintendent of Police, (district not revealed), Chhattisgarh, applicable to post 2004 period
2009.
18
Interview with Deputy Superintendent of Police, (district not revealed), Chhat-
Historical institutions like colonial indirect rule do not explain
tisgarh, 2009.
19
Miklian (2009: 443-44) mentions that Chhattisgarh police ‘‘lags far behind other
the timing of onset of insurgency, but only explain the spatial vari-
Indian states in both quantitative and qualitative terms”, and most policemen view ation in rebel control after insurgency emerges. The timing of emer-
Chhattisgarh positions as bad for their career. gence of the Maoists in Chhattisgarh was related to the ideological
20
Interview with human rights activist Dr. Binayak Sen, Raipur, Chhattisgarh, 2008. and strategic re-thinking within the broader radical leftist move-
21
Focus group discussion with villagers, Village X (pseudonym), near Kirandul
ment in India in 1977–80 (Sinha, 1989), which led to emergence
town, Dantewada district, 2009.
22
Interview with PUCL activist Y (pseudonym), Bhilai, Chhattisgarh, 2009. Also see
26
PUCL, Where the State Makes War on its Own people, p. 7–8. P. Shankar (2006), p. 222–226; PUCL, Bastar: Development and Democracy, July
23
(PUCL, p. 13). 1989, p. 13.
24 27
For a longer description, see Online Appendix H. P. Shankar (2006), p. 222–226; PUCL, Bastar: Development and Democracy, July
25
Dandakaranya Special Zonal Committee, CPI-Maoist. 2005. Jan Jagran Nahi, Jan 1989, p. 13.
28
Daman Abhiyan, p. 6. PUCL, Bastar: Development and Democracy, 1989, p.10.
120 S. Mukherjee / World Development 111 (2018) 113–129

of the PWG in Telangana region of former princely state of Hyder- without a male heir, and was for reasons exogenous to the quality of
abad in the neighboring state of Andhra Pradesh in 1980, and a the districts within Nagpur state. The central districts of current day
strategic decision by the PWG leadership to expand to neighboring Chhattisgarh—Raipur, Bilaspur, Durg, Dhamtari and Mahasamund—
Bastar region of Chhattisgarh in 1980s.29 were part of Nagpur state in 1854, when they formed only two large
Also, colonial institutional legacies may not be useful to explain districts of Raipur and Bilaspur. Since the reason for the switch of
rapid expansion of insurgency once a rebel organization develops these districts to colonial direct rule were due to random circum-
sufficient strength to be able to expand even to areas of higher stances of the natural death of the ruler of Nagpur state, and were
state capacity. So this theory can only explain spatial variation in exogenous to the quality of these districts which could make them
rebel control before the unification of the two most powerful Mao- more prone to rebellion then or in the future, therefore it is used
ist groups, the MCC and PWG, to form CPI-Maoist in 2004, which as an instrument for the British choice of direct/indirect rule in the
suddenly increased the organizational capacity and resources of Chhattisgarh area.
the Maoists and resulted in a phase of expansion all over India. Exclusion restriction: The only way by which the death of the
Nagpur ruler is related to the outbreak of Maoist insurgency in
5. Empirical analysis of spatial variation in Maoist control in the future is through the conversion of these districts to direct rule.
Chhattisgarh This satisfies the requirement of the instrument being exogenous
to the outcome being studied, and fulfills the exclusion restriction
5.1. Addressing the selection issue – using an instrument for colonial condition of a good instrument. While it could be argued that the
indirect rule British wanted Nagpur state for its resources and there was selec-
tion involved, the British administrators could not have predicted
In her anthropological study of Bastar princely state, Sundar the death of Raghuji III in 1854 beforehand. So the actual timing
(2007), p. 103, writes: ‘‘Indirect rule had several advantages for of the switch to direct rule was randomly caused by this death,
the British. First, it was useful for areas which were not immedi- due to the prevailing official policy of Doctrine of Lapse of the gov-
ately open to exploitation, like Bastar. In 1884, the Chief Commis- ernor general Lord Dalhousie, and thus satisfies the exclusion
sioner explicitly concluded that Bastar was too poor to justify restriction condition. The only reason this was not exogenous
direct management by the state. Secondly, it was cheaper. . . . ” would be if the British planned the death of the ruler, but there
The British possibly selected districts for indirect rule based on is no evidence of this. Also, the British chose not to annex Nagpur
whether they were more difficult to govern due to hilly terrain, state in 1817 after defeating the Marathas in battle due to geo
high forest cover, intrinsic tribal rebelliousness, low revenues, political circumstances, and this too goes against the argument
and other unobserved qualities. that they selected it for direct rule for its resources suddenly in
If this is true, then the pre-colonial qualities of these districts 1854, something they could have easily done in 1817 itself, but
made them more prone to tribal rebellion in the future, and so did not.
OLS estimates would be potentially biased upward. However, Coding of the instrument: See Appendix E (online appendix) for
selection was not universal and historical contingencies sometimes details of coding of instrument. The instrument is coded as those
prevented the British from being selective, and they chose districts constituencies in current day Chhattisgarh state which were part
like Khairagarh, Kawardha, Nandgaon in the western border of of the colonial era districts of Bilaspur and Raipur, since these
Chhattisgarh for indirect rule, even though these were more agri- two districts in the colonial era were part of erstwhile Nagpur state
culturally productive, and had no tribal rebellion, which goes and today are part of current state of Chhattisgarh. In 2001 census,
against the expected direction of bias.30 In the OLS analysis below, the erstwhile Raipur and Bilaspur districts have been divided into
I control for some observable determinants of indirect rule choice, the following districts of current day Chhattisgarh—Raipur, Bilas-
like forest cover and elevation. To better address the issue of unob- pur, Durg, Dhamtari and Mahasamund. These districts are thus
servable qualities of districts causing selection effects, I then use an coded as the instrument since they were part of Nagpur state in
instrument for the choice of indirect rule through princely state, 1854, when they formed only two large districts of Raipur and
based on the random death of the ruler of Nagpur, which resulted Bilaspur, and switched to British direct rule and became part of
in the central districts of Chhattisgarh switching to British direct Central provinces.
rule. However, the districts of Rajnandgaon, Kawardha etc. which
were part of the colonial era princely state of Nandgaon in the
5.1.1. Instrument for indirect rule through princely states west, did not switch to British direct rule, and neither did the prin-
(instru_NagpurLapse) cely states of Surguja, Koriya, Jashpur in the north, and the princely
Following the defeat of Appa Sahib of the Marathas in 1817 to states of Bastar, Kanker in the south. Also, there were some dis-
the British, the Nagpur State was managed by the British on behalf tricts like Korba (3 constituencies) and Janjgir-Champa (6 con-
of the minor Bhonsla Raja Raghuji III, who ‘‘succeeded to the stituencies) which were British direct rule and not part of
estates in 1830, but died without heirs in 1853, and the province Nagpur princely state and did not become direct rule because of
lapsed to the British Government.” (Baden Powell, 1892, Vol. 1, this random switch due to death of Nagpur ruler, and so are not
p. 47) 31 The reason for lapse of Nagpur State, ruled by the Bhonsla coded as part of the instrument.
clan of the Marathas, to the British government due to death of the Comparing with Iyer (2010)’s IV2SLS: This instrument is similar
ruler was because of the existence of the policy of Doctrine of Lapse to the instrument in Iyer (2010)’s analysis of the effects of colonial
implemented by the governor general Lord Dalhousie (1847–56) British rule on development outcomes, but the IV2SLS analysis
under which any Indian ruler who died without a male heir would below contrasts with the Iyer (2010) IV2SLS results which suggest
have to forfeit his kingdom to the British, and adoption of heirs that on average districts with indirect rule in India have more
would not be recognized. The switch to British direct rule was due development. This is because Iyer (2010) uses a truncated sample
to the random circumstance of the death of the ruler of Nagpur state for her IV2SLS analysis for districts annexed only in the 1847–56
period of Lord Dalhousie’s reign, thus not being able to address
29
selection in the northern epicenter of insurgency in Bihar/Bengal
See Section 2.1 above and Appendix H for details of history of the movement in
Chhattisgarh. which had already been annexed in 1765 in the Battle of Buxar.
30
E. A de Brett, Chhattisgarh Feudatory States, p. 3–4. Also there are some coding errors of princely state in the Iyer
31
Baden Powell, Land Tenure Systems of British India, Volume 1, p. 47. (2010) dataset, i.e. Bastar and Rajnandgaon districts of 1991
S. Mukherjee / World Development 111 (2018) 113–129 121

Census are coded as britdum = 1, when actually they are prin- or fatalities. It is important to distinguish between these concepts,
cely states and britdum = 0 (Imperial Gazetteer of India, v. 26, since in those areas where the state is completely absent and the
Political Divisions map, p. 20). This is explained in greater detail rebels have full control and set up alternate institutions of gover-
in Online Appendix K. nance, there is possibly less violence, and yet insurgency is most
successful (Kalyvas, 2006). In the case of Chhattisgarh, this is even
5.2. OLS and IV-2SLS regression analysis more the case because before the start of the Salwa Judum move-
ment in 2005 which led to escalation of violence, the levels of rebel
The following hypothesis is proposed based on the theory out- control were quite high in the southern districts like Narayanpur
lined above. and Dantewada, and yet levels of violence were relatively low, as
Hypothesis: Areas which had indirect colonial rule through princely shown in Fig. 2. So using insurgency violence will not correctly mea-
states tend to have higher probability of Maoist insurgency in the sure the areas of rebel control in early 2000s before violence esca-
future, even after controlling for various proximate measures of rebel lated in Chhattisgarh in 2005. A second reason is that media
opportunity and ethnic grievances. based events data may not record violent events deep inside rebel
territories due to lack of access to information from such zones of
high rebel control (Zukerman-Daly, 2012). For both these reasons,
5.2.1. Data and variables
using total violence could mis-measure rebel control and lead to
Mapping Census data into Assembly Constituencies:. Unlike most of
conceptual stretching (Sartori, 1970).
the econometric analysis of Maoist insurgency in India which use
While Kalyvas (2006) had used rebel control as an independent
district level datasets, this paper uses the Vidhan Sabha (State
variable to explain selective violence, he does not have a good expla-
Assembly) constituency as the unit, to achieve sufficient disaggre-
nation for why rebel control emerges in some places and not others,
gation in measurement of rebel control. Since the constituency is
and it is important to explain spatial variation in rebel control as the
the basic political unit for which MLAs are elected and are account-
dependent variable. Following the precedence of Mitchell (1968),
able to the public, it makes sense to use this as the unit, instead of
Kalyvas and Kocher (2009), I measure Maoist control based on gov-
the district, which is too aggregate and masks sub-district variation
ernment perception of rebel influence.37 Electoral data gives the %
in Maoist control.32 This is the first study on the Maoist insurgency in
of polling stations within each Assembly constituency that were
India to use the sub-district Assembly Constituency as the unit of
Highly Sensitive, Sensitive, or Normal for the 2003 State Assembly
analysis.
elections, and was collected during field work.38 I use the % of Highly
The state of Chhattisgarh has 17 districts subdivided into 97
Sensitive polling stations within each constituency as a proxy of
tehsils, and 90 State assembly constituencies (ACs).33 Each district
Maoist control in that constituency. This is a measure of how polit-
has one or more ACs. I develop a dataset for these 90 ACs which is
ically sensitive a particular constituency is perceived to be, based on
very detailed and the first constituency level dataset for the state
reports that the individual district administrations send to the Chief
of Chhattisgarh. The dependent variable of Maoist control as well
Election Commissioner of the state prior to elections. This is a con-
as the independent variable of princely state are measured at the
tinuous measure and provides more information than a categorical
AC level directly. Unfortunately, the Census 2001 socio economic,
measure as used by Kalyvas (2006) or Mitchell (1968).39 It is a valu-
public good and demographic data is in administrative units like dis-
able empirical contribution, given the challenges of collecting good
trict/tehsils, and there is not a perfect match geographically of tehsil/
data in an active conflict zone with the Indian state often reluctant
district boundaries with Assembly constituency (AC) electoral
to share data, and field work being risky.40 See Online Appendix C
boundaries.34 The geographical matching of constituencies with
for details.
administrative boundaries is a problem for several well-known stud-
Possible bias in measure of rebel control does not bias regression
ies of Indian politics.35 To match the 90 constituencies to the 97 teh-
coefficients: There are various possible biases in this measure of
sils, a map of district/tehsil boundaries of Chhattisgarh in 2001 was
Maoist control and these are discussed in detail in Online Appendix
compared to constituency boundaries from an electoral map from
C, and I briefly mention these here.
2003 State Assembly Elections.36 The boundaries of tehsils and
One possible bias occurs in a well-known previous study using
assembly constituency boundaries was matched to the extent possi-
measures of rebel control based on government perception, i.e.
ble, following the procedures of Banerjee and Somanathan (2007)
Kalyvas and Kocher (2009: 342) use the Hamlet Evaluation System
and Thachil (2011). The coding procedure and data sources are
(HES) data created by the US military during the Vietnam war to
described in Online Appendix B.
measure rebel control, but note that there is ‘‘optimistic bias” in
the HES data in favor of showing more government control.41 It
Measuring Maoist control as the dependent variable. In this paper, I is possible that in Chhattisgarh, the district police chief intentionally
explain spatial variation in Maoist rebel control, instead of killings

32 37
For example, the Indian state considers a district like Kanker in Chhattisgarh as Mitchell (1968) tries to predict spatial variation in government control in the
under high Maoist influence, but it is the western areas of Kanker which are under Vietnam war using data on 26 South Vietnamese provinces measured as ‘‘the
higher Maoist control, while the eastern areas are not. percentage of hamlets in a province classified as government controlled according to
33
There are three levels of elections within Indian democracy. The first is the Lok a detailed map . . . which was derived from US government sources.” Kalyvas and
Sabha or national legislative assembly elections. The second is state legislative Kocher (2009) and measure rebel control in the Vietnam insurgency based on the
assembly or Vidhan Sabha elections for individual provinces or states. The third is Hamlet Evaluation System (HES) data created by the US government through regular
elections to panchayats of village level bodies. surveys of US and Vietnamese officials.
34 38
The administrative unit comprises the state followed by the district, and then the Table 22: ‘Assembly Segment Wise Highly Sensitive, Sensitive & Normal Polling
mandal or taluk or tehsil (different states have different names for this sub district Stations’, Chhattisgarh State Assembly Election – 2003, p. 52.
39
level unit), followed by block, town or village. The electoral unit within a state is the Analysis is also carried out by converting the % of Highly Sensitive polling stations
assembly constituency (AC) followed by polling stations. into a categorical measure of Maoist control, on a scale of 0 to 4, like Kalyvas’ (2006)
35
Chandra (2004, p. 159–160) notes ‘‘. . . government data, including data from the categorization of rebel control. The results are similar.
40
census, are reported by administrative subdivisions (district, tehsil, and block), which Various human rights activists and scholars have been harassed during field work
do not coincide with constituencies.” in Maoist areas, and the author faced suspicion from the police.
36
Map 7: ‘Chhattisgarh Administrative Divisions 20010 in Census of India 2001 41
Kalyvas and Kocher (2009: 342) find that ‘‘Bole & Kobata (1975) find evidence
Chhattisgarh Administrative Atlas, p. 15, with Table 7: ‘List of Assembly Constituencies that the HES was biased in the direction of government control (the so-called
District-wise’, pages 15–17, and ‘Map of Assembly Segments’, p. 18 of Chhattisgarh ‘optimistic bias’), perhaps in response to bureaucratic incentives to show ‘progress’ in
State Assembly Election – 2003. the pacification effort.”
122 S. Mukherjee / World Development 111 (2018) 113–129

underestimates some areas under Maoist control to show progress to 5.2.2. OLS estimates of the impact of indirect colonial rule on Maoist
superior officers, thus creating this ‘optimistic bias’.42 Bias could go insurgency
in the opposite direction, if the police chief intentionally overesti-
mates the number of sensitive polling stations in their district to (a) Difference in means shows effects of colonial institutions on
ensure that the Election Commission provides extra police and intermediary mechanisms of state capacity, development
paramilitary troops to that district, to make it easier for them to Table 1A gives the difference in means between direct rule and
organize peaceful elections.43 However, the error in the measure of indirect rule constituencies of each variable for all constituencies
political sensitivity is not correlated with the independent variable in Chhattisgarh, and shows significantly higher mean values of
of colonial indirect rule, since the police have number of Maoist Maoist control for the constituencies that were under indirect rule
squads, and maybe level of violence in mind when perceiving the through princely states. It shows that constituencies that were for-
level of Maoist control, but are not thinking of historical institu- merly princely states had more forest cover, and higher terrain,
tions.44 So, the OLS estimators are unbiased and consistent, though which indicates possible selection.
there will be larger variance in the error terms.45 However, Table 1A also show that princely state constituencies
have lower access to many public goods like schools, water tanks
Independent variables and control variables. and tubewells, electricity, while British direct rule areas have
Independent variable: The main independent variable is colonial higher levels of access to paved roads, buses, and less average dis-
indirect rule through princely states, in the area which is today part tance of villages from main town, i.e. higher state penetration in
of Chhattisgarh state in central India. these rural areas (Census 2001 data). Direct rule constituencies
Princely state: Princely state dummy was created by matching also seem to have higher literacy and population density (levels
the 2003 Chhattisgarh Assembly Constituency Election Map46 with of urbanization). Table 1B presents OLS regressions that show sim-
the map of direct and indirect rule in Chhattisgarh from The ilar results that princely state is a statistically significant predictor
Imperial Gazetteer of India: Volume 26—Atlas, Plate 39 (see Fig. 1B of all these various contemporary measures of public goods, devel-
above). This is coded as 1 if the constituency was earlier part of opment and state capacity. This provides evidence for the long
any of the princely states within Chhattisgarh area, and 0 if it was term negative effects of the Chhattisgarh princely states, and pos-
part of the British governed areas of Raipur, Bilaspur and Durg, itive effects of colonial direct rule on development, state capacity,
which is possible since there are no constituencies today which were and ethnic inequalities, which acted as intermediating mecha-
partly within British India and partly within princely states. nisms that were exploited later by Maoist rebels.
Wilkinson (2017) criticizes studies like Verghese (2016a,b),
Banerjee and Iyer (2005), and Iyer (2010) for clubbing different (b) Model specification: The OLS regressions are of the form
types of colonial land tenure and indirect rule which are really
quite dissimilar into similar categories.47 While in future research Y i ¼ a þ b princelystatei þ dX i þ ei ;
it would also be useful to have a continuous measure of princely
state, for this paper I consider that using the same binary measure where Yi is the dependent variable of Maoist control for con-
of princely state as in Iyer (2010) has the following advantages. First, stituency i, princelystatei is the dummy for whether the constituency
it allows my study to be comparable to Iyer (2010) by using similar was earlier part of a princely state or British India, and Xi stands for
binary measure of princely state and still showing that the conclusion other constituency characteristics controlled for, including forest
is the opposite, i.e. indirect rule leads to lower development and cover, elevation, literacy, rurality, % of tribes and lower castes,
insurgency. Second, unlike in an all India analysis where there would and other variables usually included in civil war onset models. ei
be a lot of variation between types of princely states, within the state represents the error term.
of Chhattisgarh, there is not much variation in types of princely The OLS model results are presented in Tables 2A, and 2B. In all
states between Kanker, Bastar, Surguja, Koriya, Nandgaon which models, standard errors are clustered at the district level to
are all Chhattisgarh feudatory states with Rajput rulers. Third, I account for unobserved district level characteristics, because the
cluster using colonial era princely state boundaries in Table 4C, and district is the administrative unit within a province, and electoral
that takes care of heterogeneity between princely states in constituencies in the same district are similar in terms of adminis-
Chhattisgarh. tration, counter insurgency, and development policy, and other
Control variables: Electoral data at the constituency level were unobserved qualities.48 In Table 2A, the baseline specification is
directly obtained from the Chhattisgarh State Election Commis- Model 1A, which has only the main independent variable, princelys-
sion. The socio-economic and demographic data like literacy, tate, which is statistically significant at the 1% error level in predict-
unemployment, percent of scheduled castes and tribes, provision ing Maoist control. In Models 1B to 1D, princely state remains
of public goods etc. were converted from the Census of India significant even after controlling for forest cover and elevation, which
(2001) data, using the procedure described above. These variables are two measures of terrain that could provide opportunity for rebel-
and their sources are described in Online Appendix D. lion, and could also be considered pre-colonial qualities of these
areas affecting selection by British. Combined with the results in
Table 1B which shows that princely states has lower levels of devel-
42
Interview with Superintendent of Police, Chhattisgarh (district not revealed), opment and state capacity, the results in Models 1A to 1D in
2009. Table 2A suggests that princely state has an effect on Maoist control
43
Interview with Chief Election Commissioner of Chhattisgarh, Raipur, November
through these causal mechanisms.
2008.
44
The Ministry of Home Affairs, India, use various criteria like number of
underground Maoist squads, number of overground front organizations of Maoists 48
It is not possible to do district fixed effects to control for any possible district level
etc. to determine which districts are under Maoist control at the national level for the unobservables, because there is little within-district variation in the princely state
Security Related Expenditures (SRE) scheme, and similar criteria are probably being variable, preventing Fixed Effects estimation for princely state due to almost no within
used here. group variation (See Gujarati, Basic Econometrics, p. 640–51). This is because post-
45
See Woolridge, Introductory Econometrics, p. 302–303. colonial district boundaries continued to follow the colonial era district boundaries
46
‘Map of Assembly Segments’, p. 18 of Chhattisgarh State Assembly Election – 2003. without much change, and there are no current districts in Chhattisgarh which were
47
See Steven Wilkinson, ‘‘Looking Back at the Colonial Origins of Communal and part of both British direct rule and princely states. However, Random Effects
Caste Conflict in India,” February 21, 2017, The Wire, at https://thewire.in/ estimation shows princely state dummy to be still statistically significant. Results
110535/communal-violence-caste-colonialism/. available from author.
S. Mukherjee / World Development 111 (2018) 113–129 123

Table 2A
OLS estimates of impact of colonial institutions on Maoist rebellion.
Dependent Variable: Maoist Control (% Highly Sensitive Polling Stations in each Constituency).

Pre colonial controls Post colonial controls


Model 1A Model 1B Model 1C Model 1D Model 2A Model 2B
Princely State 20.09*** (0.001) 13.42*** (0.004) 17.83** (0.044) 14.67** (0.042) 15.55*** (0.005) 11.93*** (0.002)
Forest Cover 0.260** (0.015) 0.277** (0.039) 0.281** (0.014) 0.118 (0.220)
Elevation 0.0134 (0.569) 0.0101 (0.724) 0.0304 (0.173)
Popln Density 0.000250 (0.960) 0.00238 (0.588)
Rural % 0.0285 (0.636) 0.0688 (0.178)
Per Capita Income 0.000320 (0.476) 0.000172 (0.483)
Male Unemployment 0.490 (0.260) 0.852* (0.064)
Scheduled Caste% 0.505** (0.038)
Scheduled Tribe% 0.450*** (0.009)
Electricity 26.93** (0.040)
ST% * Electricity 1.029*** (0.001)
Male Literacy 0.481* (0.090)
Constant 2.173* (0.061) 3.013 (0.136) 2.110 (0.774) 0.151 (0.984) 34.74 (0.203) 13.86 (0.749)
Observations 90 90 90 90 90 90
R2 0.296 0.429 0.304 0.433 0.439 0.651

p-values in parentheses. *p < 0.10, **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01.
Robust Std. Errors adjusted for 17 clusters by district.

Table 2B
OLS estimates of impact of colonial institutions on maoist rebellion.
Dependent Variable: Maoist Control (% Highly Sensitive Polling Stations in each Constituency).

Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6 Model 7 Model 8


Princely State 12.10*** 11.34*** 11.46*** 11.62*** 12.14*** 12.87***
(0.001) (0.002) (0.003) (0.002) (0.002) (0.001)
Forest Cover 0.129 0.0916 0.105 0.116 0.115 0.109
(0.194) (0.384) (0.226) (0.227) (0.230) (0.241)
Elevation 0.0310 0.0289 0.0287 0.0287 0.0314 0.0265
(0.167) (0.164) (0.190) (0.180) (0.157) (0.226)
Popln Density 0.000349 0.00784 0.00217 0.00781 0.00266 0.00454
(0.952) (0.325) (0.624) (0.114) (0.560) (0.259)
Rural % 0.0672 0.0811 0.0562 0.0799 0.0683 0.0853
(0.181) (0.181) (0.312) (0.130) (0.203) (0.136)
Per Capita Income 0.000177 0.000418
(0.484) (0.137)
Male Unemployment 0.839* 0.833* 0.763* 0.819* 0.869* 0.565
(0.061) (0.052) (0.063) (0.061) (0.068) (0.111)
Scheduled Caste% 0.431* 0.454** 0.449* 0.556** 0.492* 0.741**
(0.059) (0.040) (0.065) (0.037) (0.057) (0.022)
Scheduled Tribe% 0.462*** 0.493*** 0.393** 0.408** 0.461** 0.313**
(0.008) (0.006) (0.031) (0.017) (0.011) (0.046)
Electricity 26.34** 29.53** 24.15** 25.19** 26.04** 25.03**
(0.033) (0.023) (0.032) (0.047) (0.026) (0.024)
ST% * Electricity 1.032*** 1.047*** 0.960*** 0.968*** 1.017*** 1.001***
(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.000)
Male Literacy 0.479* 0.498* 0.491* 0.526* 0.502 0.476*
(0.086) (0.078) (0.091) (0.075) (0.126) (0.096)
Paved Road 7.410
(0.270)
Post Office 24.27
(0.334)
Distance from Town 0.0691
(0.515)
Railway Station 170.3
(0.110)
VoterTurnout 1985 0.0568
(0.760)
ENPV 1998 6.374**
(0.030)
Constant 16.25 12.00 7.445 8.116 15.70 11.82
(0.708) (0.775) (0.859) (0.846) (0.720) (0.770)
Observations 90 90 90 90 90 90
R2 0.653 0.657 0.655 0.655 0.652 0.687

p-values in parentheses.
Robust Std. Errors adjusted for 17 clusters by district.
*
p < 0.10, **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01.

In Table 2A, Model 2A adds proximate post-colonial controls electricity, and the interaction term of scheduled tribes with access
like population density, rural percent, per capita income, and male to electricity. Table 2B has Models 3 to 6 replace per capita income
unemployment, and Model 2B includes proximate factors like male which Fearon and Laitin (2003) use as their proxy for state capac-
literacy, percent of scheduled caste and scheduled tribes, access to ity, with other proxies for state capacity like access to paved road,
124 S. Mukherjee / World Development 111 (2018) 113–129

Table 3A
First stage of IV-2SLS estimates of impact of colonial institutions on Maoist rebellion.
Dependent Variable: Princely State.

Pre colonial controls Post colonial controls


Model 1A Princely Model 1B Princely Model 1C Princely Model 1D Princely Model 2A Princely Model 2B Princely
State State State State State State
Nagpur Lapse (1854) 0.776*** (0.000) 0.719*** (0.001) 0.645*** (0.002) 0.641*** (0.004) 0.576*** (0.008) 0.604*** (0.004)
Forest Cover 0.00229 (0.454) 0.000280 (0.902) 0.00110 (0.621) 0.00250 (0.262)
Elevation 0.000995 (0.114) 0.000970* (0.089) 0.000694 (0.134) 0.000446 (0.214)
Popln Density 0.000124 (0.430) 0.00000304 (0.981)
Rural % 0.000635 (0.778) 0.000100 (0.962)
PerCapita Income 0.00000732 (0.148) 0.00000500 (0.517)
Male Unemployment 0.0249 (0.103) 0.0224 (0.285)
Scheduled Caste% 0.00880 (0.463)
Scheduled Tribe% 0.00389 (0.562)
Electricity 0.382 (0.138)
ST% * Electricity 0.00612 (0.340)
Male Literacy 0.00658* (0.099)
Constant 0.776*** (0.000) 0.679*** (0.006) 0.329 (0.381) 0.328 (0.386) 1.950** (0.029) 2.696* (0.060)
Observations 90 90 90 90 90 90
R2 0.611 0.626 0.676 0.676 0.707 0.728
Adjusted R2 0.607 0.617 0.668 0.665 0.682 0.685
Weak Instrument Diagnosis:
Partial R2
Angrist Pischke F statistic 37.27 17.44 12.95 11.36 9.08 11.63
Angrist Pischke p value (0.000) (0.000) (0.0024) (0.0039) (0.0082) (0.0036)
Kleibergen-Paap Wald 37.27 17.44 12.95 11.36 9.08 11.63
statistic
Cragg-Donald Wald F 138.49 99.56 89.38 82.18 61.25 60.97
statistic

p-values in parentheses. *p < 0.10, **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01.
Robust Std. Errors adjusted for 17 clusters by district.

access to post office, railway station, average distance of villages from districts of Chhattisgarh based on the lapse of Nagpur state to Bri-
nearest town in a constituency.49 tish rule.
These OLS models 2A, 2B, and 3 to 6 show that princely state The results of the first stage of the IV-2SLS are presented in
remains a statistically significant predictor of Maoist control even Table 3A below. Replicating Model 1A, 1B, 1C, 1D, 2A and 2B from
after controlling for more proximate measures of ethnic grievances, Table 2A of the OLS regressions, the first stage regressions gener-
poverty and literacy, state capacity, which are themselves the ally show that Instru_Nagpur Lapse has a strong negative correla-
result of colonial rule institutions. This suggests that the colonial tion with colonial indirect rule through princely states.50 This is
indirect rule institutions have its own separate effect, over and because these districts switched to direct British rule due to death
above the effects of contemporary factors like state capacity, of ruler. Bound, Jaeger and Baker (1995) show how the IV-2SLS esti-
ethnicity, development on rebellion. However, the OLS results mates may be somewhat biased in the same direction as OLS esti-
may possibly be biased due to selection, so the next section pre- mates in finite samples if there is weak correlation in the first
sents the IV-2SLS analysis. stage between the instrument and the endogenous independent
variables. For Model 1A, the first stage regression with princely state
as the dependent variable yields an Angrist-Pischke F statistic of
5.2.3. 2SLS instrumental variable regression model estimation:
37.27 (p value of 0.000) for the excluded instrument. For Models
In this section, I replicate the Models from the OLS regressions
1B, 1C, 1D, the Angrist-Pischke F statistic is 17.44, 12.95, 11.36
in Tables 2A and 2B, using IV-2SLS. I instrument for the potentially
respectively. For Model 2A and 2B, which are the longer models,
endogenous independent variable, princelystate, using instru_Nag-
the Angrist-Pischke F statistic is 9.08 (p value of 0.0082) and 11.63
pur Lapse, based on random annexation of Nagpur state due to
(P value of 0.0036) respectively.51 The Angrist-Pischke F statistic of
death of the ruler.
the instrument for princelystate is larger than 10 in all models except
First stage of IV-2SLS: The first stage regression for the IV strat-
2A, which is the usual F statistic value required to suggest that
egy is:
instruments are sufficiently strong. Given this information, it is pos-
princelystatei ¼ a þ binstruN agurLapsei þ dX i þ ei sible to reject the null hypothesis of no correlation between instru-
ment and endogenous regressors at the 95% confidence level, and
where princelystatei is the measure of colonial indirect rule for the this implies that the instruments are not weak.52
i th constituency, as in the OLS regressions above, and Xi stands Second stage of IV-2SLS: The second stage regression for the IV
for the same constituency characteristics controlled for in the OLS strategy estimates the impact of colonial indirect rule through
model. In the first stage of the 2SLS, I use instru_NagpurLapse as
the instrument for the choice of direct vs. indirect rule in the British 50
Estimating first stage regressions for Models 3–8 in Table 4A below will give
similar results, and are not shown.
49 51
These indicate the ability of state forces to quickly reach distant rural areas, and The Kleibergen-Paap Wald statistic is the same as the Angrist-Pischke statistics,
may be better measures of actual state penetration in rural areas, than measures of since there is only one endogenous independent variable, namely princelystate. See
per capita income at the sub-district level. Model 7 includes voter turnout from 1985 Angrist & Pischke (2009) for discussion on instrumental variables.
52
assembly elections in Chhattisgarh as a possible measure of level of democracy. See Stock, Wright and Yogo (2002) for detailed discussion about weak
Model 8 includes ENPV lagged for the 1998 Chhattisgarh elections, which Wilkinson instruments, and see Baum, Schaffer, and Stillman (2007) for how to check for weak
(2004) found has an effect on ethnic riots in India. instruments, and the STATA code to use.
S. Mukherjee / World Development 111 (2018) 113–129 125

Table 4A
IV-2SLS estimates of impact of colonial institutions on Maoist rebellion.
Dependent Variable: Maoist Control (% Highly Sensitive Polling Stations in each Constituency).

Pre colonial controls Post colonial controls


Model 1A Model 1B Model 1C Model 1D Model 2A Model 2B
Princely State 22.06*** (0.000) 13.92*** (0.000) 20.81*** (0.007) 15.13** (0.011) 16.47*** (0.005) 11.79** (0.037)
Forest Cover 0.256*** (0.005) 0.275** (0.019) 0.290** (0.011) 0.118 (0.158)
Elevation 0.00737(0.744) 0.0109 (0.680) 0.00716 (0.792) 0.0303 (0.144)
Popln Density 0.000179 (0.974) 0.00233 (0.535)
Rural % 0.0267 (0.652) 0.0686 (0.120)
PerCapita Income -0.000324 (0.446) 0.000172 (0.424)
Male Unemployment 0.453 (0.293) 0.846* (0.052)
Scheduled Caste% 0.505** (0.013)
Scheduled Tribe% 0.450*** (0.001)
Electricity 26.95** (0.016)
ST% * Electricity 1.030*** (0.000)
Male Literacy 0.482* (0.061)
Constant 1.341** (0.023) 3.105* (0.085) 1.002 (0.889) 0.00386 (1.000) 30.34 (0.343) 13.42 (0.752)
Observations 90 90 90 90 90 90
R2 0.293 0.429 0.299 0.433 0.441 0.651
Adjusted R2 0.285 0.416 0.283 0.413 0.393 0.597
Endogeneity & Overidentification Test Diagnosis:
Hansen’s J statistic y y y y y y
Hansen’s J (p value) y y y y y y
Anderson-Rubin Wald test na 9.54 5.29 5.33 4.25 2.10
Anderson-Rubin (p-value) na (0.0070) (0.0352) (0.0347) (0.0559) (0.1668)

p-values in parentheses. *p < 0.10, **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01.
Robust Std. Errors adjusted for 17 clusters by district.
y
Hansen J Statistic (overidentification test of all instruments) is 0.000, since equation is exactly identified because the number of endogenous regressors equals the number of
instruments.

princelystate on Maoist control, and has the same specification as nants of choice of indirect rule like terrain, as well as using an
the OLS model: instrument for indirect rule to address selection effects, princely state
institutions have a separate causal effect on the probability of Maoist
Y i ¼ a þ b princelystatei þ dX i þ ui ; insurgency. Once the institutions of indirect rule were in place, they
had an additional effect on state penetration and development
where Yi is the dependent variable of Maoist control for constituency
which persisted through ‘sticky’ path dependent mechanisms and
i used in the OLS regression table, princelystatei is the same measure
created political opportunity structures for leftist insurgency.
of indirect rule, Xi stands for the same set of control variables, and ui
In Table 4A, Model 2A, 2B, I include the other post-colonial and
represents the error term. Standard errors are robust to clustering
more proximate factors, and in Table 4B, I control for the larger set
by district, though district fixed effects cannot be shown because
of post-colonial proximate factors like public goods, economic
of lack of within district variation in the independent variable of
development, literacy, employment, alternate state capacity mea-
princelystate, since current district boundaries follow colonial era
sures. Princely state continues to be statistically significant predic-
district boundaries, as explained above.
tor of Maoist control. This suggests that colonial indirect rule
Tables 4A below and 4B show the results of the second stage of
institutions have a causal effect beyond the effects of proximate
the IV-2SLS regressions, and are the same specifications as OLS
factors on Maoist insurgency. Colonial indirect rule acts as a deep
models in Tables 2A and 2B above. It is not possible to do the Han-
rooted structural condition which creates several of these proxi-
sen’s J test for overidentifying restrictions, since the number of
mate measures of state capacity, ethnic inequalities, and levels of
instruments is equal to the number of endogenous regressors,
literacy and development, and these proximate factors then act
and the equation is exactly identified, but the instrument should
as mechanisms that are exploited by the Maoists.
satisfy exclusion restrictions.53
Proximate post-colonial factors: The IV2SLS models include prox-
imate factors in Models 2A, 2B, and 3–7. Some notable results are
5.2.4. Analysis and discussion of results that forest cover is significant and has a positive coefficient in the
Colonial institutions: In Table 4A, Model 1A, the instrumental shorter models, but in the longer models like 2B, and Table 4B,
variable regression yields a point estimate of 22.06 on princelystate Models 3–8 it is not statistically significant. Elevation, which is a
which is significant at 99% confidence level. The size of the IV-2SLS proxy for rough terrain, has a positive but non-significant coeffi-
coefficient in Model 1A is slightly larger than the OLS regression cient in Model 1C, but in all other models with more control vari-
coefficient of 20.09 for princely state in Table 2A, Model 1A. The ables, elevation has a negative coefficient, which could be because
effect of being a princely state in Chhattisgarh on the possibility of influential observations.54
of Maoist insurgency in the future is quite large—moving a con- In Model 2B, Scheduled Tribe (ST) % has a positive and significant
stituency from direct rule under the British to indirect rule through coefficient, since the Maoists recruit mainly from the poor tribal
a princely state increases the % of Maoist affected polling stations populations in Chhattisgarh. The other papers like Gawande et al.
in the constituency by almost 22 percentage points. In Models 1B (2017), Chandra and Garcia-Ponce (2014), Gomes (2015) also find
to 1D, on including forest cover and elevation, princely state is still that scheduled tribes have a positive correlation with Maoist
statistically significant and positively correlated with Maoist con-
trol. These results suggest that controlling for pre-colonial determi- 54
Maybe two influential observations of Konta and Bijapur constituencies that score
highest on Maoist control but low on elevation are causing the correlation to become
53
See Kurt Schmidheiny, ‘‘A Short Guide to Microeconometrics”, Spring 2012, negative. On excluding them, elevation has a positive coefficient. (See Appendix F for
Downloaded from internet. graph).
126 S. Mukherjee / World Development 111 (2018) 113–129

Table 4B
IV-2SLS estimates of impact of colonial institutions on maoist rebellion.
Dependent Variable: Maoist Control (Measured as % of Highly Sensitive Polling Stations in each Constituency).

Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6 Model 7 Model 8


Princely State 12.15** 11.14** 11.75** 11.28* 12.44*** 12.70**
(0.024) (0.040) (0.041) (0.051) (0.009) (0.018)
Forest Cover 0.130 0.0912 0.105 0.116 0.116 0.108
(0.133) (0.318) (0.165) (0.167) (0.162) (0.181)
Elevation 0.0310 0.0287 0.0290 0.0284 0.0317 0.0264
(0.134) (0.138) (0.161) (0.157) (0.115) (0.191)
Popln Density 0.000337 0.00780 0.00226 0.00774* 0.00276 0.00448
(0.947) (0.272) (0.555) (0.063) (0.439) (0.148)
Rural % 0.0673 0.0809 0.0568 0.0795* 0.0687 0.0850*
(0.121) (0.125) (0.255) (0.077) (0.132) (0.067)
PerCapita Income 0.000178 0.000417*
(0.423) (0.075)
Male Unemployment 0.841** 0.825** 0.776* 0.805* 0.881** 0.558
(0.049) (0.042) (0.075) (0.054) (0.041) (0.129)
Scheduled Caste% 0.431** 0.454** 0.449** 0.557** 0.491** 0.741***
(0.023) (0.014) (0.030) (0.011) (0.020) (0.005)
Scheduled Tribe% 0.462*** 0.494*** 0.393*** 0.409*** 0.461*** 0.314**
(0.001) (0.000) (0.009) (0.003) (0.001) (0.014)
Electricity 26.33** 29.59*** 24.12** 25.24** 25.96*** 25.06***
(0.012) (0.007) (0.010) (0.020) (0.008) (0.008)
ST% * Electricity 1.032*** 1.048*** 0.960*** 0.968*** 1.016*** 1.002***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
Male Literacy 0.479* 0.499** 0.489* 0.529** 0.501* 0.478*
(0.059) (0.049) (0.064) (0.049) (0.083) (0.066)
Paved Road 7.420
(0.214)
Post Office 24.42
(0.239)
Distance from Town 0.0684
(0.488)
Railway Station 171.6*
(0.056)
VoterTurnout 1985 0.0587
(0.684)
ENPV 1998 6.364***
(0.009)
Constant 16.41 11.37 8.404 7.016 16.69 11.28
(0.702) (0.780) (0.846) (0.866) (0.685) (0.779)
Observations 90 90 90 90 90 90
R2 0.653 0.657 0.655 0.655 0.652 0.687
Adjusted R2 0.599 0.604 0.601 0.602 0.592 0.633
Endogeneity & Overidentification Test Diagnosis:
y y y y y y
Hansen’s J statistic
y y y y y y
Hansen’s J (p value)
Anderson-RubinWald test 2.31 2.05 2.03 1.85 2.79 2.35
Anderson-Rubin (p-val) (0.1484) (0.1713) (0.1734) (0.1923) (0.1141) (0.1450)

p-values in parentheses.
Robust Std. Errors adjusted for 17 clusters by district.
*
p < 0.10, **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01.
y
Hansen J Statistic (overidentification test of all instruments) is 0.000, since equation is exactly identified because the number of endogenous regressors equals the number
of instruments.

insurgency, and this show a common finding in all studies on the reduces Maoist insurgency by providing employment in rural areas
Maoist insurgency, and suggests support for the Cederman, (Gawande et al., 2017; Hoelscher et al., 2012).
Wimmer, and Min (2010) mechanism of ethnic grievances. Sched-
uled Caste (SC) % has a negative and significant coefficient, because
6. Robustness checks
the lower castes in Chhattisgarh live in the central districts where
there is no insurgency.55
I do various robustness checks, and colonial indirect rule mea-
Another interesting result is that Male unemployment has a pos-
sured by princely state continues to remain statistically significant.
itive and significant effect in the longer models, which could be
I briefly mention the tests here, please see Online Appendix G for
support for both opportunity as well as grievance mechanisms,
detailed description.
since unemployment may create lower opportunity costs to joining
rebellion, and also may generate grievance among tribal unem-
ployed males.56 This supports the finding that NREGS program 6.1. Clustering by colonial era boundaries of princely states and British
districts

55
There can be unobservable similarities for current day electoral
In other states of India, like Bihar, the Maoists recruit mainly from the lower
castes, thus indicating multiple causal pathways to insurgency in India.
constituencies which were historically part of the same princely
56
Sambanis (2004) points out how it is better to measure rebel opportunity costs at state, or same British direct rule era district. To address this, I clus-
the sub-national level using fine grained data on male unemployment. ter by colonial era princely state and British district boundaries,
S. Mukherjee / World Development 111 (2018) 113–129 127

Table 4C
IV-2SLS estimates of impact of colonial institutions on Maoist rebellion.
Dependent Variable: Maoist Control (Measured as % of Highly Sensitive Polling Stations in each Constituency).

Pre colonial controls Post colonial controls


Model 1A Model 1B Model 1C Model 1D Model 2A Model 2B
Princely State 22.06*** (0.000) 13.92*** (0.000) 20.81** (0.029) 15.13*** (0.009) 16.47*** (0.003) 11.79*** (0.003)
Forest Cover 0.256* (0.055) 0.275* (0.094) 0.290* (0.062) 0.118 (0.212)
Elevation 0.00737 (0.751) 0.0109 (0.680) 0.00716 (0.791) 0.0303 (0.162)
Popln Density 0.000179 (0.969) 0.00233 (0.526)
Rural % 0.0267 (0.566) 0.0686* (0.096)
PerCapita Income 0.000324 (0.444) 0.000172 (0.409)
Male Unemployment 0.453* (0.078) 0.846** (0.032)
Scheduled Caste% 0.505** (0.048)
Scheduled Tribe% 0.450*** (0.009)
Electricity 26.95** (0.013)
ST% * Electricity 1.030*** (0.000)
Male Literacy 0.482* (0.067)
Constant 1.341** (0.029) 3.105 (0.183) 1.002 (0.892) 0.00386 (1.000) 30.34 (0.148) 13.42 (0.745)
Observations 90 90 90 90 90 90
R2 0.293 0.429 0.299 0.433 0.441 0.651
Adjusted R2 0.285 0.416 0.283 0.413 0.393 0.597

p-values in parentheses. *p < 0.10, **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01.
Robust Std. Errors adjusted for 16 clusters by colonial boundaries of princely states and British districts.

Table 4D
IV2SLS (spatial lagged) estimates of colonial institutions on Maoist rebellion.
Dependent Variable: Maoist Control (Measured as % of Highly Sensitive Polling Stations in Each Constituency).

Pre colonial controls Post colonial controls


Model 1A Model 1B Model 1C Model 1D Model 2A Model 2B
Princely State 12.43* (0.081) 10.27* (0.094) 8.331 (0.133) 8.519* (0.094) 7.814* (0.061) 5.882** (0.048)
Forest Cover 0.156** (0.011) 0.148*** (0.007) 0.150*** (0.003) 0.104** (0.020)
Elevation 0.0108 (0.339) 0.0196* (0.083) 0.0136 (0.139) 0.0154* (0.081)
Popln Density 0.00541 (0.352) 0.00566 (0.309)
Rural % 0.0637 (0.283) 0.0814 (0.161)
PerCapita Income 0.000248 (0.554) 0.000107 (0.788)
Male Unemployment 0.578* (0.059) 0.674** (0.027)
Scheduled Caste% 0.0234 (0.918)
Scheduled Tribe% 0.181* (0.076)
Electricity 5.097 (0.561)
ST% * Electricity 0.427* (0.068)
Male Literacy 0.193 (0.124)
Constant 0.0343 (0.992) 2.802 (0.338) 2.331 (0.531) 2.774 (0.454) 40.74* (0.050) 65.79*** (0.007)
Lambda
Constant 0.519 (0.163) 0.404 (0.188) 0.857*** (0.000) 0.701*** (0.001) 0.864*** (0.000) 1.019*** (0.000)
rho
Constant 0.505 (0.217) 0.484 (0.116) 0.191 (0.633) 0.233 (0.521) 0.105 (0.764) 0.532 (0.119)
Observations 90 90 90 90 90 90

p-values in parentheses. *p < 0.10, **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01.
No robust standard errors since spatial ivreg does not allow that option. Spatial Weights matrix used to calculate spatial lag of Maoist control.

and present the IV2SLS results in Table 4C below which show prin- 6.3. Controlling for alternate historical factors
cely state to be strongly significant.
First, to control for effects of pre-colonial conflict on current
6.2. Spatial autocorrelation – contagion from neighboring conflict (Besley & Reynal-Querol, 2014), I develop and control for
constituencies a new measure of pre-colonial agrarian rebellion for the Mughal per-
iod (1556–1707), see Online Appendix G, Table 5. Second, I control
To control for spatial diffusion or contagion of insurgency from for previous organizational legacies (Jha & Wilkinson, 2012;
neighboring constituencies, I test for spatial autocorrelation by cre- Zukerman-Daly, 2012) that could facilitate future conflict, by using
ating a spatial weight matrix for Chhattisgarh, and including a spa- an alternate measure of leftist strength. Finally, I control for prior
tial lag of Maoist control in the model (Lane (2016: 397), Gleditsch subaltern ethnic party success from 1980 elections (Chandra &
(2007: 302), Salehyan and Gleditsch (2006). The results in Table 4D Garcia-Ponce, 2014).
show some evidence for spatial autocorrelation, but princely state
is still significant.57 6.4. Other measures of dependent variable of Maoist rebel control

57
See Drukker et al. (2013a, 2013b) for the STATA code on how to create spatial I check the robustness of the regression estimates for other
weight matrices and include spatial lag in instrumental variable regression. measures of Maoist control from alternate sources like Ministry of
128 S. Mukherjee / World Development 111 (2018) 113–129

Home Affairs (MHA), police strength in constituencies during elec- creates a new assembly constituency (AC) level dataset for
tions, and perception of an Inspector General of Police collected Chhattisgarh.
during field work in Chhattisgarh. See Tables 6A and 6B in Appen- There are policy implications of my study of Maoist insurgency
dix G and Figs. 3A–3F. in Chhattisgarh, where Maoist violence escalated in 2005 due to
the rise of the vigilante Salwa Judum movement. Since the British
6.5. Relationship between Maoist control and Maoist violence policy of indirect rule was continued by the post-independence
government of Madhya Pradesh (of which Chhattisgarh was a part
I check whether the relationship between Maoist violence and till 2000) into the 1980s, it set up the conditions of weak state
Maoist control is non-linear as suggested by Kalyvas (2006). The capacity, and required the BJP government in Chhattisgarh to indi-
results in Table 7 and Fig. 4 in Appendix G show a non-linear rela- rectly depend on vigilante movement to tackle the Maoists, since
tionship between Maoist control and Maoist violence. they did not have an efficient police force (Miklian, 2009). Also,
while officially the landlord and princes were abolished following
independence, the landlords and landed tribal elites continued to
7. External validity of this study
have power within society and politics (Mahoney, 2000), and it
was a landed elite named Mahendra Karma, who started the Salwa
7.1. Broader testing on all India dataset show similar results
Judum vigilante movement to counter the Maoist threat of dis-
tributing land to tribals. Avoiding such policies of indirect rule
As discussed earlier, using an IV2SLS analysis based on a new
and exploitation would have possibly prevented successful Maoist
instrument on European Wars in an all India dataset, I find that dis-
mobilization, and also not led to the rise of a violent movement like
tricts which had these different forms of indirect rule have a higher
the Salwa Judum in former princely state areas of Chhattisgarh.
probability of Maoist control (Mukherjee, 2018). This shows
broader generalizability of this argument within India. Thinking
beyond the Maoist insurgency, the other cases of insurgency in Acknowledgements
India, like Kashmir and the North Eastern states, also were differ-
ent forms of indirect rule, which future studies should analyze. I acknowledge financial support for research on this topic from
Within India, Jafa (n.d.) suggests, ‘‘A number of areas which the Bri- the USIP dissertation research grant 2008, the NSF doctoral disser-
tish ruled indirectly through native princes or tribal chiefs upto tation grant 2011-12 while a Ph.D. student at Yale university, and
1947 . . . have been in the forefront of dissent or open armed defi- the Connaught New Scholar Grant 2016-17, at the University of
ance . . . The Nagas and the Mizos were ruled through the tribal Toronto.
chieftains and headmen, Manipur and Tripura through their
respective Maharajas. Jammu and Kashmir was ruled indirectly
Appendix A. Supplementary data
through the Maharaja. . . .” So there is generalizability of this theory
to the several cases of insurgency in India.
Supplementary data associated with this article can be found, in
Beyond India: There is potential generalizability of this causal
the online version, at https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2018.06.
mechanism of indirect rule, weak state capacity, and ethnic grie-
013.
vances evident in Chhattisgarh to other similar cases in South Asia
like tribal grievances in the Taliban insurgency in the FATA area of
indirect rule in NWFP in Pakistan (Naseemullah, 2014), the Baluchi References
insurgency in princely states of Kalat in Pakistan (Khan, 2015), the
various ethnic secessionist insurgencies in ‘frontier areas’ of indi- Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. (2001). The colonial origins of comparative
development: An empirical investigation. American Economic Review, 91(5),
rect rule in Burma (Callahan, 2003).58 Outside South Asia, British 1369–1401.
indirect rule allowed the Islamic caliphate and sharia law to con- Angrist, J. D., & Pischke, J.-S. (2009). Mostly harmless econometrics: An empiricist’s
tinue in the north of Nigeria, thus creating conditions for Islamic companion. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Banerjee, A., & Iyer, L. (2005). History, institutions and economic performance: The
movements and more recently the emergence of the Boko Haram legacy of colonial land tenure systems in India. American Economic Review, 95
insurgency in Nigeria’s north (Sampson, 2014: 312-15). This micro- (4), 1190–1213.
level analysis of Chhattisgarh sets the agenda for further research on Banerjee, A., & Somanathan, R. (2007). The political economy of public goods: Some
evidence from India. Journal of Development Economics, 82.
how colonial institutions create conditions for persistence of conflict Baruah, S. (2005). Durable disorder: Understanding the politics of northeast India. New
in other cases. Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Baum, C. F., Schaffer, M. E., & Stillman, S. (2007). Enhanced routines for instrumental
variables: Generalized method of moments estimations and testing. The Stata
8. Conclusion: broader contributions and policy implications Journal, 7(4), 465–506.
Besley, T., & Reynal-Querol, M. (2014). The legacy of historical conflict: Evidence
from Africa. American Political Science Review, 108(2), 319–336.
Historical institutions are potential omitted variables that need Bhatia, B. (2005). The naxalite movement in central Bihar. Economic and Political
to be taken seriously by studies of civil war and Maoist insurgency Weekly, 1536–1549.
in India. This article exploits sub-national variation within the Boone, C. (1994). States and ruling classes in postcolonial Africa: The enduring
contradictions of power. In Migdal, Kohli and Shue (Ed.), State power and social
Indian state of Chhattisgarh, to show the historical origins of forces: Domination and transformation in the third world, pp. 117–118.
sub-national variation in state capacity, and tribal grievances, Boone, C. (2013). Property and political order in Africa: Land rights and the structure of
which were used by Maoist rebels to mobilize successfully. By politics. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Boone, C. (2017). Sons of the soil conflict in Africa: Institutional determinants of
focusing on the causal effects of colonial institutions, and using
ethnic conflict over land. World Development, 96, 276–293.
an instrument for princely state based on the random death of an Bound, J., Jaeger, D., & Baker, R. (1995). Problem with instrumental variables
Indian king, the paper addresses the issue of endogeneity of estimation when the correlation between the instruments and the endogenous
explanatory variable is weak. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 90
socio-economic and state capacity measures to ongoing conflict.
(430), 443–450.
While emerging econometric studies of the Maoist insurgency in Callahan, Mary (2003). Making Enemies: War and State Building in Burma. Ithaca,
India have disaggregated to the district level in India, this paper N.Y.;London: Cornell University Press.
Cederman, L.-E., Wimmer, A., & Min, B. (2010). Why do ethnic groups rebel? New
data and analysis. World Politics, 62(1), 87–119.
58
I describe two shadow cases of the Taliban insurgency in Pakistan and the Maoist Chandra, K. (2004). Why ethnic parties succeed: patronage and ethnic headcounts in
insurgency in Nepal in Appendix J (supplementary files). India. Cambridge, UK; New York: Cambridge University Press.
S. Mukherjee / World Development 111 (2018) 113–129 129

Chandra, K., & Garcia-Ponce, O. (2014). Why subaltern-led parties crowd out armed Miguel, Edward, Satyanath, Shanker, & Sergenti, Ernest (2004). Economic Shocks
violence: Explaining maoist violence in India. Paper presented at workshop on and CivilConflict: An Instrumental Variables Approach. Journal of Political
India’s Maoist insurgency. Princeton University. Economy, 112(4), 725–753.
Dasgupta, A., Gawande, K., & Kapur, D. (2017). (When) do anti-poverty programs Miklian, J. (2009). The purification hunt: The Salwa Judum counterinsurgency in
reduce violence? India’s rural employment guarantee and Maoist conflict. Chhattisgarh, India. Dialectical Anthropology, 33, 441–459.
International Organization, 71(3), 605–632. https://doi.org/10.1017/ Mitchell, E. (1968). Inequality and insurgency: A statistical study of South Vietnam.
S0020818317000236. World Politics, 20(3), 421–438.
Dell, M. (2010). The persistent effects of Peru’s mining mita. Econometrica, 78, Mukherjee, S. (2018). Colonial origins of Maoist insurgency in India: Historical
1863–1903. institutions and civil war. Journal of Conflict Resolution, published online
Dirks, Nicholas (2001). Castes of the Mind: Colonialism and the Making of Modern September, 2017 at http://journals.sagepub.com/doi/full/10.1177/
India. Princeton: Princeton University Press. 0022002717727818
Drukker, D., Peng, H., Prucha, I., & Raciborski, R. (2013). Creating and managing Naseemullah, A. (2014). Shades of sovereignty: Explaining political order and
spatial-weighting matrices with the spmat command. Stata Journal, 13(2), disorder in Pakistan’s northwest. Studies in Comparative International
242–286. Development, 49, 501–522.
Drukker, D., Prucha, I., & Raciborski, R. (2013). A command for estimating spatial- Ramusack, Barbara N. (2004). The Indian Princes and Their States. The New
autoregressive models with spatial-autoregressive disturbances and additional Cambridge History of India. III.6. Cambridge University Press.
endogenous variables. Stata Journal, 13(2), 287–301. Robinson, J. (February 2013). Colombia: Another 100 years of solitude? Current
Fearon, J., & Laitin, D. (2003). Ethnicity, insurgency, and civil war. American Political History.
Science Review, 97(1), 75–90. Salehyan, I., & Gleditsch, K. (2006). Refugees and the spread of civil war.
Fisher, M. H. (1991). Indirect rule in India. Residents and the residency system, 1764- International Organization, 60(2), 335–366.
1858. Delhi: Oxford University Press. Sambanis, N. (2004). Using case studies to expand economic models of civil war.
Foa, R. (2016). Ancient polities, modern states Dissertation. Harvard University. Perspectives on Politics, 2, 259–279.
Gawande, Kishore, Kapur, Devesh, & Satyanath, Shanker (2017). ‘‘Renewable Sampson, I. T. (2014). Religion and the Nigerian state: Situating the de facto and de
Resource Shocks and Conflict Intensity: Findings from India’s Ongoing Maoist jure frontiers of state-religion relations and its implications for national
Insurgency”. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 61(1), 140–172. https://doi.org/ security. Oxford Journal of Law and Religion, 3(2), 311–339.
10.1177/0022002714567949. Sartori, Giovanni (1970). Concept Misformation in Comparative Politics. The
Gerring, J. (2007). Is there a (Viable) crucial-case method? Comparative Political American Political Science Review, 64(4), 1033–1053.
Studies, 40(3), 231–253. Scott, J. (2009). The art of not being governed: An anarchist history of upland Southeast
Gerring, John, Daniel, Ziblatt, Van Gorp, Johan, & Julian, Arevalo (2011). An Asia (p. 2009). New Haven: Yale University Press.
Institutional Theory of Direct and Indirect Rule. World Politics, 63(3), 377–433. Sinha, S. (1989). Maoists in Andhra Pradesh. New Delhi: Gian Publishing House.
Gleditsch, K. (2007). Transnational dimensions of civil war. Journal of Peace Research, Stock, J. H., Wright, J. H., & Yogo, M. (2002). A survey of weak instruments and weak
44(3), 293–309. identification in generalized method of moments. Journal of Business and
Gomes, J. F. (2015). The political economy of the maoist conflict in India: An Economic Statistics, 20, 518–529.
empirical analysis. World Development, 68, 96–123. Sundar, N. (2007). Subalterns and sovereigns: An anthropological history of Bastar
Guardado, J. (2016). ‘‘Forced labor, ethnicity and conflict: Evidence from the Peruvian (1854–2006). Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Mita”, Manuscript, presented at OSU conference on colonialism, June 2016. Teitelbaum, E., & Verghese, A. (2016). Colonialism and armed conflict in the Indian
Gujarati, D. (2004). Basic econometrics (4th ed.). McGraw Hill. countryside. Manuscript.
Hegre, H., & Sambanis, N. (2006). Sensitivity analysis of empirical results on civil Thachil, T. (2011). Embedded mobilization: Nonstate service provision as electoral
war onset. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 50(4), 508–535. strategy in India. World Politics, 63(3), 434–469.
Hoelscher, K., Miklian, J., & Vadlamannati, K. (2012). Hearts and mines: A district- Tudor, Maya., (2013). ‘‘Explaining Democracy’s Origins: Lessons from South Asia”,
level analysis of the Maoist conflict in India. International Area Studies Review, 15 Comparative Politics.
(2), 141–160. Vanden Eynde, O. (2017). Targets of violence: Evidence from India’s Naxalite
Iyer, L. (2010). Direct versus indirect colonial rule in India: Long term consequences. conflict. Manuscript. The Economic Journal, 128(609). https://doi.org/10.1111/
The Review of Economics and Statistics., 92(4), 693–713. ecoj.12438. Forthcoming in.
Jafa, V. S. Unknown date. Administrative policies and ethnic disintegration Verghese, A. (2016a). British rule and tribal revolts in India: The curious case of
engineering conflict in India’s north east. Faultlines, volume 2. Downloaded Bastar. Modern Asian Studies., 50(5).
on August 3, 2015 from http://www.satp.org/satporgtp/publication/faultlines/ Verghese, A. (2016b). The colonial origins of ethnic violence. Stanford University
volume2/Fault2-JafaF.htm. Press.
Jha, S., & Wilkinson, S. (2012). Does combat experience foster organizational skill? Wilkinson, S. (2017). Looking Back at the Colonial Origins of Communal and Caste
Evidence from ethnic cleansing during the partition of South Asia. American Conflict in India. The Wire, at https://thewire.in/110535/communal-violence-
Political Science Review, 106, 883–907. caste-colonialism/.
Kalyvas, S. (2006). The logic of violence in civil war. Cambridge; New York: Wucherpfennig, J., Hunziker, P., & Cederman, L.-E. (2015). Who inherits the state?
Cambridge University Press. Colonial rule and post-colonial conflict. Forthcoming in American Journal of
Kalyvas, S., & Kocher, M. (2009). The dynamics of violence in Vietnam: An analysis Political Science.
of the hamlet evaluation system (HES). Journal of Peace Research, 46(3), Zukerman-Daly, S. (2012). Organizational legacies of violence: Conditions favoring
335–355. insurgency onset in Colombia, 1964–1984. Journal of Peace Research, 49(3),
Kennedy, J., & Purushotham, S. (2012). Beyond naxalbari: A comparative analysis of 473–491.
maoist insurgency and counterinsurgency in independent India. Comparative Government Documents/Reports:
Studies in Society and History, 54(4), 832–862.
Khan, Adeel. (2015). ‘‘Renewed Ethnonationalist Insurgency in Balochistan,
Pakistan”, in Jugdeep Chima, (Ed.), Ethnic Subnationalist Insurgencies in South Baden-Powell, B. H. (1892). The land-systems of British India, Volumes 1–3. Oxford:
Asia, (pp. 125–29). Clarendon Press.
Kohli, A. (2004). State directed development: Political power and industrialization in The imperial gazetteer of India, Volumes 1–26. 1908. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
the global periphery. New York: Cambridge University Press. Chhattisgarh state assembly election – 2003. Chief Electoral Officer, Government of
Lane, M. (2016). The intrastate contagion of ethnic civil War. The Journal of Politics, Chhattisgarh.
78(2), 396–410. Census of India, 1951, Volume VII, Madhya Pradesh, Part 1-A Report, Nagpur, Govt.
Lange, M. (2009). Lineages of despotism and development: British colonialism and state Printing, 1953.
power. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Census of India, 2001, Chhattisgarh Administrative Atlas, published by Directorate
Lange, M., & Dawson, A. (2009). Dividing and ruling the world? A statistical test of of Census Operations, Madhya Pradesh and Chhattisgarh, p. 15, Map 7:
the effects of colonialism on postcolonial civil violence. Social Forces, 88(2), ‘Chhattisgarh Administrative Divisions 2001’.
785–818.
Lee-Warner, S. W. (1910). The native states of India. London: Macmillan and Co., Ltd. Maoist and Human Rights Documents:
Lee, Alexander (2017). Redistributive colonialism: The long term legacy of
international conflict in India. Politics and Society, 45(2), 173–224.
Dandakaranya Special Zonal Committee, CPI-Maoist. 12 Aug 2005. Jan Jagran Nahi,
Lieberman, E. (2005). Nested analysis as a mixed-method strategy for comparative
Jan Daman Abhiyan.
research. American Political Science Review, 99(3), 435–452.
People’s Union of Civil Liberties (PUCL). July 1989. Bastar: Development and
Mahoney, J. (2000). Path dependence in historical sociology. Theory and Society, 29.
Democracy, Madhya Pradesh.
Mahoney, J. (2010). Colonialism and postcolonial development: Spanish America in
Shankar, P. (2006). Yeh Jangal Hamara Hain. New Vitas Publications.
comparative perspective. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Mamdani, M. (1996). Citizen and subject. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Вам также может понравиться