Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 35

Competitive Equilibrium and

Economic Efficiency

Dr. Gong Jie


Agenda

Economic Efficiency
♦ Perfectly competitive equilibrium attains economic
efficiency.
♦ Deadweight Loss
Government Interventions
♦ Price Ceilings and Floors
♦ Excise Tax
Consumer Surplus: Review

Definition: The net economic benefit to the consumer


due to a purchase (i.e. the willingness to pay of the
consumer net of the actual expenditure on the good)
P
♦ The area under an ordinary
demand curve: the benefit
from certain consumption
♦ The area under an ordinary
demand curve and above the
market price provides a
P* measure of consumer surplus.
D

Q
Q*
Producer Surplus: Review
Definition: The net benefit to the producer from
supplying a product.(i.e. the amount that a firm
actually receives from selling a good net of the
minimum amount the firm must receive to be willing
to supply)
P ♦ The area under an ordinary
S supply curve: the cost from
P* certain production
♦ The area under the market
price and above an ordinary
supply curve provides a
measure of producer surplus.

Q
Q*
Total surplus = CS + PS
Price

Consumer Surplus S

P*

Producer Surplus D

Q* Quantity
Price Underproduction

Consumer Surplus
S

Ph

Producer Surplus D

Q Q* Quantity
Price Overproduction

P*

Q* Q Quantity
Perfectly Competitive Equilibrium Attains
Economic Efficiency
 Total surplus is maximized at competitive market
equilibrium.
 How does the competitive market achieve economic
efficiency? “Invisible Hand”!
♦ No central planner: Each consumer maximizes his/her own
utility. Each firm maximizes its own profit.
♦ One price rule and “the right price”: Every consumer who is
willing to pay more than the cost of producing extra output is
able to buy; every consumer who is not willing to pay the cost of
the extra output does not buy.
Economic Efficiency and Deadweight Loss

Benchmark: A market outcome (quantity and price) is


efficient if the total surplus is maximized.
If a market outcome is not efficient, then the market
suffers from deadweight loss.
A deadweight loss is the net loss in total surplus
resulting from an inefficient allocation of resources.
Where does deadweight loss come from?
Price Restrictions

Price Ceilings
♦ The maximum legal price that can be charged
♦ Examples:
 Gasoline prices in the 1970s
 Rent control in New York City
Price Floors
♦ The minimum legal price that can be charged
♦ Examples:
 Minimum wage
 Agricultural price supports
Welfare Without Price Restrictions
Price CS S

P*

PS
Quantity
Q*
Impact of a Price Ceiling
Price S

P*

P Ceiling

Shortage D

Qs Qd Quantity
Q*
Impact of a Price Ceiling

Price CS S

Deadweight Loss
P*

P Ceiling

Shortage D

PS
Qs Qd Quantity
Q*
Impact of a Price Floor
Price
Surplus S
PF

P*

Qd Q* QS Quantity
Impact of a Price Floor
Price
CS Surplus S
PF

Deadweight Loss
P*

PS D

Qd Q* QS Quantity
Comments on minimum wage

Minimum wage law is an example of price floor.


In the labor market, the “product” is labor and the
“price” is the wage.
Raising wage above the market clearing level will
result in more quantity of labor supplied than the
quantity demanded, i.e., unemployment.
How many people a minimum wage adds to the
number of unemployed and the size of the
deadweight loss depend on the elasticity of labor
supply and demand.
Benefits and costs of minimum wage laws

Supporters Opponents
♦ Help the poorest class ♦ Increase unemployment
♦ Encourage people to join ♦ Benefit some workers at
workforce rather than the expense of the poorest
pursuing money through and least productive
illegal means. ♦ Increase labor cost (hurt
♦ Increase work ethic small business more)
♦ Remove low pay jobs and ♦ Jobs move to low-labor-
encourage automation cost areas.
Minimum wage in Singapore
No minimum wage in Singapore
 Parliament debate in 2011: overwhelming majority of
MPs did not support minimum wage law to help low-
skilled and low-wage workers.
 The MP for Bishan-Toa Payoh, Ms Josephine Teo,
pointed out that to be meaningful, a minimum wage must
force some employers to pay more than the market rate.
 “Companies that do not wish to engage in the illegal
practice (of paying below minimum wage) and find it too
costly to operate in Singapore will close shop or
relocate.”
Excise Tax

Excise or specific tax: tax of a certain amount of


money per unit sold.
♦ Without tax, the price that consumers pay(Pd) equals
the price producers receive (Ps).
♦ With an excise tax, what buyers actually pay exceeds
what sellers actually receive.
 Pd=Ps+T
What’s the difference between buyer pay vis-à-vis
seller pay?
Excise Tax Paid by Sellers

P S’
CS S
T
Deadweight Loss
A
Pd
P*
Tax
Ps

D
Q1 Q* Q

PS
When the tax is paid by sellers

Without the tax, equilibrium is at point (P*, Q*)


With tax, the sellers have to pay T per unit sold to the
government.
♦ At a given price P, it is “as if” the market price is P-T to the
sellers. Supply curve shifts upward by T.
♦ The equilibrium is at A, where consumers pay Pd per unit
to the sellers, sellers pay T per unit to the government and
keep Pd – T= Ps per unit. There are Q1 units sold in total.
♦ Consumer and producer surplus both decrease. Part of the
reduction becomes tax revenue, part is deadweight loss.
Excise Tax Paid by Buyers

P
CS S

Deadweight Loss

Pd
P*
Tax
Ps
B
T
D
Q1 Q* Q

PS
When the tax is paid by buyers

Without the tax, equilibrium is at point (P*, Q*)


With tax, the buyers have to pay T per unit purchased
to the government.
♦ At a given price P, it is “as if ” the market price is P+T to
the buyers. Demand curve shifts downward by T.
♦ The equilibrium is at B, where consumers pay Ps per unit to
the sellers and T per unit to the government, a total of Ps +
T=Pd per unit. There are Q1 units sold in total.
♦ Consumer and producer surplus both decrease. Part of the
reduction becomes tax revenue, part is deadweight loss.
Comparison

P S’
S

T
A It does not matter if we shift
Pd the supply or the demand
curve: The market outcome is
P*
the same!
Ps
B T
D
Q1 Q* Q
Who bears the tax burden?

It does not matter who literally pays the tax.


♦ Buyers and sellers share the tax on each unit of the product.
We care about who bears the actual tax burden.
Incidence: change in price for buyer/seller resulting
from changes in demand or supply
♦ The amount by which the price paid by buyers, Pd, rises
over the non-tax equilibrium price, P*, is the incidence of
the tax on consumers; the amount by which the price
received by sellers, PS, falls below P* is the incidence of
the tax on producers.
If demand is relatively inelastic at (P*, Q*)

P S’
S
Increase in
T Consumers bear most
consumers’ price
Pd of the tax burden.

P*
Ps
Decrease in
producers’ price

D
Q2 Q* Q
If demand is relatively elastic at (P*, Q*)

P S’
S
Increase in
T Producers bear most
consumers’ price
of the tax burden.
Pd
P*
Decrease in
producers’ price Ps
D

Q3 Q* Q
Incidence of a tax depends on the price
elasticity of demand and supply
If demand is less elastic than supply at the
competitive equilibrium, the tax will have a larger
impact on consumers’ price.
If demand is more elastic than supply at the
competitive equilibrium, the tax will have a larger
impact on producers’ price.
The side of the market that is relatively less sensitive
to price changes will bear larger portion of the tax.
Impact of taxes on alcohol and tobacco?
“Pass-through” rule
ΔP d η ΔQ s / Q s ΔQ d / Q d
 = where η= ,ε =
ΔP s
ε ΔP / P
s s
ΔP d / P d
♦ η, ε is the own price elasticity of supply and demand,
respectively.
Proof (optional):
♦ Consider equilibrium (P*,Q*), Ps = Pd = P*, Qs = Qd = Q*
♦ A tax increases Pd and decreases Ps. Both Qs and Qd drop.
♦ For market to clear, the change in quantity demanded and
supplied should be the same. ΔQ s / Q* =ΔQ d / Q *
♦ Thus η ΔP d
/ P d
ΔP d
= =
ε ΔP s / P s ΔP s
Example: Incidence of a Tax

Let ε = -.5 and η = 2. What is the relative incidence


of a specific tax on consumers and producers?
♦ ΔPd/ΔPs = 2/(-.5) = -4
Interpretation:
♦ The increase in the price consumers pay will be four
times as much as the decrease in price producers
receive. Hence, an excise tax of $1 results in an
increase in consumer price of $.8 and a decrease in
price received by producers of $.2.
The Important Lessons We Learned

When firms experience negative supply shock


(marginal cost increases), the cost increase cannot be
fully shifted to consumers.
When firms experience positive supply shock
(marginal cost decreases), the cost reduction cannot
fully accrue to consumers.
Applications

 “(March 9, 2006, The Wall Street


Journal) …Soaring fuel prices were bad news for
all airlines last year, .… The airline (Cathay Pacific)
said passenger and cargo fuel surcharges only
partly offset this additional cost…”
♦ Why do passenger and cargo fuel surcharges only partly
offset this additional cost?
 Manufacturer Promotion
♦ Cents-off coupons to consumers vs. Wholesale price-cut
to retailers
♦ Which makes more sale?
Takeaways

An "invisible hand" guides the competitive market to


the efficient level of production and consumption.
Although the buyers and sellers act selfishly, the net
outcome is at least as good as the best efforts of the
most enlightened and well-informed central planner.

We obtained the above conclusion for a single market


only and under the assumption that price fully reflects
all costs and benefits to the market and that there is
perfect information. We will relax these assumptions
in subsequent lectures.
Government policies such as price ceilings, price
floors, and taxes cause deadweight losses and impede
economic efficiency.
Who pays a tax does not determine who bears the tax.
Even though all policies resulted in a reduction in
total surplus, each had a "constituency" in the form of
consumers, producers or the government (effect on
budget). If total surplus maximization is not the goal
of policy-makers, each policy can be argued for on
economic grounds.

Вам также может понравиться