Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 74

EFMD

 Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
The  Quants’  Impact  on  Management  Education  -­‐  and  What  We  Might  Do  About  It:  
A  History-­‐Framed  Essay  Rethinking  the  MBA  Program  
 
J.-­‐C.  Spender,  ESADE  &  LUSEM  
jcspender@yahoo.com  
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
Prepared  for  the  1st  Annual  EFMD  Higher  Education  Research  Conference  
The  Transformation  of  Higher  Education  Institutions  and  Business  Schools  
Zurich,  February  14th  &  15th,  2012  
 

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  1  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

 
 
 
 
“I  often  say  that  when  you  can  measure  what  you  are  speaking  about,  and  express  it  in  numbers,  you  know  
something  about  it;  but  when  you  cannot  measure  it,  when  you  cannot  express  it  in  numbers,  your  knowledge  
is  of  a  meagre  and  unsatisfactory  kind;  it  may  be  the  beginning  of  knowledge,  but  you  have  scarcely  in  your  
thoughts  advanced  to  the  state  of  Science,  whatever  the  matter  may  be.”    Baron  William  Thomson  Kelvin  
(1824-­‐1907)  -­‐  From  'Electrical  Units  of  Measurement',  a  lecture  delivered  at  the  Institution  of  Civil  Engineers,  
London  (3  May  1883).  
 
“The  saying  often  quoted  from  Lord  Kelvin  (though  the  substance,  I  believe,  is  much  older)  that  "where  you  
cannot  measure  your  knowledge  is  meagre  and  unsatisfactory,"  as  applied  in  mental  and  social  science,  is  
misleading  and  pernicious.  This  is  another  way  of  saying  that  these  sciences  are  not  sciences  in  the  sense  of  
physical  science,  and  cannot  attempt  to  be  such,  without  forfeiting  their  proper  nature  and  function.    
Insistence  on  a  concretely  quantitative  economics  means  the  use  of  statistics  of  physical  magnitudes,  whose  
economic  meaning  and  significance  is  uncertain  and  dubious.    (Even  ‘wheat’  is  approximately  homogeneous  
only  if  measured  in  economic  terms.)    And  a  similar  statement  would  apply  even  more  to  other  social  
sciences.    In  this  field,  the  Kelvin  dictum  very  largely  means  in  practice,  "if  you  cannot  measure,  measure  
anyhow!"    That  is,  one  either  performs  some  other  operation  and  calls  it  measurement  or  measures  
something  else  instead  of  what  is  ostensibly  under  discussion,  and  usually  not  a  social  phenomena.    To  call  
averaging  estimates,  or  guesses,  measurement  seems  to  be  merely  embezzling  a  word  for  its  prestige  value.    
And  it  might  be  pointed  out  also  that  in  the  field  of  human  interests  and  relationships  much  of  our  most  
important  knowledge  is  inherently  non-­‐quantitative,  and  could  not  conceivably  be  put  in  quantitative  form  
without  being  destroyed.    Perhaps  we  do  not    "know"  that  our  friends  really  are  our  friends;  in  any  case  an  
attempt  to  measure  their  friendship  would  hardly  make  the  knowledge  either  more  certain  or  more  
‘satisfactory’"!    Knight  F.  H.  1940.  What  is  Truth  in  Economics?  Journal  of  Political  Economy  48(1):18n  
 
 
Contents:  
Introduction                3  
The  Business  Schools'  Situation            9  
The  Rise  of  the  Quants             18  
From  Conglomerates  to  Casino  Capitalism         24  
BSchools'  Challenges             37  
Concluding  Comments             48  
Bibliography               58  
 

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  2  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

Introduction  
 
Our  conference  is  about  the  transformation  of  higher  education  in  general  and  business  schools  
in  particular.    I  have  not  administered  a  university  so  I  do  not  really  know  what  is  involved  in  
making  them  better;  although  there  is  plenty  of  advice  around,  and  probably  all  sorely  needed  (Bok,  
2003;  Lewis,  2007;  O'Brien,  1998;  Owton,  2011;  Rhoades  &  Sporn,  2002;  Zemsky,  Wegner,  &  Massy,  
2005).    But  I  have  been  an  entrepreneur,  banker,  and  Dean  of  a  business  school  and  sense  some  of  
what  business  schools  are  up  to  and  might  or  might  not  do  in  the  future.    I  see  this  topic  as  
intellectually  appealing  and  probably  important  -­‐  certainly  to  our  students  if  no  one  else.    Not  
everyone  agrees,  of  course,  so  I  accept  that  some  will  find  my  essay  neither  improving  nor  
interesting.    Notwithstanding,  I  hope  it  might  intrigue  a  few  towards  new  thoughts.    I  also  hope  my  
longish  bibliography  will  help  some  researchers,  especially  those  in  business  schools,  touch  fields  of  
research  lying  beyond  our  discipline’s  central  journals.  
     
Some  have  queried  whether  business  schools  (BSchools)  belong  in  universities  at  all,  given  their  
long  history  outside  them  and  that  most  business  education  takes  place  elsewhere.    Widespread  
criticism  of  BSchools’  doings  has  raised  questions  though  without,  it  seems,  generating  much  clarity  
on  how  they  might  be  dealt  with.    Some  think  we  are  at  an  impasse  and  do  not  know  where  to  go  or  
what  has  been  achieved  -­‐  that  we  have  lost  our  way  (Bennis  &  O'Toole,  2005;  Mintzberg,  2004;  
Stewart,  2009)  or  that  what  we  achieved  was  too  late  (Rehder,  1982).    Others  suggest  we  have  
achieved  much  and  are  simply  being  challenged  to  do  better  (Behrman  &  Levin,  1984;  Bisoux,  2007;  
Cheit,  1985;  DeAngelo,  DeAngelo,  &  Zimmerman,  2005;  Durand  &  Dameron,  2008;  Hay  &  
Hodgkinson,  2008;  JMS  Editors,  2004;  Khurana  &  Penrice,  2011;  Kuchinke,  2007;  Lorange,  2005,  
2008;  McCormack,  1989;  Morsing  &  Sauquet,  2011;  Pfeffer,  2007;  Pfeffer  &  Fong,  2002);  
Zimmerman  wondered  about  BSchools’  survival  (Zimmerman,  2001).    In  contrast,  other  authors  
(Cornuel,  2005;  Ewing,  1990),  and  especially  the  AACSB  establishment  (Fernandes,  2004,  2005),  
see  our  industry  through  remarkably  rosy  spectacles  -­‐  onwards  and  upwards.    But  the  debate  is  
more  often  a  clash  of  opinions  than  evidence-­‐based.  
 
In  contrast  to  the  fact-­‐lite  hubbub  characterizing  the  conversation  since  the  1970s,  a  group  of  
energetic  management  education  historians  has  opened  up  new  ways  of  analyzing  what  we  do  
(Aaronson,  1992;  Augier  &  March,  2011;  Cooper,  2011;  Daniel,  1998;  Engwall,  2004,  2007;  Engwall  
&  Danell,  2011;  Engwall  &  Zamagni,  1998;  Hanlon,  1996;  Hugstad,  1983;  Khurana,  2007;  R.  R.  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  3  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

Locke,  1984,  1989,  1996,  1998,  2004;  R.  R.  Locke  &  Schone,  2004;  O'Connor,  2011;  Thomas  &  
Wilson,  2011;  Wensley,  2011;  Witzel,  2011).    Historians  have  lots  of  freedom,  especially  in  picking  
their  research  questions.    Thus  some  simply  assume  BSchools  exist  and  tell  the  story  of  their  
multiplication  or  shifting  status  in  the  university.    Others  that  BSchools  exist  but  are  not  doing  what  
they  could  or  should.    Others  see  them  as  unproblematic  entities,  ‘professional  schools’  whose  
nature  seems  pretty  obvious,  with  problems  that  can  be  analyzed  reflexively  through  the  theories  
taught  in  the  schools  -­‐  'physician  heal  thyself'.    Some  see  BSchools  responding  ‘isomorphically’  to  
their  environment  (D.  Wilson  &  McKiernan,  2011).    Others  see  them  as  professional  service  entities,  
originating  in  Europe,  reconstituted  dynamically  by  'social  leadership  processes'  (Fragueiro  &  
Thomas,  2011).    Others,  focusing  narrowly  on  the  MBA  degree,  see  them  as  little  more  than  its  
constructors  and  deliverers  (Datar,  Garvin,  &  Cullen,  2010;  Friga,  Bettis,  &  Sullivan,  2003).      
 
Those  in  the  institutionalist  tradition  of  Douglass  North  do  not  take  the  BSchools’  existence  for  
granted  and  ask  (a)  why  they  exist  and  (b)  what  characteristics  might  differentiate  them  from  other  
social  institutions.    Whitley,  for  example,  suggested  they  exist  as  a  means  for  the  elite  in  our  
democratic  capitalist  society  to  maintain  its  grip  in  the  face  of  social  and  technological  changes  
(Whitley,  Thomas,  &  Marceau,  1981).    Khurana,  in  contrast,  argued  business  schools  came  into  
existence  to  meet  a  national  anxiety  at  the  end  of  the  19th  century  about  the  selection,  education  
and  evaluation  of  private-­‐sector  managers  as  their  power  and  impact  was  growing  rapidly  
(Khurana,  2007).    They  would  be  the  instruments  of  a  national  'professionalization  project'  to  
transform  management  into  a  profession  -­‐  like  medicine,  engineering  or  law,  with  their  policed  
modes  of  professional  selection,  education,  credentialing,  appointment,  practice  assessment,  and  so  
on.    The  project  developed  a  substantial  literature  between  1900  and  1935  (Drucker,  2005;  
Henderson,  1927;  Jarausch,  1982;  Light,  1983;  Lowell,  1923;  Metcalf,  1926,  1927).    But  we  know  
there  are  difficulties  with  this,  given  entry  into  management  remains  in  management's  hands  and  
un-­‐policed  by  professional  bodies  like  the  AMA,  ASME  or  ABA.    Nor,  as  yet,  is  there  a  demarcated  
and  policed  body  of  knowledge  on  which  a  profession  might  be  put  in  place.    Nor  is  there  much  
evidence  from  the  last  century  of  management  research  that  this  is  going  to  appear  anytime  soon.    
 
A  rather  different  analysis  opens  up  when  attention  shifts  from  BSchools  as  social  or  
institutional  entities  and  onto  the  components  of  their  curricula.    This  leads  to  different  research  
questions,  of  course,  less  why  do  BSchools  exist  than  why  this  or  that  material  is  in  the  curriculum,  
what  it  might  equip  students  to  do,  how  it  fits  with  the  curriculum's  other  materials,  and  is  the  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  4  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

pedagogical  objective  to  teach  theory  or  skilled  practice,  or  should  it  be  studied  individually  or  in  
groups?    In  this  essay  I  look  at  the  present  challenges  to  BSchools  through  the  lens  of  the  
quantitative  methods  that  are  now  the  major  component  in  the  curriculum.    These  methods  have  
sometimes  been  highlighted  to  indicate  where  we  have  gone  wrong.    The  criticism  that  quantitative  
methods  loom  too  large  in  the  curriculum  goes  back  many  decades  and  has  been  much  repeated  
recently,  yet  was  crisply  put  by  Harvard  President  Bok  in  his  1977  commentary  on  the  state  of  the  
Harvard  Business  School  (Bok,  1978;  Keller  &  Keller,  2001:442).    The  criticism  has  recently  
morphed  into  the  charge  that  teaching  business  students  mathematics,  statistics,  quantitative  
methods  and,  especially,  neoclassical  micro  economics  (or  mathematical  economics)  de-­‐socializes  
them  and  turns  them  into  greedy  destructive  egoists  when  they  get  their  hands  on  financial  or  
organizational  power  (Ferraro,  Pfeffer,  &  Sutton,  2005;  Ghoshal,  2005;  Ghoshal  &  Moran,  1996;  Iida  
&  Oda,  2011;  Pfeffer,  2005).    In  lieu  of  cod-­‐liver  oil,  they  need  a  strong  dose  of  business  ethics.  
 
I  do  not  think  this  a  useful  way  to  think  about  the  challenges  management  education  faces,  in  
part  because  it  pays  insufficient  attention  to  our  increasingly  quantified  society.    But  our  analysis  is  
always  prisoner  to  our  assumptions,  and  if  we  take  BSchools  for  granted,  as  many  do,  I  think  we  
lose  hold  of  the  debate  immediately.    The  question  of  why  BSchools  exist  is  pivotal,  for  the  answer,  
explicit  or  not,  sets  the  grounds  for  every  author’s  analysis  and  its  possible  conclusions.    Ignoring  
the  question  leaves  the  analysis  poorly  structured  at  best.    Thus  the  first  part  of  my  essay  reviews  
our  situation  and  explores  why  BSchools  exist  and  how  they  might  be  critiqued.    For  instance,  are  
they  doing  something  they  should  not  be  doing,  or  not  doing  something  they  should  be  doing  -­‐  like  
teaching  business  ethics  or  ‘green’  management?    After  rejecting  the  suggestion  that  the  BSchools  
had  much  to  do  with  the  present  financial  turmoil  I  conclude  our  core  difficulty  is  that  we  have  no  
viable  theory  of  the  managed  private  sector  firm,  and  without  it  little  way  of  knowing  whether  what  
we  are  doing  is  right  or  wrong.    This  lack  clearly  stands  in  the  way  of  our  playing  a  part  in  
professionalizing  management;  even  assuming  this  is  our,  or  their,  objective  -­‐  which  I  doubt.      
 
In  the  second  section  I  narrow  the  discussion  onto  quantitative  methods  and  examine  the  long-­‐
term  societal  trend  to  their  greater  use  and  our  rising  trust  in  numbers  as  part  of  the  cultural  shift  
towards  ‘modernism’  and  the  belief  the  important  things  in  life  can  be  theorized  and  brought  under  
our  control  by  using  quantitative  methods,  including  those  of  science  (Pettigrew,  2001).    This  
section  relies  heavily  on  Theodore  Porter's  historical  analysis  (T.  M.  Porter,  1995).    In  the  third  
section  of  the  essay  I  look  at  how  quantitative  methods  came  to  dominate  the  BSchool  curriculum  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  5  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

as  they  do  today.    Their  introduction  was  not  the  result  of  an  innovative  curriculum  move  by  some  
far-­‐seeing  transformational  academic.    Rather  it  was  a  widespread  response  to  the  changing  
markets  into  which  the  BSchools  intended  their  graduates  to  move  -­‐  a  convoluted  way  of  saying  
'because  business  wanted  it'.    This  leads  to  my  general  thesis  that  the  BSchool  curriculum  was  
developed  less  by  educational  innovations  from  within  than  as  relatively  opportunistic  responses  to  
the  demands  without.    There  is  nothing  novel  about  this  argument,  of  course,  but  it  reframes  the  
history  of  management  education  as  one  of  educators  passively  following  the  history  of  
management  -­‐  especially  as  viewed  through  their  sometimes  questionable  notions  of  management  
practice  (D.  Wilson  &  McKiernan,  2011).    The  principal  weakness  with  this  strategy  arose  because  
the  schools  lacked  (as  we  still  lack  today)  a  definitive  practical  managerial  theory  of  the  private  
sector  firm.    As  a  result  administrators  and  faculty  had  no  way  of  analyzing  or  justifying  how  any  
proposed  new  component  of  the  curriculum  related  to  managerial  practice  and  thus  to  a  curriculum  
intended  to  equip  students  for  that  practice.    Equally  important,  they  were  not  able  to  evaluate  the  
market  opportunities  that  were  arising  and  how  firms’  self-­‐directed  needs  might  be  balanced  
against  or  meshed  with  either  the  student's  educational  needs  or  the  broader  social  needs  being  
addressed  by  the  university.      
 
Somewhat  following  along  with  Khurana's  argument  as  he  outlined  three  phases  of  US  business  
school  evolution,  I  suggest  the  BSchools'  sense  of  why  they  were  teaching  quantitative  methods  was  
market-­‐driven  and  has  gone  through  five  historical  phases.    The  first  was  suggested  by  Khurana’s  
notion  of  an  earlier  time,  when  the  curriculum  objective  was  to  train  individuals  into  managing  as  a  
‘social  duty’.    The  second  phase  extending  from  around  1900  to  WW2,  to  supply  the  metrics  and  
accounting-­‐based  skills  necessary  to  implement  the  measurement  and  control  systems  introduced  
by  the  pioneers  of  Scientific  Management  led  to  the  period  of  'managerial  capitalism'  (Smiddy  &  
Naum,  1954).    A  third  ‘conglomerate  and  M&A’  phase,  especially  in  the  1960s,  saw  BSchools  
providing  the  new  tools  for  cash-­‐flow  management,  corporate  financial  analysis,  corporate  
governance  and  corporate  valuation  that  enabled  firms  to  increase  in  size  and  complexity  in  the  
years  after  WW2.    Fourth,  in  the  1970s,  as  the  business  emphasis  switched  from  enlarging  and  
sustaining  complex  corporations  to  maximizing  the  returns  to  free-­‐floating  investors,  schools  
provided  the  analytic  tools  for  'investor  capitalism',  institutionally  demarcated  by  managers'  
willingness  to  asset-­‐strip,  break  firms  up  and  sell  their  parts,  or  liquidate  them  entirely  so  long  as  it  
made  'financial  sense'  to  the  stockholders.      
 

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  6  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

But  the  core  of  my  thesis  is  about  a  fifth  phase,  arising  in  the  1980s,  when  BSchools  moved  to  
support  the  financial  services  industry's  switch  into  what  Keynes  labeled  'casino  capitalism'  
(Keynes,  2009:132).    I  suggest  Khurana's  notions  of  managing  (1)  as  social  duty,  (2)  in  pursuit  of  
firm  efficiency,  and  (3)  as  a  service  to  institutional  shareholders  can  be  usefully  elaborated  by  
separating  his  investor  capitalist  phase  into  (a)  a  conglomerate  and  M&A  phase,  and  (b)  a  
shareholder  capitalist  phase,  and  then  extending  the  historical  sequence  to  a  fifth  phase  of  ‘casino  
capitalism’  (Hanlon,  1996;  McKenzie,  2011;  Strange,  1997).    The  explosive  growth  of  this  last  phase  
persuaded  market-­‐following  BSchools  to  provide  for  that  niche,  perhaps  at  the  expense  of  their  
traditional  markets.    The  new  tools  necessary  included  the  high-­‐level  mathematical  skills  necessary  
to  model  ‘risk’  and  price  options,  derivatives,  and  a  host  of  new  ‘financial  products’  (Avellaneda,  
1999;  Benninga,  2008).    The  rapid  expansion  of  this  activity  precipitated  the  era  of  'rocket  scientist'  
quants  (Ayres,  2007;  Patterson,  2010).    They  helped  usher  in  a  new  universe  of  mathematically-­‐
based  trading  that  further  encouraged  the  development  of  next  generation  financial  products  such  
as  options,  derivatives,  swaps,  collateralized  debt  obligations  (CDOs),  contracts  for  difference  
(CFDs),  and  ‘algotrades’,  among  others,  and  the  creation  and  rapid  expansion  of  shadow  markets  in  
which  these  products  could  be  traded.    Their  rise  has  been  widely  blamed  for  the  financial  collapse  
(Partnoy,  2004;  Sorkin,  2009;  Zeckhauser,  2010).      
 
While  Khurana's  narrative  framed  his  three  phases  as  somewhat  'paradigmatic'  (Figure  1)  each  
displaced  in  a  Kuhnian  paradigm  shift,  I  see  the  five  phases  above  as  more  accumulative  (Figure  2)  
although  interpenetrated  and  mutually  reinforcing  as  each  phase  persisted  to  some  degree  even  
when  it  seemed  overtaken  in  business  and  career  attractiveness  by  a  later  phase.    However,  the  
later  phases  I  particular  encroached  into  the  world  of  finance  and,  impelled  by  that,  led  to  a  
quantitative  'colonizing'  of  the  BSchool  curriculum  (Fine  &  Green,  2000).    Those  specialized  in  
researching  and  teaching  these  methods  began  to  dominate  the  schools'  internal  politics  and  
resource  allocation  struggles.    There  was  a  steady  transition  in  ideology  and  ethos  as  the  in-­‐school  
trends  were  both  driven  and  materially  empowered  and  reinforced  by  the  national  political  and  
ideological  shifts  that  led  to  the  rise  of  rational  choice  liberalism  (Amadae,  2003;  Duménil  &  Lévy,  
2011;  R.  R.  Locke  &  Spender,  2011;  Peck,  2010).    
 

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  7  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

Social  Duty  

Managerial  Capitalism  

Investor  Capitalism  
 
        Figure  1:  Khurana’s  Three  Phases  
 

Social  Duty  

Managerial  Capitalism  

Conglomerate  -­‐  M&A  

Shareholder  Capitalism  

Casino  Capitalism  
 
        Figure  2:  Spender’s  Five  Phases  
 
Since  the  job  opportunities  created  during  the  fifth  period  of  casino  capitalism  are  still  there  for  
quantitatively  oriented  BBAs  and  MBAs,  not  significantly  diminished  by  any  post-­‐collapse  
regulations,  such  as  the  Dodd-­‐Frank  Wall  Street  Reform  and  Consumer  Protection  Act  (2010),  any  
prescription  to  have  BSchools  make  less  of  quantitative  methods  is  misconceived.    The  prescription  
mistakes  the  problem  and  shows  we  need  a  new  diagnosis.    My  essay  outlines  a  different  
interpretation  of  today's  BSchool  challenge,  focused  on  developing  a  better  understanding  of  how  
these  powerful  quantitative  methods  might  be  fitted  into  an  education  that  is  less  reactive,  less  
passively  conceived  and  less  abandoned  to  the  financial  sector's  evolving  needs,  even  as  our  
students  are  inevitably  attracted  by  the  extraordinary  returns  from  working  in  ‘trading’  and  the  
new  parts  of  the  financial  services  industry.    It  is  sheer  hypocrisy  for  us  to  pretend  to  modesty  and  
asceticism  from  the  comfort  of  tenure,  given  the  students'  increasingly  turbulent  world  -­‐  atop  the  
relentless  rise  in  college  fees,  leading  to  stunning  student  debt  and  its  extraordinary  burdens,  to  say  
nothing  of  pervasive  cheating  (McCabe,  Dukerich,  &  Dutton,  1994;  Molho,  1997).    At  the  root  of  this  
is  our  failure  to  develop  a  theory  of  the  managed  private  sector  firm  that  can  be  used  as  a  
touchstone  for  directing  curriculum  choices  and  research.    With  this  in  hand  we  would  know  how  
quantitative  methods  fit  into  the  curriculum,  how  they  integrate  with  the  other  subjects  we  think  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  8  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

should  also  be  taught,  and  so  on.    In  my  concluding  section  I  review  some  indications  of  what  this  
theory  might  look  like  and  the  educational  activity  implied.    I  question  the  cost  to  our  students  of  
organizing  the  MBA  curriculum  along  disciplinary  lines,  in  spite  of  its  convenience  to  faculty,  and  
suggest  a  curriculum  based  on  (a)  the  different  kinds  of  firm  suggested  by  a  multi-­‐phase  historical  
analysis,  and  (b)  the  different  methodologies  that  we  always  need  to  complement  the  quantitative  
methods  now  dominating  our  research  and  teaching.  
 
As  Khurana  noted,  there  has  been  a  recent  ‘turn’  towards  leadership  and  entrepreneurship  
studies,  and  the  student  body  seems  interested  in  these.    Many  Deans  feel  these  can  provide  the  
basis  for  curriculum  reform.    But  they  have  been  around  for  a  long  time.    Leadership  was  a  major  
topic  in  Greek  and  Roman  thought  while  theorizing  entrepreneurship  goes  back  to  Cantillon  at  least  
(Cantillon,  2001).    Plus  there  is  as  little  evidence  of  viable  teachable  theory  here  as  there  is  of  a  
useful  theory  of  the  managed  firm,  so  it  is  not  clear  whether  this  turn  is  forwards  or  backwards.    Of  
course,  the  deeper  answer  to  the  question  of  'what  is  to  be  done  about  the  quants'  is  neither  
technical  nor  theoretical;  it  is  a  more  fundamental  professional  one,  whether  our  community  is  to  
take  back  the  educational  initiative,  and  the  abandoned  moral  high-­‐ground,  or  remain  forever  in  fee  
to  market  forces.    The  irony  being  that  over  the  last  century  management  education  has  become  a  
profession  in  every  sense  of  the  word,  while  management  remains  something  else,  perhaps  a  
practice,  perhaps  an  ideology  (Spender,  2007b).  
 
 
The  Business  Schools'  Situation  
 
The  many  critics  of  business  schools,  this  author  included,  need  to  come  to  terms  with  
management  education’s  obvious  successes  -­‐  which  is  not  to  say  we  could  not  do  better.    But  the  
critics  are  not  merely  urging  better;  they  hope  to  strike  deeper  and  show  something  is  deeply  
wrong  (Bennis  &  O'Toole,  2005;  I.  Berg,  2003;  Crainer  &  Dearlove,  1999;  Hayes  &  Abernathy,  1980;  
Mintzberg,  2004;  Navarro,  2008;  Starkey  &  Tiratsoo,  2007).    At  the  same  time  we  can  appreciate  
BSchools  are  older  than  most  realize  and  have  been  criticized  for  centuries,  as  have  the  US  schools  
since  their  inception  around  the  turn  of  the  20th  century  (Redlich,  1957;  Spender,  2005,  2007b).    
The  criticism  does  not  seem  to  have  impacted  the  schools’  behavior  or  their  growth  and  
proliferation;  so  the  boosters  and  the  critics  seem  to  be  in  parallel  universes,  neither  paying  much  
attention  to  the  others'  arguments.    Focusing  on  something  BSchools  are  actually  doing,  teaching  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  9  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

quantitative  methods,  helps  bridge  these  positions.    Quantitative  methods'  dominance  has  also  
provided  some  critics  with  their  target,  but  attempts  to  value  quantitative  methods  against  some  
real  or  imagined  opportunity  cost  lead  to  little  more  than  academic  squabbling  -­‐  such  as  the  curious  
continuing  discussion  about  whether  teaching  students  economics  makes  them  antisocial  or  
narcissistic  (Iida  &  Oda,  2011;  Westerman,  Bergman,  Bergman,  &  Daly,  forthcoming).    Some  of  our  
best  friends  are  economists!    There  are  also  accountants,  reaching  back  centuries  with  their  
separate  programs  and  accreditation,  equally  nourished  by  numbers  (Brown  et  al.,  2009;  Previts  &  
Merino,  1998).  
 
Business  studies  are  typically  at  four  levels;  undergraduate,  masters,  doctoral  and  executive.    
The  critics'  focus  is  primarily  on  the  MBA  programs,  somewhat  towards  the  BBA  programs,  but  
seldom  towards  the  PhD  and  DBA.    The  executive  programs  are  curiously  under-­‐criticized,  perhaps  
on  the  grounds  that  the  market's  view  is  all  the  comment  required  -­‐  and,  caveat  emptor,  academics  
cannot  add  anything  to  free-­‐market  forces.    So  even  though  exec  programs  are  the  major  activity  at  
many  schools  I  exclude  them  from  this  essay.    The  business  studies  part  of  the  BBA  curriculum  is  
often  similar  to  the  MBA  curriculum,  perhaps  'watered-­‐down',  perhaps  identical.    The  doctoral  level  
is  primarily  oriented  towards  training  faculty  for  the  BBA  and  MBA  programs  and  deserves  its  own  
critics,  so  I  shall  not  consider  it  either.    Rather  than  evaluate  the  MBA  syllabus  course  by  course,  I  
turn  to  recent  research  into  the  history  of  BSchools  in  the  US  and  elsewhere.    Our  discipline's  
history  is  little  appreciated  even  though  it  provides  important  insights  into  what  we  do  and  why.    
When  it  comes  to  quantitative  methods,  it  is  useful  to  see  how  we  got  to  teach  them  in  the  first  place  
and  what  was  expected.    Accepting  the  fact  that  we  teach  them,  we  can  explore  the  criticism  that  
BSchools  have  lost  some  desired  balance.    If  this  is  to  be  more  than  academic  snobbery,  the  critic's  
obligation  is  to  spell  out  and  justify  a  better  balance,  and  this  is  not  so  easy.    We  might  extend  the  
undergraduate  principle  of  balancing  a  major's  quantitative  orientation,  such  as  chemistry  or  
engineering,  with  a  substantial  dose  of  liberal  arts  in  order  to  produce  a  more  'rounded'  individual.    
This  principle  is  ancient  and  recalls  Newman  or  Pelikan  (Pelikan,  1992),  applies  to  all  the  sciences,  
is  not  peculiar  to  business  studies,  and  may  have  little  relevance  to  post-­‐graduate  work  anyway,  
raising  questions  about  what  is  to  be  expected  of  an  MBA  degree.  Alternatively  we  might  argue  that  
a  better  balance  of  study  and  co-­‐op/lab/simulation/practice  would  be  better  preparation  for  the  
workplace  (Berggren  &  Söderlund,  2011;  Revans,  1971;  Schön,  1983,  1987);  though  this  idea  is  
hostage  to  the  claim  that  the  MBA  is  meaningful  preparation  for  managerial  work,  something  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  10  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

neither  demonstrated  by  graduates'  performance  nor  reflected  in  the  empirical  data  on  how  they  
value  their  experience.  
 
The  historical  analysis  confirms  what  we  all  know,  that  over  the  last  century  BSchools  (a)  have  
followed  a  rapidly  expanding  market  for  the  kind  of  management  education  we  actually  deliver,  and  
(b)  have  become  firmly  institutionalized  into  the  processes  of  private  sector  management  selection  
and  employment.    The  BSchool's  various  rankings,  commercial  and  institutional,  such  as  the  UK's  
RAE,  bear  directly  on  its  place  in  these  processes,  so  we  see  many  schools  have  worked  hard  to  
perfect  their  curriculum,  and  to  burnish  their  reputations  and  attract  private  funding  to  supplement  
their  fee  income  so  as  to  apply  that  towards  improving  their  ranking.    It  may  be  that  no  other  goals  
matter,  the  market  speaks  and  growth,  market  penetration  and  rankings  are  all  that  count.    The  
very  different  proposition  that  management  is  or  should  be  a  profession  in  the  way  medicine,  
architecture  and  engineering  are  stands  against  this.    Khurana's  'higher  aims'  provided  a  strong  
narrative  line  for  his  history  of  the  American  schools,  but  it  may  not  clarify  any  specific  BSchools'  
origins,  situation  or  activities,  or  help  us  see  what  to  do  ‘going  forward’.    As  ‘professional  schools’,  
as  they  are  often  called,  BSchools  have  closer  parallels  with  law  schools  than  with  medical,  
architecture  or  engineering  schools,  for  those  stand  on  solid  ‘knowledge  foundations’,  even  
scientific.    Yet  in  comparison  with  law  schools  significant  differences  remain.    All  professional  
schools  present  their  host  universities  with  challenges,  especially  when  they  are  growing  fast  and  
they  are  still  viewed  as  academically  questionable  by  other  faculty.    But  it  seems  off  the  mark  to  
criticize  the  BSchools  for  the  problems  they  create  within  the  university  when  those  same  
universities  were  party  to  those  schools'  creation.  
 
If  business  education  is  to  be  'improved'  beyond  the  brute  fact  of  more  successfully  meeting  the  
market's  needs,  measured  by  the  number  of  BBA  and  MBA  applicants,  student  retention  rates  and  
satisfaction,  and  the  school's  rankings,  the  critics  must  focus  on  something  the  schools  should  be  
doing  but  are  not  -­‐  or  are  doing,  and  in  spite  of  good  market  acceptance,  should  not  be.    To  pillory  
the  BSchools  for  teaching  economics  is  absurd  and  illogical  if  we  are  not  also  going  to  complain  
about  the  provision  of  economics  degrees  elsewhere.    To  pillory  BSchools  for  teaching  quantitative  
methods  makes  no  sense.    Likewise,  teaching  theory  as  opposed  to  'best  practice'  remains  a  major  
problem  for  all  professional  schools  as  they  struggle  with  the  tension  between  analysis  and  skilled  
practice.    There  is  nothing  peculiar  to  BSchools  here  and  anyway,  in  this  litigious  age,  BSchools  
would  be  unwise  even  to  claim  they  prepare  students  for  managerial  practice.    The  tension  between  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  11  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

theory  and  practice  goes  back  to  the  roots  of  Western  philosophy  and  the  well-­‐appreciated  gulf  
between  generalities  -­‐  the  language  of  analysis  and  theory  -­‐  and  particulars  -­‐  the  language  of  
experience  and  practice.    Which  leads  on  to  a  debate  about  the  grounds  on  which  BSchools  dare  
claim  any  relevance  to  managerial  practice  as  they  presume  engineering  schools,  for  instance,  claim  
relevance  to  professional  engineering  practice.    In  fact  engineering  schools  have  their  own  
difficulties,  little  understood  or  discussed  in  BSchools  (Sheppard,  Macatangay,  Colby,  &  Sullivan,  
2008).    The  perennial  rigor-­‐relevance  debate  may  be  more  about  stroking  faculty  egos  and  
intellectual  biases  than  about  what  the  schools  might  do  to  meet  the  students'  or  their  employers'  
needs  better  (Contardo  &  Wensley,  2004;  Knights,  2008).      
 
If  we  look  at  what  BSchools  are  doing  but  should  not,  there  are  two  kinds  of  caveat.    First,  in  the  
heat  of  their  invective  critics  are  tempted  to  over-­‐emphasize  the  schools'  impact  on  their  students;  
but  maybe  it  does  not  matter  much  what  BSchools  do  -­‐  and  perhaps  the  faculty  and  their  research  
do  not  matter  that  much  either  (Hambrick,  1994).    There  are  few  good  measures  of  what  MBA  
programs  do  for  our  students  (Fisher  &  Kiang,  2007;  Holtom  &  Inderrieden,  2007;  Hsu,  James,  &  
Chao,  2009;  Montgomery  &  Ramus,  2011).    But  when  we  look  at  what  students  have  to  say  about  
the  MBA  experience  few  complain  it  was  like  being  sent  to  a  religious  or  military  school  and  force-­‐
fed  grossly  inappropriate  dogma  (P.  Cohen,  1974;  Kelly  &  Kelley,  1986;  McCormack,  1989).    Most  
report  it  as  a  mildly  to  greatly  improving  experience,  some  for  purely  instrumental  reasons,  it  got  
them  a  good  job,  some  for  more  personal  and  complex  reasons  (Lundstrom,  2011).    For  most  it  led  
to  personal  growth  as  well  as  expanded  opportunities  and  membership  of  a  new  community.    It  is  
not  obvious  that  BSchools  are  worse  in  their  bad  effects  on  students  than  other  schools,  whether  
the  negative  impact  arises  from  persuading  the  students'  into  unrealistic  work  expectations  or  de-­‐
socializing  them.    MBA  students  are  probably  as  able  as  any  to  handle  a  school's  or  a  faculty  
member's  bad  influences,  and  BSchools  cannot  be  blamed  for  being  on  the  institutionalized  
pathway  from  high  school  to  a  high-­‐paying  job  at  Goldman  Sachs,  Google  or  McKinsey.    A  BSchool  
background  may  also  serve  to  attract  the  attention  of  venture  capitalists  in  the  event  students  want  
to  start  up  on  their  own.    Contemporary  capitalism  and  its  institutions  have  their  idiosyncratic  
functions  and  dysfunctions  quite  independent  of  the  BSchools'.    A  more  persuasive  argument  is  that  
BSchools  are  failing  in  not  doing  something  they  should  be  doing  for  those  who  select  to  attend  
them,  given  that  most  managers  do  not.    For  instance,  many  call  for  more  attention  to  business  
ethics;  but  it  would  be  illogical  not  to  expand  that  to  non-­‐BSchool  students  as  well  (Macfarlane,  
1998).    Perhaps  the  critics  presume  managers  have  special  ethical  burdens  other  citizens  do  not  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  12  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

have  -­‐  in  which  case  these  need  to  be  spelled  out,  something  that  requires  a  workable  theory  of  
managing  as  distinct  from  simply  living  and  interacting  with  others.  
 
Most  attending  our  conference  will  have  views  about  where  the  argument  might  go  next.    Even  
though  it  is  easier  to  point  to  the  presence  of  something  unacceptable  or  objectionable  in  the  
curriculum  or  process,  in  the  end  the  critic  has  to  fasten  on  some  evident  failing  and  then  inveigh  
against  it.    Clearly  BSchools  should  not  teach  a  position  that  stands  against  the  law  on  racial  or  
gender  discrimination,  or  against  pollution,  currency  or  immigration  controls.    They  should  not  be  
blind  to  inhumane  industrial  practice  offshore  or  onshore,  but  they  are  training  private  sector  
managers,  not  public  sector  managers  or  regulators.    On  the  other  hand  businesses  often  operate  in  
a  grey  area,  not  strictly  prohibited  but  not  manifesting  our  'better  angels'  either.    There  may  be  a  
tug  of  decency  against  profit.    Eventually  those  determining  the  curriculum  arrive  at  the  distinction  
between  managing  as  a  value-­‐free  logical  or  mechanical  activity,  versus  seeing  it  as  a  value-­‐
penetrated  social  process  that  engages  real  people,  with  values  and  futures.    While  values  are  
personal,  our  teaching  demands  values  be  embedded  in  the  school's  philosophy,  ethos  and  praxis.    
An  important  lack,  therefore,  might  be  of  an  identifiable  value-­‐position  that  stands  clearly  against  
merely  mechanical  or  ‘numbers  rule’  models  of  managing.    Some  favor  free-­‐market  approaches,  
others  are  attentive  to  social  responsibilities,  but  in  every  course  students  deserve  a  value  position  
-­‐  whether  to  be  accepted  or  rejected  matters  less  than  to  be  debated.    To  propose  neutrality  is  
hiding,  an  eviscerating  attempt  to  deny  the  managerial  reality  in  which  nothing  socially  or  
personally  significant  can  also  be  value-­‐neutral.    At  the  core  of  all  education,  and  certainly  that  in  
business,  is  the  students'  need  to  debate  values  and  so  help  find  their  place  in  the  lived  world.      
 
Business  schools  are  probably  not  the  best  place  to  explore  an  anti-­‐capitalist  or  postmodernist  
political  program  -­‐  but  a  critical  approach  can  be  effective  in  illuminating  how  democratic  
capitalism  and  its  engines  actually  work,  so  we  should  not  be  too  hasty  on  this  (Alvesson  &  
Willmott,  1992;  Currie,  Knights,  &  Starkey,  2010;  French  &  Grey,  1996;  Perriton,  2007).    A  school's  
value-­‐position  is  also  articulated  in  its  educational  philosophy,  yet  schools'  mission  statements  
seldom  deal  with  this,  surely  their  most  important  aspect  (Palmer  &  Short,  2008).    These  often  
favor  generality,  universal  goods,  and  value  neutrality,  and  here  schools  can  fail  to  make  their  
students  aware  of  the  ethical  dimensions  of  life  as  well  as  of  managing  as  an  activity  involving  
directing  others.    Most  Anglo-­‐American  schools  subscribe  to  some  variant  of  the  Deweyian  
philosophy  of  education  (Kolb  &  Kolb,  2005),  favoring  a  'guide  on  the  side'  over  a  'sage  on  the  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  13  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

stage'.    Dewey's  theory  of  education  works  by  encouraging  students  to  think  for  themselves  rather  
than  slavishly  follow  the  teaching,  to  think  critically,  to  view  arguments  from  as  many  sides  as  
possible  and,  in  our  field,  to  accept  the  fundamental  heterogeneity  and  diversity  of  our  socio-­‐
economy.    Aside  from  the  complexities  and  challenges  of  teaching  this  way,  especially  if  the  student  
has  been  trained  into  different  intellectual  habits,  there  is  the  difficulty  of  maintaining  the  
necessary  openness  that  energizes  such  teaching  (Bloom,  1987).    On  the  one  hand  there  is  the  
faculty's  necessary  openness  to  and  knowledge  of  alternative  views,  on  the  other  the  difficulty  of  
helping  the  students  remain  open-­‐minded,  especially  as  they  experience  the  satisfactions  of  
grasping  some  new  viewpoint  -­‐  systems  theory,  for  instance,  when  everything  gets  called  a  system,  
a  nail  to  be  hammered  with  their  new  systems  theory  ‘hammer’.    Even  those  of  a  Deweyian  
persuasion  can  fail  to  be  open-­‐minded  in  their  teaching  practice.    Thus  there  are  clearly  two  solid  
grounds  for  criticizing  any  school  -­‐  (a)  when  it  fails  to  promote  the  discussion  of  the  values,  or  (b)  
when  it  is  closed-­‐minded  conceptually.  
 
But  these  remarks  apply  to  all  professional  schools  and  probably  all  education.    They  are  
general  and  reflect  nothing  of  what  is  peculiar  to  the  BSchool’s  defining  topics,  travails,  
methodologies  and  constituencies.    If  we  want  to  evaluate  BSchools  against  their  own  intentions  to  
serve  aspiring  or  practicing  managers  or  the  broader  socio-­‐economy  we  have  to  fasten  on  what  is  
specific  about  them;  and  if  we  do  not  accept  Khurana’s  challenging  proposition  that  they  exist  to  
inculcate  democratic  capitalism's  'higher  aims'  -­‐  even  assuming  we  could  ever  find  and  agree  on  
how  to  operationalize  these  (Ruef,  2008)  -­‐  we  have  to  find  some  other  defining  characteristic  that  
separates  business  from  the  rest  of  social  life.    The  education  of  business  managers  has  to  be  
defined  in  some  way  that  differentiates  them  from  the  general  weal.    Do  the  manager’s  values  or  
decision-­‐making  differ  from  those  of  other  forms  of  life?    Such  questions  do  not  seem  to  have  been  a  
problem  for  our  community.    One  of  the  many  curiosities  of  our  discipline  is  the  contrast  between  
(a)  the  homogeneity  of  the  BSchool  curriculum  around  the  globe  -­‐  in  spite  of  increasing  institutional  
and  national  differentiation  -­‐  and  (b)  the  lack  of  any  justification  for  or  explanation  of  why  we  teach  
what  we  teach.    In  spite  of  much  debate  at  the  margin,  whether  we  should  teach  business  ethics  or  
entrepreneurship  or  operations  management  or  not-­‐for-­‐profit  accounting,  or  whether  the  
classroom  or  the  case  method  is  more  effective,  there  is  no  clear  central  principle  or  justification  for  
the  BSchool  curriculum.    This  lack  has  been  part  of  the  US  debate  since  the  early  20th  century  as  
business  education  moved  from  the  vocational  sector,  where  there  was  no  curriculum  justification  
beyond  trial-­‐and-­‐error  identification  of  market  need,  and  into  the  university,  where  continuous  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  14  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

curriculum  debates  are  normal  and  broader  principles  pursued.    While  this  lack  of  curriculum  
justification  drew  comment  in  the  early  days  of  American  schools  (Copeland,  1958;  Donham,  1954;  
McNair  &  Hersum,  1954)  it  has  pretty  much  vanished  from  our  journals  today  (Khurana,  2007:154).    
It  seems  we  are  not  assailed  by  doubts  about  the  legitimacy  or  utility  of  the  mainstream  core  
curriculum  and  the  debate  on  curriculum  change  is  focused  on  its  fringes.  
 
The  academic  shorthand  here  is  that  we  lack  the  theory  of  the  managed  private  sector  firm  that  
could  be  the  touchstone  for  justifying  curriculum  content  -­‐  an  obviously  contested  point  I  consider  
throughout  my  essay’s  other  sections.    Though  there  is  a  widely  shared  sense  of  what  we  should  
teach  there  is  a  similarly  unarticulated  sense  of  what  we  should  not  teach  -­‐  cultural  anthropology  or  
theater  or  the  design  of  mechanical  processes  or  the  psychology  of  bipolar  disorders,  even  though  
there  might  well  be  arguments  for  including  them,  given  business  is  complex,  about  human  beings  
and  their  interaction,  and  could  be  informed  by  the  entire  corpus  of  human  knowledge.    But  there  is  
no  great  clarity  on  what  really  belongs  in  the  curriculum.    Rather,  what  we  agree  on  seems  to  have  
spread  by  imitation,  especially  of  the  curriculum  at  the  Harvard  Business  School.    Without  a  central  
pillar  of  justification  or  distinction  between  business  and  the  rest  of  life,  well-­‐meaning  faculty  are  
free  to  bring  all  manner  of  material  into  the  curriculum;  but  how  justified?    For  example,  how  do  we  
justify  integrating  psych-­‐lab  research  on  students  -­‐  non-­‐employees  -­‐  into  theories  of  managing  in  
the  curiously  a-­‐social  context  of  the  real  firm?    The  most  damaging  criticism  is  that  BSchools  have  
no  theory  of  the  firm  that  is  their  focus;  and,  by  extension,  no  robust  theory  of  what  managing  the  
firm  is  about.    The  familiar  claim  that  managing  is  'decision-­‐making'  would  be  fine  if  we  knew  what  
that  really  meant.    Rational  decision-­‐making  we  understand,  but  we  also  see  that  it  is  not  a  good  
guide  to  the  decision-­‐making  that  characterizes  managing.    It  may  well  be  useful  to  teach  students  
rational  decision-­‐making  but  it  would  certainly  be  a  mistake  to  convince  them  it  is  a  representative  
model  of  managing.    In  spite  of  Simon's  work  on  'bounded  rationality'  we  lack  a  good  sense  of  
rational  decision-­‐making's  limits  and  thus  of  the  managerial  relevance  of  the  rational  approach.      
 
The  most  profound  critique  of  BSchools  must  stand  on  this  ground  and  our  most  urgent  
academic  task  must  be  to  address  this  lack.    But  even  without  dealing  with  it,  we  seem  able  to  justify  
teaching  (a)  economics  (Jacoby,  1956),  and  (b)  quantitative  methods,  especially  if  we  treat  them  in  
the  way  statistics  used  to  be  treated  -­‐  a  universal  method  for  extracting  conclusions  from  a  mass  of  
noisy  empirical  data.    All  forms  of  managing  would  seem  to  require  dealing  with  lots  of  data,  so  
statistics  is  good.    But  if  we  also  had  a  tenable  theory  of  the  managed  firm  it  would  help  us  find  a  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  15  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

proper  balance  of  quantitative  methods  against,  say,  business  ethics  or  cross-­‐cultural  managing  or  
the  dysfunctions  of  bureaucracy,  and  much  else  besides.    Even  if  we  had  no  more  than  a  
comprehensive  set  of  managerial  heuristics  to  frame  'best  firm-­‐level  practice'  we  would  be  better  
off  than  we  are.    A  century  of  research,  US  and  elsewhere,  has  yet  to  establish  the  widely  accepted  
body  of  business  knowledge  necessary  to  justify  the  BSchool  curriculum,  let  alone  develop  a  
professional  identity  (McGuire,  1982).    In  this  state  of  lack,  every  critic  and  teacher  tends  to  start  
from  her/his  own  intuition  of  the  firm's  essential  nature;  and  the  diversity  here  makes  it  unlikely  
that  any  critic  will  be  able  to  mount  a  telling  case  against  the  momentum  of  the  institutionalized  
curriculum  content.    The  conventional  -­‐  but  unjustified  -­‐  center  will  hold,  forcing  critics  into  
division,  to  be  duly  conquered  by  the  sheer  momentum  of  the  traditional  syllabus.  
 
In  the  face  of  our  research  program's  failure  to  identify  a  theory  of  the  managed  firm,  the  work  
of  historians  like  Augier  &  March,  Daniel,  Engwall,  Khurana,  Locke,  O'Connor  and  Witzel,  shows  the  
ways  in  which  history  offers  different  insights.    It  is  a  different  methodology.    Instead  of  testing  
hypotheses,  it  offers  facts  that  might  be  summarized  as  a  testable  hypothesis.    For  instance,  if  we  
had  settled  the  debate  about  whether  small  firms  create  jobs  while  big  firms  focus  on  profit  then  we  
would  know  whether  we  are  looking  for  two  different  theories  of  the  firm,  one  small  and  job-­‐
creating,  the  other  large  and  profit-­‐oriented  (Neumark,  Wall,  &  Zhang,  2011;  Regatiero,  2010).    But  
note  the  enquiry  is  driven  by  historical  and  empirical  data,  not  by  testing  a  deductively  generated  
hypothesis.    Likewise  only  if  we  had  a  theory  of  the  firm  would  we  know  how  and  if  corporate  social  
responsibility  should  be  part  of  that  theory  or  merely  epiphenomenal  to  an  ideological  critique  of  
capitalism  (Carroll  &  Shabana,  2010;  Dahlsrud,  2008;  Heald,  1988;  Kemper  &  Martin,  2010;  
Windsor,  2006).    But  the  inclusion  of  qualitative  methods  seem  pretty  obvious  given  accounting  is  
both  essential  to  managing  and  legally  required,  so  why  not  count  everything  -­‐  the  issue  on  which  
Lord  Kelvin  and  Frank  Knight  seem  to  disagree?      
 
The  next  section's  focus  is  on  quantitative  methods  and  how  they  became  part  of  the  BSchool  
curriculum.    As  Khurana  and  others  have  shown  there  is  an  important  connection  to  the  1959  
Foundation  Reports  and  there  are  similarly  important  relations  between  post-­‐WW2  political  
developments  and  the  impact  of  institutions  such  as  RAND  and  the  Cowles  Commission  on  the  
BSchool  agenda  and  on  the  nation.    Plus  there  is  more  to  be  said,  for  treating  the  reports  as  causes  
writes  out  how  they  came  to  be  written  and  adopted  by  American  schools,  and  thus  the  wider  
political  and  technological  external  pressures  on  BSchools  to  conform  in  content  and  method.    Also  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  16  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

our  view  of  the  reports  may  be  far  from  what  their  preparers  anticipated  (Wensley,  2011).    But  the  
history  does  show  the  market  for  US  and  European  management  education  changed  greatly  in  the  
1970s  -­‐  as  it  changed  also  in  the  1920s,  1950s  and  1960s.    In  the  1970s  there  were  major  
adjustments  in  the  legal  context  of  private  sector  firms  as  deregulation  freed-­‐up  the  financial  
markets  in  particular  and  led  to  a  rapid  expansion  of  financial  services.    This  industry,  with  its  
ancillary  consulting  activities,  developed  a  huge  appetite  for  MBAs  with  quantitative  skills  because  
of  the  specific  markets  they  served.    
 
Many  argue  the  BSchools  were  ‘asleep  at  the  switch’  during  the  recent  crisis,  and  things  can  be  
made  right  by  adding  in  some  training  in  the  non-­‐quantitative  and  more  moral-­‐conscious  
disciplines  -­‐  and  this  will  prevent  another  crisis.    This  is  curious,  obviously  hubristic,  and  illogical.    
The  claim  that  BSchools  were  material  causes  of  the  financial  collapse  in  2008  is  as  absurd  as  the  
claim  teaching  economics  causes  students  to  become  greedier.    As  Fligstein  has  shown,  
summarizing  some  of  the  huge  and  still  expanding  literature  on  the  causes  of  the  collapse,  BSchools  
are  scarcely  mentioned  (Fligstein,  2010,  2011;  Munir,  2011;  Rötheli,  2010;  Zeckhauser,  2010).    
More  to  the  point,  since  BSchools  lack  a  theory  of  the  managed  firm  they  had  no  way  of  judging,  
evaluating  or  critiquing  the  morality  of  the  world  around  them  -­‐  yet  into  which  they  were  
projecting  the  students.    So  there  is  no  logical  argument  for  or  against  adding  business  ethics,  CSR,  
sustainability,  green  management,  etc.  into  the  curriculum  (Macfarlane,  1998;  Spender,  2011b).      
 
Thus  the  BSchools  failed,  and  continue  to  fail,  in  the  most  fundamental  way  that  distinguishes  
vocational  training  from  a  university's  core  activity.    No  question  democratic  capitalism  needs  well-­‐
trained  and  expert  professionals  such  as  accountants,  analysts,  statisticians,  programmers,  data  
divers  and  manipulators,  operations  researchers,  model  builders,  and  financial  engineers,  and  
universities  may  choose  to  offer  training  in  these  matters.    But  my  charge  is  that  BSchools  'lost  their  
way'  (Bennis  &  O'Toole,  2005),  or  perhaps  never  really  found  any  way  beyond  blindly  meeting  local  
business  demand,  and  were  thus  unable  to  provide  students  -­‐  as  opposed  to  vocational  trainees  -­‐  
with  the  intellectual  and  cultural  vantage-­‐point  from  which  to  critique  these  experts  and  the  worlds  
they  created.    A  historical  question  then  is  did  the  BSchools  ever  provide  such  a  critical  intellectual  
vantage  point  and,  if  they  did,  how  did  it  get  lost?    The  history  of  quantitative  methods  has  much  to  
say  on  this  matter.  
 
 

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  17  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

The  Rise  of  the  Quants  


 
The  urge  to  quantify  matters  economic  and  social  goes  back  at  least  to  Comte  and  the  birth  of  
European  positivism,  though  there  were  significant  precursors  during  the  Arab  Caliphates  (Brown,  
et  al.,  2009;  Chaudhuri,  1985;  Nasr,  2009;  Previts  &  Merino,  1998;  Saliba,  2007).    We,  and  our  
languages,  are  now  so  deeply  penetrated  by  the  idea  of  quantitative  measurement  that  we  can  
scarcely  imagine  life  without  it,  yet  its  encroachment  into  our  lives  took  many  centuries,  even  after  
Comte.    The  growth  and  social  impact  of  science  and  technology  has  much  to  do  with  this.    Likewise  
the  desire  for  control,  which  has  a  special  resonance  for  managers,  inspires  quantification  -­‐  whether  
it  is  land  surveying  for  the  tax  authorities,  ocean  navigation,  or  measuring  shipping  cargoes  and  
shoe  production.    Most  of  the  modern  measurement  and  quantification  techniques  were  developed  
in  the  late  19th  century  (T.  M.  Porter,  1986,  1995).    But  the  wider  social  urge  to  quantification  
became  especially  pronounced  with  the  rise  of  commerce  in  the  17th  and  18th  centuries  when  the  
European  agricultural  economy  flourished  as  people  moved  off  farms  where  they  grew  their  own  
produce  and  into  industrial  and  government  centers  where  they  had  to  buy  their  food  at  markets.    
Standard  metrics  for  beer,  spirits,  wheat,  yarn,  and  so  on  proliferated,  especially  in  France  after  the  
Revolution.    The  UK,  Germany  and  France  set  up  standards  institutes  and  gradually  their  chosen  yet  
different  measures  came  to  permeate  every  aspect  of  national  life;  though  their  spread  was  slower  
and  more  contested  than  we  might  think  looking  back  from  our  own  metricized  and  over-­‐surveilled  
situation.      
 
Non-­‐scientists  often  assume  science  grows  from  the  precise  measurement  of  reality  and  this  is  
not  at  all  the  case.    The  method  of  measurement  is  always  an  application  of  an  observation  theory  
together  with  some  kind  of  measuring  apparatus.    Any  part  of  this  complex  knowledge-­‐generating  
process  might  fail,  be  incorrect  or  less  than  completely  understood.    The  conclusions  to  be  drawn  
from  an  experiment  are  never,  as  Popper  is  thought  to  have  claimed,  entirely  definitive.    
Falsification  cannot  be  either  logical  or  final,  and  drawing  a  conclusion  is  invariably  an  exercise  in  
judgment  about  the  relative  weights  or  attractiveness  of  the  theory  of  observation,  the  theory  being  
tested  and  the  robustness  and  dependability  of  the  measuring  apparatus  being  used.    Every  
conclusion  is  a  synthesis  of  these  factors,  indefinite,  tentative  and  temporary,  awaiting  overthrow.    
Foucauldian  analysts  frame  the  imposition  of  standards  as  an  exercise  in  social  power  to  which  
measurement  is  a  handmaiden.    If  so,  science  is  more  problematic  since  its  power  is  typically  less  
concentrated.    Rather,  standards  and  measurement  are  part  of  the  'codification'  process  that  makes  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  18  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

it  possible  for  scientists  to  communicate  efficiently  with  each  other,  so  there  is  some  collective  
interest  in  setting  and  adopting  them.    But  ultimately  quantification  stands  on  mutual  trust,  a  
shared  process  of  legitimating  quantities  and  measures  (Gooday,  2004;  Latour  &  Woolgar,  1986).    
Researchers  cannot  repeat  every  experiment  in  order  to  test  the  validity  of  another  scientist's  
findings.    Thus  all  measures,  even  the  most  esoteric  scientific  measures,  are  deeply  social.  
 
Karl  Pearson  (1857-­‐1936)  was  a  significant  contributor  to  our  current  attitudes  to  measures  
and  quantification.    He  is  credited  with  founding  mathematical  statistics,  of  course;  but  the  concepts  
were  framed  by  his  thinking  about  experimental  evidence.    He  argued  our  impressions  are  not  
directly  determined  by  reality,  they  are  simply  our  impressions.    But  neither  are  they  arbitrary  or  
crudely  subjective.    Science  was  the  social  activity  of  applying  a  method  that  would  order  our  
impressions  and  align  them  with  those  of  other  scientists.    Becoming  a  scientist  involved  being  
trained  into  a  community  that  developed  and  adopted  a  method  of  arranging  impressions  in  a  
collectively  accepted  and  legitimated  way.    Science  is  simply  method  and  process,  not  findings.    
Science  cannot  give  us  insight  into  reality  for  we  can  only  ever  see  or  measure  what  we  have  
previously  imagined.    At  best  the  scientific  method  helps  us  accumulate  trustworthy  facts  or  
evidence  and  then,  in  an  act  of  imagination,  we  summarize  these  as  a  law.    But,  equally,  we  can  
never  find  'perfect  law-­‐like-­‐ness'  or  'causality'.    Instead  we  find  association  and  correlation  
attended  by  variation,  for  nothing  about  reality  is  perfect,  there  is  always  noise.      
 
In  Pearson's  view  statistics  was  a  universal  method  for  teasing  significant  correlations  out  of  
empirical  data.    Quantification  thereby  separated  thinking  (theorizing)  from  experiencing,  
separated  the  universe  of  law-­‐making  from  the  lived  universe  of  experience  and  evidence;  the  
general  separated  from  the  particular.    We  live  one  instant  or  experience  at  a  time.    Quantification  
creates  an  artificial  reality  in  which  those  trained  can  share,  which  is  therefore  essentially  social  in  
nature.    Time  is  an  oft-­‐cited  example,  evident  as,  perhaps,  the  Church's  need  to  establish  a  
predictable  calendar  of  events  from  weekly  services  to  annual  gatherings,  or  the  nation's  need  to  
have  taxes  due  or  magistrate’s  hearing  dates.    Many  historians  have  explored  the  establishment  or  
imposition  of  modern  time,  often  illustrated  as  the  need  to  coordinate  railway  movements,  but  
more  generally  to  run  an  industrial  society  in  which  production  lines  could  only  run  when  every  
station  was  manned  or  military  operations  likewise  conducted  (Landes,  1983).    The  result  is  
tension  between  conventionalist  agreements  about  how  to  manage  time,  daylight  savings  for  
instance,  versus  trust  in  some  'objective'  non-­‐social  time  set  by  NIST’s  cesium  clock  that  hides  the  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  19  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

social  nature  of  our  agreement  about  how  many  ticks  or  vibrations  make  for  a  year.    We  begin  to  
see  how  time  is  problematized  and  contextualized,  varying  according  to  the  analyst’s  point  of  view.  
 
The  pursuit  of  social  control  through  quantification  collided  with  existing  class  arrangements.    
The  elite  asserted  they  knew  the  facts  'immediately'  through  their  superior  mental  powers  and  
sensory  acuity.    Boosters  of  quantification  ran  up  against  elitism  and  their  influence  spread  only  as  
the  elites’  social  and  political  powers  declined  in  the  18th  and  19th  centuries,  in  part  through  the  rise  
in  commerce  and  management.    Management,  in  turn,  envisioned  new  forms  of  measurement  to  
buttress  their  new  powers.    Note  the  term  ‘statistics’  (state-­‐istics)  derives  from  computation  in  the  
service  of  the  state,  whence  also  the  term  'population'.    Porter's  histories  of  quantification  pointed  
out  that  it  made  possible  socially  significant  entities  that  did  not  previously  exist.    Mortality  rates  -­‐  
in  a  plague,  say  -­‐  meant  nothing  before  data  collection  and  statistical  analysis,  so  the  authorities  had  
no  sure  way  of  gauging  the  seriousness  of  news.    To  illustrate  just  two  ways  in  which  quantification  
created  new  worlds,  statistics  (a)  made  an  insurance  industry  possible,  a  matter  of  interest  to  the  
state,  employers  and  employees,  and  (b)  provided  politicians  and  administrators  with  a  new  field  of  
policy-­‐making  by  distinguishing  collective  and  individual  activities.    If  the  child  mortality  rate  in  
one  part  of  the  city  differed  from  that  in  another  part,  this  might  indicate  the  need  for  sewers,  
better  water  supply,  and  so  on;  or  for  better  parenting.    Statistics  would  supply  much  of  the  
debate’s  rhetoric.    To  be  managed  the  state  had  to  exist  as  something  more  tangible  than  a  name,  so  
presenting  the  state  as  a  set  of  statistics  created  the  state  as  a  manageable  modern  entity.      
 
Likewise  the  debate  about  state-­‐supported  education  depended  on  statistics  about  its  cost  and  
impact.    War  making,  always  a  key  driver,  required  the  state  to  gather  huge  amounts  of  data  about  
its  citizens,  their  health  and  education  as  well  as  data  about  the  economy,  and  so  on.    Statistics  
made  it  possible  to  form  testable  hypotheses  to  guide  statewide  social  action  in  a  'objective'  non-­‐
political  way.    They  made  bureaucratic  administration  possible.    The  possibility  of  managing  the  
economy  depended  on  gathering  economic  statistics.    The  same  was  true  of  managing  individual  
firms,  especially  as  they  were  moving  to  the  production  of  large  quantities  of  many  different  
articles.    For  example,  in  the  1870s  the  Ames  Shovel  Works  in  North  Easton  MA,  the  world's  
dominant  supplier  at  the  time,  produced  several  hundred  different  types  of  shovel  and  spade,  a  
situation  that  demanded  dealing  with  huge  quantities  of  data.    Likewise  Frederick  Taylor's  
Scientific  Management  movement  was  a  hugely  influential  data-­‐driven  business  development  at  the  
end  of  the  19th  century  (Spender  &  Kijne,  1996).    Taylor  identified  two  new  kinds  of  production  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  20  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

statistician  as  essential  to  his  new  ways  of  organizing  production:  time  clerk  and  routing  clerk,  as  
well  as  measurers  of  production  rates,  product  tolerances,  scrap,  work-­‐in-­‐progress,  and  inventory.    
Naturally,  such  production  oriented  quantitative  experts  were  progressively  more  important  as  the  
economy  expanded  and  operations  became  more  complex.    At  the  same  time  firms  were  growing  
larger,  to  the  point  where  they  could  only  be  managed  with  the  support  of  many  different  types  of  
statistician  -­‐  accountants,  record  keepers,  clerks,  estimators,  financial  analysts,  market  analysts,  
and  so  on.    Private  sector  managers  and  owners  discovered  the  limits  of  firm  manageability,  and  
this  spurred  academic  economists  to  search  for  theoretical  limits  to  the  firm’s  size  and  growth,  and  
thus  to  search  for  metrics  with  which  the  firm  might  be  characterized  -­‐  assets,  employment,  sales,  
market  penetration,  and  so  on  -­‐  a  search  that  continues  today  with  the  attempt  to  measure  the  
firm’s  ‘intangibles’.  
 
While  the  impacts  of  Scientific  Management  were  economy-­‐wide,  the  place  of  quantitative  
studies  in  the  business  curriculum  was  not  immediately  clear.    Taylor  famously  argued  business  
schools  were  a  waste  of  the  students'  time  (Kanigel,  1997).    Khurana's  second  phase  of  managerial  
capitalism  put  the  emphasis  on  organizational  efficiency  in  the  Taylorist  tradition.    The  aesthetic  
was  the  engineers'  and  quantitative  methods  inevitably  played  an  increasingly  important  role  in  the  
education  of  managers  being  trained  to  view  the  firm  as  an  efficiency-­‐seeking  bureaucratic  or  
mechanical  system.    Scrap  rates,  time  to  complete  product  development,  production  downtime,  and  
so  on  became  the  new  quantitative  language  of  management.    The  firm’s  language  was  
comprehensible  only  within  the  context  of  the  firm  as  a  social  milieu,  and  perhaps  within  its  
industry,  but  seldom  across  industries.    By  1930  the  BSchool  statistics  faculty  had  established  a  
separate  disciplinary  identity,  especially  in  the  AACSB  schools,  and  along  with  economics,  business  
finance,  and  public  finance,  made  up  the  quantitative  group  that  balanced  the  industry  and  
organizational  content  specialists  such  as  insurance,  real  estate  and  transportation  (Khurana,  
2007:167).    But  this  does  not  tell  us  much  about  how  quantitative  skills  were  applied  and  how  they  
related  to  the  firms'  activities.    The  state  use  of  statistics  was  obviously  in  the  service  of  political  
discussions  about  state  action,  and  numbers  became  the  key  modernist  rhetorical  device  for  
persuading  a  more  educated  and  numerate  populace.    They  suggested  objectivity  and  hid  the  social  
foundations  on  which  all  measurement  stood  in  both  the  physical  and  the  social  sciences.      
 
Numbers  were  clearly  useful  in  the  firm's  discussions  of  strategic  direction,  but  increasingly  
complex  firms  used  numbers  in  other  ways  as  well.    Managerial  accountants  needed  the  costs  and  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  21  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

values  of  the  intermediary  stages  of  production  and  sales,  creating  ‘internal’  numbers  that  could  not  
be  verified  against  external  referents  such  as  market  price.    These  made  it  possible  to  imagine  
internal  markets  into  existence  and  debate  the  allocation  of  resources  between  divisions  and  
projects  using,  for  instance,  internal  rates  of  return  (IRR)  or  anticipated  growth  rate.    In  the  
Taylorist  Scientific  Management  tradition  numbers  were  in  the  service  of  production  control  and  
resource  allocation  decisions.    But  firms  also  began  to  use  numbers  to  'model'  their  processes  in  the  
manner  used  by  engineers,  creating  artificial  entities  that  allowed  managers  to  evaluate  making  
changes  (Johnson  &  Kaplan,  1987;  Kay,  1991).    These  methods  also  permeated  the  social  sciences  
where  notions  of  'theory'  and  'model'  converged  (Ando,  Fisher,  &  Simon,  1963).    This  alternative  
way  of  using  quantities  had  earlier  precipitated  the  Methodenstreit  between  the  historicist  
Schmoller  and  his  followers  and  the  deductivist  Austrian  School  of  Menger  (Mäki,  1997;  Senn,  2005;  
Vaughn,  1994).    The  historicists  collected  empirical  data  in  support  of  administrative  and  political  
decisions  that  were  ultimately  matters  of  social  and  personal  judgment,  while  the  deductivists  
pursued  theories  expressed  in  the  quantitative  terms  that  would  allow  them  to  be  tested  
'objectively',  as  if  the  numbers  were  objective  rather  than  social  in  essence.    In  this  way  those  
skilled  in  quantification  battled  rhetorically  to  establish  a  higher  ground  seemingly  safe  from  
subjectivism  and  mere  opinion.    This  also  meant  suppressing  the  moral  and  ethical  issues  of  social  
action  beneath  the  screen  of  'scientific  objectivity'.    The  main  point  being  that  quantification  can  
always  be  applied  in  two  very  different  ways,  one  to  better  inform  a  value-­‐penetrated  debate  
between  people  choosing  in  their  lived  and  morally  burdened  world,  the  other  to  create  a  model,  an  
artificial  and  rigorous  a-­‐moral  world  that  people  might  then  try  to  inhabit.  
 
The  1959  Foundation  Reports  had  a  huge  impact  on  American  BSchools  at  the  same  time  as  
they  were  expanding  rapidly  in  number,  size  and  influence.    But  the  reports  themselves  were  only  
BSchool-­‐focused  manifestations  of  the  general  post-­‐WW2  trend  towards  science  and  rigor  as  social  
and  political  metaphors  for  rationalist  politics  in  the  emerging  new  world.    BSchools  had  long  
taught  economics,  perhaps  on  the  grounds  that  business  is  about  making  money  and  economists  
talk  about  money  (Jacoby,  1956).    Progressively  more  attention  was  paid  to  why  economics  should  
be  taught,  Harris  summarizing  eight  reasons,  including  the  benefits  of  quantification  and  
intellectual  rigor  and  the  ideology  of  monetary  incentives  (Harris,  1984).    The  work  of  a  handful  of  
the  world's  top  economists,  political  scientists,  mathematicians,  operations  researchers  and  
computer  scientists  brought  together  at  RAND  in  Santa  Monica  CA  or  the  Cowles  Commission  in  
Chicago  IL  did  a  great  deal  to  draw  economic  principles  and  quantitative  styles  of  thought  together  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  22  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

to  help  fashion  a  new  neoliberal  politics  that  had  a  major  impact  on  the  thinking  articulated  into  the  
Foundation  (Amadae,  2003;  Amadae  &  de  Mesquita,  1999;  Peck,  2010).    Crucial  was  Arrow's  
'impossibility  theorem'  which  helped  'prove'  neither  a  voting  system  nor  central  planning  could  
work  fairly  and  efficient  markets  were  the  core  of  democracy  (Bouleau,  2011;  Feldman  &  Serrano,  
2008;  Geanakoplos,  2005;  Sen,  1979).      
 
The  concept  of  management  was  gradually  transformed  from  Taylorist  efficiency  engineering  
into  rationalism  pure  and  simple,  a  managerial  doctrine.    Modeling  expanded  alongside  business  
fact  gathering  and  statistical  analysis.    This  opened  the  BSchools  to  a  new  generation  of  faculty  
without  business  or  management  experience,  so  long  as  they  had  quantitative  modeling  skills.    
Additionally,  Khurana  argued  the  pre-­‐WW2  aspects  of  the  'human  relations'  discourse  that  
balanced  the  Taylorist  efficiency  seeking  began  to  be  pushed  aside  by  the  emerging  managerial  
rationalism  (Khurana,  2007:203).    The  rhetoric  of  the  rational  profit-­‐seeking  firm,  modeled  by  
objective  numbers,  began  to  overwhelm  any  notions  of  social  duty,  competitive  positioning,  
customer  service,  and  so  on.    Managers  became  'organization  men'  measured  in  terms  of  their  
service  to  the  firm's  quantifiable  goals,  less  and  less  concerned  with  or  able  to  deal  with  the  non-­‐
quantifiable  aspects  of  operating  in  a  democratic  capitalist  system  with  its  many  complex  tensions;  
less  and  less  the  firm's  entrepreneurial  agents  and  more  and  more  mere  passive  cogs  in  a  rational  
machine.    Today’s  lawyers  are  measured  in  terms  of  their  fee  income,  engineering  professors  in  
terms  of  their  research  grant  income.    The  quants  began  to  rise  to  dominance  through  their  facility  
with  this  new  rhetoric,  pointing  to  the  irresistible  logic  of  the  conclusions  their  numbers  generated.    
 
Against  this  we  can  note  the  historian’s  device  of  asserting  phases  of  management  or  
organization,  such  as  Khurana’s  three  phases,  was  previously  used  by  Preston  and  Post  who  argued  
for  a  somewhat  similar  three  phase  analysis,  but  with  the  most  recent  a  turn  from  ‘mechanical’  
management  to  ‘participative’  management  (Preston  &  Post,  1974,  1975).    Historians  can  deploy  a  
different  narrative  line  to  tell  a  different  story  and  move  towards  very  different  hypotheses  and  
theories.    The  combination  shows  the  literatures  of  rational  managing  and  human  relations  drifted  
apart,  becoming  more  specialized  as  communicating  between  the  HR  and  rationalist  disciplinary  
silos  became  more  difficult.    Today’s  management  researchers’  interest  in  ‘trust’,  ‘stakeholder  
theory’  (Freeman,  Harrison,  Wicks,  Parmar,  &  de  Colle,  2010),  workplace  democracy,  ‘servant  
leadership’,  and  variants  of  the  Scanlon  Plan  and  other  forms  of  ‘worker  participation’,  show  our  
continued  interest  in  the  non-­‐quantitative  discussion.    That  my  five  phases  co-­‐exist,  the  last  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  23  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

beginning  after  the  time  of  Preston  &  Post’s  writings,  allows  the  earlier  social  duty,  efficiency-­‐
oriented,  conglomerate,  and  shareholder  capitalist  phases  to  continue  to  evolve  even  as  the  later  
phases  come  into  place.    While  there  is  significant  continuing  interest  in  modernizing  management  
practices  and  paying  greater  attention  to  HRM,  but  it  is  focused  on  those  managers  who  intend  to  
keep  their  firms  alive  and  operating.    It  is  of  less  interest  to  those  ‘managers’  who  intend  to  put  
their  firms  ‘in  play’,  stripping  their  under-­‐used  assets  and  trading  them.    Thus  against  the  theory  of  
the  firm  implicit  in  Preston  &  Post’s  work,  modeled  as  human  relationships,  is  the  theory  of  the  firm  
implicit  in  shareholder  capitalism,  modeled  in  financial  language  alone.    The  contrast  creates  
problems  for  Deans  because  of  the  considerable  tension  between  the  faculty  involved  and  in  the  
BSchool’s  curriculum,  unresolved  in  the  absence  of  finding  or  choosing  the  theory  of  the  firm  on  
which  the  school  can  be  based.  
 
 
From  Conglomerates  to  Casino  Capitalism  
 
The  quantitative  experts'  ability  to  model  as  well  as  measure  and  analyze  had  major  
implications  for  managing  the  increasingly  complex  and  diversified  corporations  of  the  post-­‐WW2  
era.    The  diverse  artificial  entities  imagined  into  existence  could  nonetheless  be  modeled,  managed  
and  evaluated  using  uniform  criteria,  such  as  ROI,  market  share  or  cash  flow.    Rapidly  growing  
conglomerate  firms  like  ITT,  created  through  Harold  Geneen's  success  in  purchasing  over  350  
different  companies  in  80  countries,  were  managed  through  a  coherent  system  of  uniformly  
structured  reports  based  on  corporation-­‐approved  metrics  (N.  Berg,  1965;  Klein,  2001).    Managers  
read  these  reports  and  took  decisions  on  the  basis  of  the  figures  shown,  scarcely  bothering  about  
what  the  numbers  represented  or  the  particular  products,  people  and  communities  affected.    
Everything  was  reduced  to  its  expression  in  the  firm's  uniform  financial  language.    The  managers'  
role  was  to  use  the  standardized  data  to  transform  investment  into  revenue.    No  other  non-­‐
measurable  attributes  mattered.    Thus  'rational  management'  shifted  the  focus  away  from  firms  
that  saw  themselves  as  providing  unique  products  and  services  for  different  employees  and  
consumers,  perhaps  loyal  perhaps  local,  and  onto  the  operating  units  of  a  'legal  fiction',  an  
investment  vehicle  primarily  engaged  in  making  profits  through  buying  and  selling  the  operating  
units  themselves,  using  earnings-­‐per-­‐share  (EPS)  and  the  finance  market's  opinions  and  
expectations  as  their  decision  criteria.    The  shift  was  from  managing  operations  to  ‘deal  making’.      
 

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  24  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

As  business  historians  have  shown,  this  kind  of  shareholder  or  investor  capitalism  seemed  to  
overtake  the  'managerial  capitalism'  of  the  earlier  Taylorist  era  that  focused  on  production  and  
distribution  efficiency.    It  is  not  generally  appreciated  that  Taylor's  successful  consulting  practice  
was  not  based,  as  many  assume,  on  engineering  or  work  measurement  or  even  replicating  the  
administrative  methods  he  introduced  at  Bethlehem  Steel,  but  rather  on  the  introduction  of  
systematic  cost  and  production  accounting  in  all  manner  of  operations,  including  dental  offices.    As  
corporate  accounting  no  longer  merely  supported  production  but  was  refashioned  into  
conglomerate  controls,  short-­‐termism,  especially  as  behavior  ruled  by  the  market's  shifting  
opinions,  displaced  the  'patient'  capitalism  that  set  management's  eye  on  long-­‐term  goals  and  more  
challenging  developments,  especially  globalization  and  new  technology.    Vigorous  debate  over  the  
socially  and  economically  damaging  consequences  or  benefits  of  strategic  short-­‐termism  continues  
(Hayes  &  Abernathy,  1980;  Laverty,  1996;  Marginson  &  McAulay,  2008;  Marston  &  Craven,  1998;  M.  
E.  Porter,  1992)  but  whichever  way  the  debate  tilts,  the  BSchools'  role  remains  quite  clear.    They  
did  not  cause  the  shift  from  managerial  capitalism  to  deal  making  and  short-­‐termism.    Geneen  was  
not  a  BSchool  graduate,  nor  were  many  of  his  fellow  conglomerate-­‐builders  or  asset  -­‐strippers.    
Rather  they  were  enterprising  individuals  who  understood  how  to  create  artificial  financial  or  
'special  purpose'  vehicles  that  would  attract  the  attention  of  potential  investors  and  the  stock  
market.    The  typical  vehicle  would  not  be  a  holding  company  owning  a  number  of  efficiency-­‐seeking  
or  rent-­‐seeking  units,  as  Carnegie,  Ford  or  Wharton  owned  many  different  enterprises,  but  a  
money-­‐making  machine  in  its  own  right  that  traded  its  inventory  of  firms  and  operations,  rather  
than  the  products  and  services  they  provided.    Its  managers  could  play  high-­‐margin  games  with  
other  peoples'  low-­‐margin  money,  very  different  from  the  rent-­‐seeking  firms  that  dominated  the  
pre-­‐WW2  economy  that  grew  by  acquiring  monopolies  and  accumulating  retained  earnings  into  
capital.    The  new  post-­‐WW2  firms  borrowed  hugely  and  explored  how  to  transform  managing  debt  
into  revenue.      
 
The  asset-­‐strippers  and  conglomerate-­‐builders  generated  an  explosion  of  opportunities  for  
docile  young  'organization  men'  (generally  men  though  after  the  1980s  BSchools  attracted  an  
increasing  percentage  of  women).    Though  MBA  applicants  were  expected  to  have  2  or  so  years  
'work  experience'  they  generally  lacked  management  experience,  and  thus  experience  of  dealing  
with  the  non-­‐quantifiable  aspects  of  the  real  world,  but  they  were  valuable  nonetheless  for  the  
essential  quantitative  skills  necessary  to  prepare  and  interpret  the  reports  that  gave  the  imaginary  
financial  entity  its  uncomplicated  substance.    The  BSchools  responded,  following  this  new  market,  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  25  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

and  helped  meet  the  demand  that  also  attracted  the  other  talents  needed  for  high-­‐velocity  deal-­‐
making  -­‐  young  16-­‐hour-­‐a-­‐day  pizza-­‐  and  Coke-­‐fueled  accountants  and  lawyers.    Law  schools  
likewise  developed  two  kinds  of  student,  those  headed  towards  the  judiciary  or  the  public  sector,  
and  the  increasing  numbers  headed  towards  the  expanding  private  sector  as  corporate  and  tax  
lawyers.    There  are  sharp  differences  between  managing  to  increase  efficiency,  to  adapting  firms  to  
changes  in  their  markets  and  technologies,  to  compete  with  new  suppliers,  all  with  a  general  focus  
on  survival  and  growth,  and  the  new  kind  of  managing  the  conglomerate  exemplified.    The  new  
business  context  made  it  acceptable,  reasonable,  and  often  highly  profitable  for  managers  to  'exit'  
the  firm  by  selling  it  as  a  going  concern,  'strip'  its  assets  by  breaking  it  up  into  parts  to  be  sold  or  
spun  out,  or  liquidating  its  operations  entirely  whenever  the  deal  'made  sense'  financially  
(Hirschman,  1970).    Survival  was  no  longer  the  firm's  taken-­‐for-­‐granted  bottom-­‐line.    The  senior  
managers  doing  these  deals  typically  survived,  of  course,  even  when  the  abandoned  employees,  
facilities  and  communities  did  not,  by  arranging  personal  deals  like  golden  parachutes  and  moving  
from  one  opportunity  to  another,  an  evanescent  layer  of  self-­‐protecting  fixer-­‐agents  like  'Chainsaw  
Dunlap'.    To  macroeconomists  this  was  'industrial  restructuring',  putting  resources  of  every  type  to  
higher  and  better  use.    To  a  mutually-­‐regarding  group  of  super-­‐managers  who  learned  this  new  
game  and  were  able  to  reconstruct  it  so  that  it  might  be  played  better  and  more  profitably,  it  was  a  
new  world,  increasingly  insulted  from  shareholders  whether  activist  or  institutional.  
 
While  deal  making  was  always  around  it  was  now  transformed  into  a  new  managerial  ethos,  
especially  manifest  in  the  US  merger  and  acquisition  (M&A)  'waves'.      Economic  historians  have  
identified  several  M&A  waves,  one  dating  around  1897  following  that  year's  financial  panic,  that  
had  the  effect  of  consolidating  industrial  supply  and  demand  into  the  monopoly-­‐seeking  trusts  
against  which  the  Anti-­‐Trust  legislation  was  eventually  launched  (Neale,  1970).    Another  between  
1916  and  1929  emphasized  both  the  rent-­‐seeking  and  the  efficiencies  gained  by  the  vertical  
alignments  examined  in  Chandler's  business  histories,  such  as  Ford's  full  integration  from  iron  and  
coal  mines  and  rubber  plantations  through  manufacture,  assembly  and  then  to  dealerships,  or  the  
geographical  integration  as  large  firms  developed  national  and  international  brands  and  
distribution,  such  as  DuPont,  Quaker  Oats  or  Sears  Roebuck.    While  any  type  of  corporate  
restructuring  calls  for  quantification,  the  M&A  wave  of  1965-­‐1969  was  enabled  by  a  special  kind  of  
analysis  -­‐  corporate  or  operations  valuation  or,  rather,  the  special  skills  and  techniques  needed  to  
shape  a  market  price  for  a  deal  that  was  a  one-­‐of-­‐a-­‐kind  event  where  no  real  facts  or  market  
existed.    It  meant  putting  a  value  on  an  imaginary  entity,  and  financial  modeling  skills  were  crucial  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  26  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

to  the  rhetoric  justifying  the  price  arrived  at  and  hotly  debated  between  the  investment  bankers  
structuring  the  deal.    'Industrial  logic'  became  the  term  of  art  for  rounding  out  the  valuation,  akin  to  
'goodwill'  as  a  balancing  term,  but  lacking  the  track  record  that  implied.    Industrial  logic  was  
forward  looking,  typically  at  the  non-­‐rigorously-­‐justified  and  non-­‐quantified  expectation  that  
restructuring  and  rearrangement  would  lead  to  'synergy'  and  greater  profitability  from  one  source  
or  another,  even  though  mergers  seldom  delivered  on  that  promise  (Kitching,  1967).    For  a  new  
generation  of  BSchool  students  it  was  more  pertinent  that  M&A  activity  paid  well,  often  very  well,  
as  did  the  expanding  consulting  activity  in  restructuring  companies  sometimes  for  salvage,  
sometimes  for  sale,  sometimes  as  alliances,  partnerships,  or  full  mergers  -­‐  all  paying  much  better  
than  the  older  style  quantitative  work  of  managerial  capitalism.      
 
With  these  developments  and  the  improving  market  for  MBA  graduates  whose  aspirations  
correspondingly  rose  ever  higher,  the  BSchools  continued  to  expand.    An  increasing  portion  of  the  
student  body  chose  to  work  in  the  highly  paid  consulting  and  financial  services.    At  the  same  time  
the  financial  services'  share  of  GDP  climbed  steadily  from  around  8%  in  the  1960  to  around  18%  in  
2000,  attracting  BSchool  graduates  into  an  industry  their  parents  would  never  have  considered  as  
they  encouraged  their  children  into  'the  professions'  -­‐  law,  engineering,  medicine,  dentistry,  
architecture,  etc.    It  would  be  difficult  to  persuade  anyone  that  being  a  financial  analyst  was  to  be  a  
member  of  a  profession,  for  their  work  lacked  even  the  legal  obligations  to  which  accountants  
hewed.    But  the  BSchools'  economics,  accounting  and  quantitative  faculty  departments  continued  to  
expand,  absorbing  the  lion's  share  of  hiring  slots  and  seizing  more  space  in  the  curriculum.    The  
balance  of  faculty  power,  and  the  balance  of  the  curriculum,  shifted  towards  quantitative  
dominance,  a  clear  response  to  the  changes  resulting  from  following  a  market  that  increasingly  
neglected  manufacturing  and  other  old-­‐style  managerial  capitalism.    The  shift  was  also  
turbocharged  by  the  rising  politics  of  rationality  and  neoliberalism  as  Deans  and  faculty  saw  that  
adopting  a  quantitative  orientation  put  them  on  the  ‘right  side  of  history'.      
 
As  we  all  know,  the  entire  BSchool  apparatus  was  shaken  to  its  core  by  the  appearance  of  the  
rankings,  first  in  1974  in  the  magazine  MBA,  and  then  in  1988  in  BusinessWeek.    The  rankings  struck  
many  as  grossly  off  the  mark  and  arbitrary,  paying  more  attention  to  student  views  and  salaries  
than  to  the  criteria  by  which  the  faculty  judged  themselves  and  others  (Cornelissen  &  Thorpe,  2002;  
Dichev,  1999).    More  importantly,  the  rankings  were  not  under  the  schools'  control,  for  the  
numbers  on  which  the  rankings  were  based  were  collected  by  outsiders  and  published  without  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  27  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

peer  review.    In  principle  the  BSchools  could  re-­‐shape  their  ranking  by  attracting  'star'  academics  
with  considerable  'public  intellectual'  presence,  whose  names  would  be  known  to  prospective  
students  through  the  press  and  TV,  or  by  building  splendid  new  facilities  or  providing  more  
comfortable  dormitories  or  sports  facilities  or  having  a  simulated  trading  room  on  site.    But  the  
rankings  remained  remarkably  stable  even  as  the  criteria  for  hiring  Deans  began  to  be  whether  
they  could  raise  the  funds  necessary  to  shift  the  school's  ranking  (Policano,  2001,  2005).    The  
rankings  reminded  Deans  daily  that  they  had  more  or  less  lost  their  control  of  their  reputations  -­‐  
the  root  of  which  condition,  of  course,  lay  in  their  lack  of  the  grounding  theory  of  the  firm  that  
would  provide  a  rational  workable  basis  for  judging  their  curriculum,  faculty,  teaching,  and  
research  choices  and  setting  up  the  school's  recruitment,  hiring  and  placement  activities.    In  the  
absence  of  this  touchstone  BSchools  accepted  being  driven  by  the  market  forces  they  inherited,  the  
pressure  of  the  rankings  exacerbating  their  market  orientation.    Even  as  the  universities  themselves  
were  grappling  with  the  consequences  of  commercialization  and  adopting  a  market  orientation  
(Bok,  2003;  Hersh  &  Merrow,  2005;  Washburn,  2005;  Wilshire,  1990),  whatever  intellectual  
aspirations  BSchools  had,  as  would  normally  be  expected  of  a  university  department,  were  
sidelined.    The  research  that  loomed  large  in  most  schools'  rhetoric  was  almost  completely  
disregarded  in  rankings  that  focused  on  student  deliverables  like  salary  on  graduation  at  the  
expense  of  faculty  chosen  or  measured  deliverables.      
 
Beginning  with  the  pre-­‐WW1  idea  the  HBS  brought  into  the  BSchool  business,  that  'research'  
meant  the  production  of  'cases'  for  the  school's  case  teaching,  the  BSchool  notion  of  research  went  
through  a  curious  transformation.    Research  findings  in  the  social  sciences  are  tricky  to  value,  but  
exemplary  research  such  as  Durkheim's  analysis  of  suicide  or  W.  H.  Whyte's  'Organization  Man'  or  
Braverman's  'Labor  and  Monopoly  Capital'  or  March  &  Simon's  'Organization'  not  only  changed  the  
related  academic  discourse,  making  a  significant  contribution  to  the  discipline  but  also,  and  more  
importantly,  changed  everyday  perceptions  of  the  phenomena  they  examined,  and  in  doing  so  did  
much  to  change  public  policy.    The  declared  purpose  of  most  social  science  research  from  Comte  
through  Durkheim  to  James  Coleman  and  Robert  Putnam  (Bowling  Alone,  2000)  was  exactly  similar  
to  Pearson's  intent  to  gather  data  and  use  statistics  to  inform  better  public  policy.    Little  of  the  
research  done  in  BSchools  since  the  pre-­‐WW2  Hawthorne  studies  seemed  to  meet  these  criteria.    
Perhaps  the  private-­‐sector  firm  was  the  new  intended  beneficiary,  rather  than  the  public  discourse?    
But  as  the  early  HBS  notion  of  casework  research  was  gradually  eroded  by  time  and  the  
methodological  debate  in  the  social  sciences,  especially  after  the  Foundation  Reports,  'doing  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  28  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

research'  gradually  came  to  mean  'getting  something  published'  (Certo,  Sirmon,  &  Brymer,  2010;  
Cooper,  2011).    The  weight  of  the  claim,  the  new  quality  metric,  being  the  journal's  ranking  rather  
than  the  work's  substantive  findings,  again  revealing  another  inevitable  consequence  of  having  no  
foundational  theory  of  the  private-­‐sector  firm  (Geary,  Marriott,  &  Rowlinson,  2004).      
 
Naturally  there  was  an  explosion  in  the  number  and  variety  of  business  school  journals  that  
continues  today  (Khurana,  2007:306),  creating  a  closed  loop  between  publication  and  research  
achievement  that,  in  the  post-­‐Foundation  Report  environment,  was  rapidly  institutionalized  into  
the  BSchools'  hiring,  promotion  and  tenure  practices.    The  loop  remains  more  or  less  insulated  from  
public  policy  practice,  especially  in  the  US  where  public  policy  schools  are  physically  and  
institutionally  separated  from  and  have  little  interaction  with  the  private  sector  oriented  BSchools.    
It  also  remains  insulated  from  private-­‐sector  management  practice.    Most  of  the  post-­‐WW2  
developments  in  management  practice  have  come  from  non-­‐BSchool  sources,  imaginative  
managers  and  consultants  being  major  contributors  along  with  rafts  of  quantitatively  trained  
operations  researchers,  accountants,  and  IT  systems  engineers.    The  result  is  the  familiar  rigor-­‐
relevance  debate  (Fincham  &  Clark,  2009;  Knights,  2008)  and,  as  indicated  earlier,  the  idea  that  it  
can  be  eliminated  by  doing  regular  BSchool-­‐style  research  on  matters  of  greater  concern  to  
managers  rather  than  letting  it  be  driven  by  the  academic  journals'  current  debates  and  fashions  
ignores  the  tension  between  theory  and  practice  that  is  fundamental  to  every  professional  school,  
defined  as  those  educating  students  to  make  a  difference  in  the  lived  world,  in  contrast  to  the  
academic  schools  whose  principal  objective  is  to  make  a  difference  in  the  discipline.    No  question  
quantitative  methods  had  a  huge  impact  on  BSchool  research,  just  as  the  Foundation  Reports’  
authors  intended.    While  casework  survives  as  a  legitimate  but  déclassé  'research  activity',  
publication  is  now  as  much  about  the  author's  public  demonstration  of  competence  with  the  
current  approved  quantitative  research  methods  as  it  is  about  the  researcher's  substantive  findings,  
probably  more  so.    Research  methods  competence  leads  to  being  hired  to  teach  other  BSchool  
students  the  same  methods,  and  so  on.    At  the  same  time  it  is  not  clear  that  any  of  these  methods  
are  useful  to  practitioners  in  the  current  business  environment,  even  in  its  more  science  and  
technology-­‐driven,  global  supply-­‐chain,  or  data-­‐intensive  parts.    At  most,  today's  top  managers  hire  
methods-­‐educated  analysts  to  support  their  decision-­‐making  in  much  the  same  way  Fayol  did  in  the  
1890s  when  he  managed  one  of  the  largest  iron  and  steel  companies  in  France.  
 

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  29  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

The  tensions  between  quantitative  methods,  including  economic  analysis,  financial  analysis,  and  
accounting,  and  the  methods  used  to  address  the  more  complex  questions  of  managing  people  of  
bounded  rationality  with  social  connections,  emotions,  heterogeneous  skills,  and  attitude,  or  
managing  the  subtleties  of  strategic  choice  and  competitive  positioning,  were  always  an  on-­‐going  
challenge  for  BSchool  administrators,  highlighted  by  struggles  over  curriculum  ‘real  estate’,  
especially  in  its  ever-­‐expanding  core,  producing  more  convergence  and  less  freedom  in  the  
students'  and  faculty's  choices.    Khurana  reported  some  of  the  many  inconclusive  discussions  
around  curriculum  balance  before  WW2  (Khurana,  2007:154).    These  challenges  were  increased  as  
the  Foundation  Reports  and  their  associated  funding  decisions  massively  accelerated  the  trend  to  
quantification.    But  Khurana's  phases  suggest  Kuhnian  paradigm-­‐shifts  as  each  managerial  ideology  
was  displaced.    In  practice  the  non-­‐quantitative  courses  mostly  survive,  just  as  casework  survives,  
though  strategy  lost  its  'capstone'  status  in  the  AACSB's  prescriptions  as  the  AACSB  shifted  its  role  
from  ‘policeman’  to  ‘consultant’  in  the  1990s.    The  balance  within  the  schools  shifted  and,  with  it,  
resources,  organizational  power  and  so  on.    The  non-­‐quantitative  faculty  and  students  became  
second-­‐class  citizens,  the  quants  ruled.      
 
While  the  considerable  literature  on  curriculum  structure  and  process  indicates  continuing  
concern  and  debate,  the  absence  of  an  agreed  theory  of  the  managed  firm  ensured  there  was  a  great  
deal  of  talking  past  each  other.    In  contrast,  Herbert  Simon's  1967  paper  on  the  design  of  the  
BSchool  curriculum  went  to  the  heart  of  the  matter  -­‐  which  was  to  understand  what  'balance'  really  
meant  (Revans,  1967;  Simon,  1967).    There  is  a  handy  distinction  between  'multi-­‐disciplinary',  
suggesting  students  take  a  variety  of  courses,  some  quantitative,  some  not,  and  'inter-­‐disciplinary',  
where  students  learn  how  to  contrast  and  critique  the  differently  based  materials,  and  secondly  
learn-­‐by-­‐doing  how  to  synthesize  a  selection  of  them  into  tackling  a  problem  situation.    In  this  way  
experiential  learning  can  complement  conceptual  learning.    Simon's  pre-­‐WW2  exposure  to  
empirical  social  science  as  the  handmaiden  to  inter-­‐disciplinary  political  decision-­‐making  at  the  
University  of  Chicago  taught  him  the  difference  between  'multi'  and  'inter',  conceptually,  
epistemologically  and  as  an  educational  practice.    Then,  in  1949,  as  a  33-­‐year  old  full  professor  and  
economist,  already  a  national  public  policy  figure,  he  was  offered  the  opportunity  to  play  a  central  
part  in  the  reformulation  of  the  post-­‐WW2  BSchool  curriculum.    He  moved  to  help  Lee  Bach  found  
the  Graduate  School  of  Industrial  Administration  (Carnegie-­‐Mellon).    Bach  had  studied  economics  
at  Chicago,  just  as  Simon  had  done  his  undergrad  degree  in  economics  and  his  PhD  work  there  too.    
Both  men  were  quantitatively  skilled  and  understood  the  potential  business  impact  of  the  tauter  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  30  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

quantitative  methods  of  operations  research  (OR)  developed  during  WW2  and  being  refined  and  
repositioned  by  RAND  colleagues  to  both  men.    Simon's  vision  was  for  GSIA  was  that  it  would  be  
fully  stocked  theoretically  -­‐  in  mathematics,  economics,  finance,  OR,  and  the  social  sciences,  and  
especially  by  its  own  empirical  research  activities  -­‐  but  would  also  be  practice-­‐oriented  (Spender,  
forthcoming).      
 
Simon's  notion  of  practice  was  not  the  rigorous  instantiation  or  application  of  theory  that  now  
seems  to  permeate  our  discipline.    As  the  author  of  the  concept  of  'bounded  rationality'  his  concept  
of  theory  was  not  in  that  tradition.    Rather  it  was  similar  to  Pearson's  'law-­‐like'  summation  of  
empirical  evidence.    But  at  the  same  time,  like  Pearson,  Simon  knew  theory  should  not  even  aspire  
to  grasp  an  empirical  situation  completely;  that  would  be  to  mistake  mechanical  or  photographic  
representation  of  reality  for  the  human  imagination.    The  connection,  of  course,  is  that  no  evidence  
can  be  free  from  the  constraints  of  prior  theorizing,  and  no  imagining  can  be  free  of  experience.    But  
this  connection  is  not  fully  determined;  there  is  some  ‘slop’  between  them.    The  discontinuities  or  
Kuhnian  anomalies  are  the  fissures  in  our  knowing  through  which  we  reach  out  into  the  unknown  
and  bring  something  back  that,  cleaned  off,  named  and  aligned  with  what  we  already  know  
becomes  ‘a  contribution’  to  our  knowing.    This  process  is  the  core  of  the  scientific  method,  which  
relies  on  the  interplay  of  generalities  and  experience.    Hence  practical  situations  were  'practical'  
and  not  'theoretical'  precisely  because  they  cannot  be  analyzed  usefully  as  instantiations  of  a  single  
theory,  for  that  would  exclude  the  discontinuities  essential  to  grasping  the  particular.    Mirroring  the  
distinction  between  generalities  and  particularities,  theory  is  ‘in  the  mind’  and  general  while  
practice  is  ‘in  the  world’  and  particular.    Given  the  lack  of  a  foundational  or  totalizing  theory  of  the  
firm,  it  follows  that  many  alternatives  theories  might  be  informative,  as  in  the  ancient  story  of  the  
blind  men  and  the  elephant.    For  instance,  it  may  make  sense  to  think  of  a  particular  firm  as  a  
system  for  transforming  purchased  inputs  into  products  and  services.    Equally  it  may  make  sense  to  
think  of  the  same  firm  as  a  community  of  particular  individuals  needing  leadership  and  improved  
communications  to  collaborate  better.    Or  it  may  be  useful  to  think  of  the  firm  as  having  strengths,  
weaknesses,  opportunities  and  threats  in  its  particular  relationships  with  its  competitors.    In  
general  each  of  several  incommensurable  theories  might  throw  light  onto  the  situation,  just  as  most  
of  the  BSchool  departments  have  something  to  say  about  most  organizational  phenomena.    For  
Simon  the  key  to  the  concept  of  practice  and  of  balance  was  to  understand  the  human  task  of  
selecting  and  synthesizing  a  particularized  'situated'  action  from  an  inventory  of  possibly  relevant  
the  several  theories.      

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  31  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

 
At  the  time  Simon  wrote  this  paper  he  was  still  struggling  with  the  same  questions  that  
precipitated  the  Methodenstreit.    On  the  one  hand  the  empirical  generalizations  of  the  historicist  
school,  on  the  other  the  rigorous  deductivism  that  is  the  Mengerian  legacy,  supported  by  a  
generation  of  rationalists  like  Walras  and  Jevons,  that  now  dominates  microeconomics;  a  duality  
that  echoes  Aristotle's  disagreements  with  Plato.    In  the  paper  Simon  argued  that  an  appropriately  
structured  and  managed  business  school  could  encourage  habits  of  synthesis  at  the  very  highest  
theoretical  level.    His  practice  orientation  was  no  'watering  down'  but  fully  embraced  the  rigor  of  
theory.    The  rhetorical  power  and  political  appropriateness  of  quantitative  methods  in  the  post-­‐
WW2  context  would  be  both  leavened  and  fructified  by  the  interplay  of  rigorous  methods  and  the  
more  subtle  human  judgments  offered  by  the  social  sciences  and  humanities.    The  quants  and  their  
ilk  would  not  dominate  the  school.    Indeed  other  materials  might  be  brought  into  the  synthesizing  
process  -­‐  especially  practice-­‐based  heuristics,  once  again  opening  the  BSchool  lecture  halls  to  the  
types  of  business-­‐experienced  faculty  member  the  Foundation  Reports  had  so  ruthlessly  but  
perhaps  inadvertently  disenfranchised  (Clinebell  &  Clinebell,  2008;  Wensley,  2011).    Sustaining  the  
necessary  conceptual,  structural  and  pedagogical  openness  would  be  the  Dean's  greatest  and  never-­‐
ending  task;  but  it  would  be  what  made  the  university  situation  different  from  any  goal-­‐oriented  
training,  be  that  in  the  private  or  the  public  sector.    Ironically  Simon  failed  to  implement  his  
interdisciplinary  synthesizing  vision  at  GSIA.    He  learned  he  could  not  sustain  good  relations  with  
his  economist  colleagues  as  they  moved  steadily  to  the  political  right  and  embraced  mathematics  
and  rationalism  as  an  ideology,  delegitimizing  synthesis.    There  was  a  crisis  in  1951  and  another  in  
1957  and  Simon  transported  himself  to  CMU’s  psychology  department  to  advance  the  AI  work  
begun  when  he  met  Allen  Newell  at  RAND  in  1952.    In  a  sense  Simon's  1967  paper  was  his  effort  to  
get  his  vision  worked  out  and  published  a  decade  after  the  academic  hurts  of  the  earlier  conflicts  
had  been  dissolved  by  time  and  his  reputation  solidified  by  the  huge  success  of  his  AI  work.  
 
At  this  point  we  might  conclude  the  impact  of  quantitative  methods  on  BSchools  was  (a)  just  
one  facet  of  a  broader  cultural  trend  that  went  back  to  before  Comte,  (b)  a  reflection  of  their  steady  
advance  into  business  practice,  especially  after  Scientific  Management's  impact,  and  (c)  a  
specifically  post-­‐WW2  response  to  the  development  of  new  complex  organizational  forms  and  the  
quantitative  approaches  fundamental  to  managing  them.    The  increasing  cost-­‐effectiveness  and  use  
of  IT  added  its  own  considerable  impetus.    But  Simon  argued  these  developments  could  facilitate  a  
better  business  school,  they  added  to  its  possibilities  and  what  it  could  usefully  teach,  both  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  32  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

academic  discipline  and  managerial  synthesis.    But  it  all  required  careful  design  and  exceptionally  
talented  BSchool  management  if  the  balance  was  to  be  maintained.    Notwithstanding  having  seen  
and  experienced  its  failure  at  GSIA,  Simon  remained  encouraged.    In  many  respects  his  hopes  are  
mirrored  in  much  of  the  discussion  today.    Without  necessarily  understanding  the  problematics  laid  
out  in  Simon's  analysis,  many  Deans  urge  a  broad  'balanced'  curriculum,  with  new  courses  in  ethics,  
diversity,  cross-­‐cultural  studies,  globalization,  entrepreneurship  and  leadership,  just  as  some  
suggest  interdisciplinary  work,  especially  the  practical  teamwork  that  can  help  students  learn  the  
day-­‐to-­‐day  collaborative  practices  that  mark  much  of  contemporary  business.    Things,  it  seemed,  
could  be  brought  under  control,  in  spite  of  the  absence  of  a  foundational  theory,  largely  by  focusing  
on  teaching  students  about  synthesizing  practice.  
 
Alas,  history  got  into  the  middle  of  this  and  changed  the  business  education  industry  in  ways  
that  rendered  Simon's  vision  little  more  than  a  smudge  in  our  history,  a  promise  scarcely  explored  
let  alone  unfulfilled.    In  the  US,  as  in  the  UK,  political  pressures  in  the  1970s  began  to  push  back  
private-­‐sector  regulation,  especially  in  the  financial  sector.    The  political  imperative  was  these  
countries'  poor  competitive  performance,  especially  against  Japan  and  Germany.    Their  conclusion  
was  that  the  prevailing  degree  of  regulation  was  excessive;  too  socialist,  and  it  hobbled  free  
enterprise.    Free-­‐market  forces  began  their  reign.    In  the  UK  Prime  Minister  Wilson  facilitated  these  
changes  in  part  to  establish  the  City  of  London  as  Europe's  financial  hub,  to  considerable  success,  
the  rapid  expansion  of  the  finance  sector  virtually  making  up  for  the  loss  of  the  UK's  traditional  
manufacturing  or  managerial  capitalist  sector.    Later  in  1987  UK  Prime  Minister  Thatcher  
inadvertently  summed  it  up  with  a  comment  in  an  interview  with  the  magazine  Women's  Own  that  
'there  is  no  such  thing  as  society'  -­‐  recognizing  society  as  something  imagined  but,  in  her  view,  a  
figment  of  mistaken  imagining.    In  the  US  President  Nixon  initiated  a  series  of  legislative  changes  
that  in  due  course,  accelerated  by  the  policies  captured  in  Reagan's  1981  Inaugural  Thatcher-­‐like  
declaration  that  'government  is  not  the  solution,  it  is  the  problem',  led  to  the  1999  repeal  of  the  
Glass-­‐Steagall  Act  of  1932,  the  Depression  era  act  designed  specifically  to  keep  citizens'  banks  from  
engaging  in  the  kinds  of  speculative  activity  that  made  fortunes  for  Joseph  Wharton,  Cornelius  
Vanderbilt,  J.  D.  Rockefeller  and  J.  P.  Morgan.    The  resulting  story  of  financial  catastrophe  is  well  
known,  even  if  not  yet  well  understood,  and  even  if  the  intermediate  1986-­‐1995  Savings  and  Loan  
Crisis,  which  might  have  been  a  lesson,  got  forgotten.    But  the  central  part  that  quantitative  
methods  played,  even  more  conspicuously  in  the  later  period  leading  up  the  collapse  of  Lehman  
Brothers  in  2008,  may  be  less  obvious.      

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  33  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

 
The  rapid  increase  in  deal  making  activity  created  additional  demand  for  quantitatively  trained  
MBAs.    Deregulation  provoked  a  massive  increase  in  the  number  of  financial  speculators  and  'hedge  
funds',  investment  vehicles  that  operated  in  the  'shadow  markets'  beyond  the  reach  of  the  rules  that  
regulated  banks  and  insurance  companies,  and  the  stock  market.    These  vehicles  were  designed  to  
attract  high-­‐wealth  individuals  who  were  in  a  position  to  take  major  risks  in  the  expectation  of  the  
higher-­‐than-­‐normal  returns  to  be  made  trading  junk  bonds  or  currency  and  commodity  options.    
Among  the  more  famous  was  George  Soros,  a  hedge  funder  and  currency  specialist  who  took  an  
historic  bet,  selling  around  $10  billion  short  against  sterling  during  the  1992  crisis.    Sterling  was  
devalued  and  Soros  made  a  billion  dollars  net  at  the  marginal  cost  of  borrowing  the  $10  billion  for  a  
few  days.    In  contrast  the  regulations  had  previously  obliged  those  managing  funds  belonging  to  
ordinary  citizens  (non-­‐sophisticated  investors,  'widows  and  orphans')  to  invest  in  'blue-­‐chip'  low-­‐
risk  vehicles  that  generated  trivial  returns  -­‐  and  so  no  prospect  of  the  huge  bonuses  to  be  made  as  a  
trader.    As  the  hedge  funds  expanded  they  created  additional  demand  for  quantitatively  skilled  
MBAs.    News  of  the  money  to  be  made  began  to  percolate  and  transform  the  climate  in  BSchools  as  
more  students  clamored  to  be  equipped  analytically  for  jobs  there.    But  the  more  fundamental  
change  was  that  an  entirely  new  generation  of  finance  sector  staff  -­‐  the  REAL  quants,  often  PhD  
physicists,  biologists,  engineers  -­‐  'rocket  scientists'  -­‐  began  to  invent  completely  new  'financial  
products',  such  as  derivatives  and  credit-­‐default  swaps,  that  were  produced  by  building  models  of  
entirely  imagined  trades  that  thereby  brought  the  new  markets  into  existence  in  which  dealers  and  
traders  could  then  gamble  -­‐  hugely  (Avellaneda,  1999;  Benninga,  2008;  Patterson,  2010).    None  of  
this  would  have  been  possible  without  the  huge  advances  in  financial  computing  and  Internet  
communication  that  made  it  financially  and  technically  feasible  to  translate  the  real  quants'  
mathematics  into  traders'  tools  available  world-­‐wide  24  hours  a  day  -­‐  to  'monetize  the  math'.  
 
As  these  new  instruments  and  markets  emerged  hedge  fund  managers  or  financial  operatives  
were  no  longer  constrained  to  buying  and  selling  real  firms,  real  products,  or  real  commodities.    At  
the  extreme,  they  took  the  most  basic  function  of  the  capitalist  financial  system  -­‐  to  gather  up  
citizens'  funds  so  that  free  market  forces  could  channel  them  towards  profitable  enterprises  -­‐  and  
turned  it  on  its  head,  focusing  instead  on  the  debts  created  as  investments  were  made.    The  debts  
were  collected  and  packaged,  and  then  bought  and  sold  as  if  they  were  real  commodities.    Further  
debts  were  incurred  as  traders  borrowed  further  to  buy,  sell  and  take  further  options  on  these  debt  
packages.    The  secondary  markets  that  underpinned  -­‐  or  undermined  -­‐  the  'real'  markets,  were  then  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  34  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

underpinned  by  tertiary  markets,  and  so  on,  digging  ever  deeper  into  bottomless  debt-­‐mines.    
Wherever  the  debts  mined  accumulated  like  mine  spoil  as  the  economy  expanded  steadily  through  
the  1970  −  2000  period,  there  were  accumulating  opportunities  for  others  to  repackage  them  and  
trade  them  as  a  highly  leveraged  gamble.    Any  kind  of  debt  was  grist  for  this  mill,  currency  options,  
corporate  debt,  student  loans,  auto  loans,  overseas  sovereign  debt,  etc.  but  housing  especially  -­‐  
being  most  citizens'  most  significant  borrowing  -­‐  offered  rich  pickings.    The  most  egregious  
example  of  this  debt-­‐mining  opportunism  -­‐  as  far  as  we  know  at  this  writing  -­‐  was  Goldman  Sachs's  
assembling,  with  hedge-­‐fund  manager  John  A.  Paulson's  help,  and  then  selling  packages  of  sub-­‐
prime  US  mortgages  to  'clients'  and  then,  for  a  fee  with  other  clients'  money,  'betting'  on  these  same  
packages'  failure.    In  his  General  Theory,  Keynes  disapprovingly  called  this  kind  of  activity  'casino  
capitalism'  (Dimand  &  Dore,  2000;  Keynes,  2009),  though  he  would  surely  have  a  sharper  term  
today.    Its  'investment'  aspects  are  almost  completely  detached  from  the  economy's  wealth-­‐
producing  activity  and,  therefore  side  step  the  financial  sector's  duty  towards  the  nation.    With  this  
development  the  financial  sector's  operations  moved  well  beyond  any  relationship  between  
management  and  national  duty,  or  management  and  private  firms'  productive  efficiency,  or  even  
management  and  the  energetic  industrial  restructuring  the  conglomerators  and  asset-­‐strippers  
introduced,  instead  the  'high  end'  of  the  financial  sector  became  wholly  taken  up  with  outright  
gambling  -­‐  thereby  denying  its  bounden  duty  to  the  country,  the  duty  that  gives  the  banking  system  
its  charter  in  a  capitalist  democracy.    Plus,  given  the  artificiality  of  the  vehicles  and  markets  created,  
there  was  also  the  strong  possibility  the  game  was  often  'rigged'  by  its  leading  players.  
 
While  the  BSchools  seldom  had  the  high-­‐level  quantitative  skills  necessary  to  train  the  new  
generation  of  rocket-­‐science  quants,  new  generations  of  faculty  took  on  two  supporting  duties  (a)  
to  develop  the  ideology  that  would  legitimate  casino  trading  and  so  shape  and  forestall  public  
policies  that  might  otherwise  move  to  disallow  it,  as  Antitrust  legislation  had  in  the  1880s  and  
1930s,  and  (b)  to  train  a  new  generation  of  operatives,  traders  and  salesmen  to  use  these  models  
and  sell  the  'products'  being  developed,  these  activities  merging  retail  mortgage,  stock  option  and  
currency  dealing  into  the  blurred  mass  of  computer  networked  activity  visible  in  the  new  bank  and  
hedge  fund  trading  rooms.    The  new  ideology  was  grounded  in  the  proposition  that  the  markets  
were  efficient,  one  of  the  chief  implications  of  the  rationalism  against  which  Simon  struggled  
ineffectually.    In  the  real  world  of  finance  the  claim  was  the  markets  were  more  efficient  at  pricing  
something  than  any  real  individual  or  group  of  individuals  could  be.    Markets  were  presumed  to  be  
especially  more  efficient  than  managers  who  were  typically  over  confident  and  under-­‐informed,  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  35  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

and  often  self-­‐interested  and  inattentive  to  the  shareholders'  interests.    A  secondary  effect  of  an  
efficient  market  was  that  it  provoked  the  invention  of  and  trading  in  new  financial  instruments,  
such  as  options,  that  leveraged  the  buying  and  selling  of  things  tangible,  be  they  shares  in  a  
business  or  a  commodity  like  wheat,  pork  bellies  or  oil.      
 
An  energetic  group  of  new  economists,  especially  those  from  the  Chicago  and  Rochester  Schools  
of  Economics,  leveraged  the  work  at  RAND  and  underpinned  the  growing  options  trading  activity  
with  a  'theory  of  options'  that  seemed  to  prove  markets  knew  best,  and  provoked  further  
exploration  of  the  implications.    Three  of  these  stood  out.    First,  the  managers'  sole  role  was  defined  
as  maximizing  the  investors'  return,  no  ifs  or  buts.    Second,  firms  were  not  transparent  and,  hidden  
in  the  organizational  shadows  that  even  the  best  metrics  and  quantification  could  not  penetrate,  
managers  had  incentives  to  skim  the  investors'  returns  as  personal  benefits  -­‐  leading  to  what  is  now  
known  as  'principal-­‐agent  theory'  (often  mislabeled  'agency  theory',  which  is  actually  about  human  
choosing  in  under-­‐determined  situations)(Spender,  2011a).    Third,  there  seemed  to  be  an  answer  
to  the  riddle  that  Ronald  Coase  posed  in  his  famous  1937  paper  on  the  nature  of  the  firm.    He  
hypothesized  firms  existed  only  because  they  provided  a  context  in  which  economic  transactions  
could  be  undertaken  at  less  cost  than  those  same  transactions  could  be  undertaken  in  'the  market'.    
Thus  extending  and  expanding  the  markets  in  which  investments  could  be  translated  into  revenue  
would  police  and  put  additional  pressure  on  firms  and  their  managers.    For  example,  if  new  
markets  were  created  for  the  intermediate  products  involved  in  writing  a  complex  piece  of  
computer  software,  the  overall  economic  system  -­‐  the  programming  project  plus  the  market  
operations  -­‐  would  be  more  efficient.    We  see  these  notions  implemented  as  moves  to  software  
modularization,  object-­‐oriented  programming,  and  open  sourcing.    The  same  applies  to  the  building  
of  a  bridge  or  a  skyscraper,  typically  broken  down  into  a  complex  of  subcontracts  awarded  
competitively.      
 
The  combination  of  these  three  implications  meant  that  management  was  redefined  as  ‘the  
problem’  rather  than  as  a  resource  or  an  asset;  managers  were  seen  as  the  custodian  of  investors'  
wealth,  not  its  source.    Khurana  called  this  the  'delegitimation  of  managerial  authority'  (Khurana,  
2007:317),  though  this  does  not  capture  sufficiently  the  glorification  of  those  making  and  trading  in  
the  new  markets,  the  bankers,  traders  and  investment  fund  managers  who  dubbed  themselves  
'masters  of  the  universe'  (MOTU).    The  efficient-­‐market  approach  also  put  renewed  attention  onto  
the  market  for  'corporate  control'  itself,  the  topic  raised  a  century  earlier  in  1904  by  Thorstein  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  36  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

Veblen  (Veblen,  1965).    Veblen  saw  four  competing  groups  seeking  to  appropriate  the  benefits  of  
the  firm's  activity  -­‐  investors,  managers,  employees  and  customers.    Berle  &  Means's  1932  book  left  
employees  and  customers  out  of  the  equation  and  focused  on  the  separation  of  ownership  and  
control.    The  new  economists  argued  that  since  markets  were  efficient,  control  should  be  passed  as  
fully  as  possible  to  those  operating  in  and  listening  to  the  market  (for  the  firm's  shares,  for  put  and  
call  options,  for  derivatives  based  on  them,  for  corporate  control,  etc.).    Managers  were  merely  
passive  agents.    Implicit,  of  course,  was  a  theory  of  the  firm,  though  not  one  that  had  a  significant  
place  for  anything  other  than  a  purely  mechanical,  transparent  and  rational  manager.    This  group  of  
economists  aggressively  'colonized'  the  territory  to  be  occupied  by  a  foundational  theory  of  the  
managed  firm  (Fine  &  Green,  2000),  an  area  more  or  less  abandoned  by  generations  of  organization  
and  management  theorists  who  had  been  unable  to  add  much  to  their  leading  candidate,  
bureaucratic  theory,  since  Cohen,  Cyert,  March,  Simon  and  their  CMU  colleagues  pursued  a  
'behavioral'  theory  of  the  firm  (K.  J.  Cohen  &  Cyert,  1965;  Cyert  &  March,  1963;  March  &  Simon,  
1958).    Interestingly,  these  writings  were  the  fruit  of  GSIA's  exemplary  non-­‐quantitative  research  
program  in  the  years  before  the  neoclassical  economists  extinguished  Simon’s  vision  of  a  school  of  
synthesis.  
 
 
BSchools'  Challenges  
 
The  story  in  the  preceding  sections  is  that  the  business  schools,  especially  in  the  US,  simply  
followed  their  market,  responding  to  the  new  opportunities  available  to  their  students  as  the  
economy's  center  of  gravity  shifted  from  commodities  and  Taylorist  manufacturing  to  retailing,  to  
services  in  general  and  then  to  post-­‐deregulation  financial  services  in  particular.    Quantitative  
methods  played  a  major  role  in  facilitating  the  shift  and  while  the  market  for  BSchool  students  grew  
steadily  throughout,  those  with  quantitative  skills  were  able  to  take  particular  advantage  of  the  
changes.    The  quantitative  segment  of  the  curriculum  was  significantly  strengthened,  especially  
after  the  1959  Foundation  Reports.    Student  interest  in  manufacturing  declined  while  interest  in  
jobs  on  Wall  Street  and  in  the  IT,  deal-­‐making,  and  marketing  consultancies  rose.      
 
So,  back  to  the  question  in  title  of  this  essay,  what  happened  and  what  is  to  be  done  about  it?    
What  happened  was  that  democratic  capitalism  once  again  displayed  its  remarkable  capacity  to  re-­‐
invent  itself  as  the  world  changed  -­‐  irrevocably.    The  fact  that  the  financial  services  sector,  and  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  37  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

eventually  the  world,  was  savagely  transformed  by  the  quants'  capacity  to  invent  some  new  
products  and  markets  that  opened  up  a  new  universe  of  extraordinarily  highly  paid  work,  and  that  
these  developments  are  now  widely  judged  to  have  been  profoundly  destructive,  corrupting  and  
against  the  public  interest,  cannot  be  charged  against  the  quants,  nor  the  BSchool  professors  who  
taught  them  nor,  really,  those  schools'  administrators  and  Deans  -­‐  any  more  than  the  scientists  and  
administrators  who  produced  the  atom  bombs  were  to  be  blamed  for  the  consequences  of  their  use  
in  Japan  or  the  global  consequences  elsewhere  as  they  competed  amongst  themselves  for  jobs,  
scientific  fame  or  power.    Warren  Buffett  noted  the  analogy  in  the  Berkshire  Hathaway  2002  annual  
report  and  remarked  "derivatives  are  financial  weapons  of  mass  destruction".    Like  the  BSchool  
professors  and  their  students,  the  atom  scientists  and  engineers  were  the  human  components  in  a  
complex  dynamic  social  and  technological  system  that  had  no  clear  structure  and  few  identifiable  
centers  of  control,  perhaps  in  Washington,  perhaps  in  Wall  Street,  perhaps  in  the  schools  and  
universities  in  which  students  were  sometimes  encouraged  to  discover  and  explore  questions  
about  the  human  and  social  values  that  shape  the  public's  democratic  choices.  
 
The  story  is  also  that  BSchool  administrators  and  those  engaged  in  research,  teaching  and  
community  service  lacked  an  anchoring  core  of  concepts  or  principles  that  might  have  enabled  
them  (a)  to  balance  a  curriculum  of  quantitative  methods  and  rigorous  theorizing  against  the  
different  understandings  of  the  human  condition  available  through  the  liberal  arts  and  social  
sciences,  and  (b)  to  handle  the  tensions  present  in  every  school  oriented  towards  practice  between  
what  is  best  learned  intellectually  through  study  and  what  is  best  learned  experientially.    Absent  
this  touchstone  the  BSchools,  indeed  the  entire  management  education  enterprise,  remains  up  for  
grabs  as  a  set  of  poorly  inter-­‐related  educational  and  promotional  activities  complemented  by  the  
din  as  one  discipline  was  thrown  against  another  without  evident  clarification  or  conclusion.    The  
ebb  and  flow  of  tension  between  the  rankings,  administrators,  and  curriculum  designers  continues  
(Adler  &  Harzing,  2009;  Morgeson  &  Nahrgang,  2006;  Özbilgin,  2009;  Wedlin,  2011).    In  the  
absence  of  a  core  theory  of  the  managed  private-­‐sector  firm  the  current  effort  to  patch  courses  on  
business  ethics,  corporate  social  responsibility,  cross-­‐cultural  or  diversity  management,  corporate  
greening,  sustainability,  and  so  on  into  the  existing  curriculum  cannot  be  theorized  or  otherwise  
justified,  however  good  it  may  sound  to  the  administration  or  appear  in  the  fund-­‐raising  or  
recruiting  materials.    It  may  salve  some  consciences  but  it  cannot  do  much  for  students  not  being  
taught  how  to  incorporate  those  materials  into  real-­‐world  practice.    They  might  just  as  well  study  
meditation  or  tapestry  making.  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  38  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

 
What  is  to  be  done?      Our  historians,  both  critical  and  supportive,  have  hugely  enriched  the  
expanding  literature  on  BSchools.    After  more  or  less  ignoring  our  history  for  50  years  we  have  now  
learned  a  great  deal  about  the  events  and  processes  that  shaped  our  schools  and  their  doings  
(Cummings  &  Bridgman,  2011).    But  the  historical  method  has  its  own  shortcomings,  and  these  are  
seldom  considered  or  even  discussed  in  our  environment  (Booth  &  Rowlinson,  2006;  Clark  &  
Rowlinson,  2004;  Collingwood,  1994;  Madansky,  2008;  Rowlinson,  Clark,  Delahaye-­‐Dado,  Booth,  &  
Procter,  2008;  Wright,  2010).    First,  historical  research  is  provocative  rather  than  conclusive.    It  
indicates  what  kinds  of  theory  might  be  brought  into  consideration  without  ever  offering  a  theory  
of  its  own.    But,  as  the  Methodenstreit  showed,  the  methodology's  powers  are  persistent  and  
balance  our  other  research  methodologies,  especially  those  of  the  'objectivists'  and  positivists.    The  
historical  method  does  not  presume  causality;  rather,  in  addition  to  piling  up  facts,  it  searches  for  
connections  that  might  lead  the  researcher's  imagination  towards  law-­‐like  ideas.    In  part  the  
historical  method  can  be  understood  as  the  practical  consequences  of  being  without  causality  as  an  
intellectual  tool.    So  it  is  a  pity  BSchools'  methodology  courses  do  not  deal  with  the  historical  
method  (Van  Fleet  &  Wren,  2005).    Rather  these  courses  have  often  shriveled  into  rote-­‐learning  of  
normal-­‐distribution  statistics,  ignoring  the  mysteries  of  epistemology,  along  with  logic  itself,  non-­‐
Gaussian  statistics,  fuzzy  sets,  small  world  phenomena,  simulation  and  the  rest  of  the  ever-­‐
expanding  toolkit  of  quantitative  tools.    Our  students  deserve  more;  perhaps  indicated  by  statistics  
suggesting  that  while  the  BSchool  students'  abilities  are  steadily  improving,  their  grades,  
attendance  and  intellectual  achievements  are  declining.    Along  with  grade  inflation,  the  curriculum  
struggles  and  inter-­‐school  competition  seem  to  be  dumbing  down  the  MBA  product.      
 
Second,  the  historical  method  requires  a  'narrative  line'.    This  is  laid  into  the  analysis  by  the  
historian  and  becomes  the  lens  by  which  historical  facts  are  noted  or  ignored.    For  instance,  most  of  
the  pre-­‐20th  century  US  universities  were  created  from  the  religious  universities  of  the  18th  and  19th  
centuries.    Yet  religion  is  scarcely  mentioned  in  the  BSchool  literature  (Khurana's  comments  being  a  
notable  exception).    But  Catholic  business  schools,  especially  those  of  the  Jesuits,  do  not  offer  the  
same  educational  experience  as  secular  schools.    Mormon  schools  such  as  BYU  differ,  just  as  the  
New  School  in  New  York  differs  and  the  technology-­‐oriented  schools  like  MIT,  Polytechnic  and  
Rennselaer  differ  too.    Even  when  the  curriculum  looks  the  same,  the  student  experience  differs  in  
important  ways  suggesting  the  school's  culture  can  become  an  important  narrative  line.    Likewise,  
our  discipline's  recent  historians  offer  different  narrative  lines.    O'Connor's  was  the  loss  of  the  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  39  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

humanism  at  the  core  of  Follett  and  Barnard's  theorizing  about  economic  activity  in  a  capitalist  
democracy  (O'Connor,  2011).    It  follows  that  recovering  and  re-­‐institutionalizing  this  humanism,  
positioned  as  the  core  principle  against  which  everything  else  is  tested,  is  both  a  prescription  for  
some  BSchool  strategists  and  also  an  explanation  of  what  many  Deans  and  faculty  are  trying  to  do  
right  now,  impelled  by  their  own  intuitions  and  reading  of  the  world  around  them.      
 
Khurana's  narrative  line  spun  out  of  the  'professionalization  project'.    Whether  there  ever  was  
such  a  project,  with  its  implications  of  the  US  elite  overtly  collaborating  in  what  we  now  call  'social  
engineering',  is  less  important  than  the  line's  strength  as  a  rhetorical  device,  making  it  possible  to  
tell  the  story  of  the  project's  birth,  decline  and  ultimate  dismissal.    Without  it  we  would  make  little  
sense  of  his  phases  and  the  transformations  in  educational  and  institutional  objectives  they  implied  
(Figure  1).    In  this  essay  I  leverage  off  his  phases  as  choices  made  by  BSchool  administrators,  
arguing  (a)  the  BSchools  were  following  the  market  changes  that  drove  their  students'  interests,  
and  (b)  a  distinction  between  the  older  opportunities  in  managerial  capitalism,  and  deal-­‐making  or  
investor  capitalism  and  the  new  ones  in  casino  capitalism  (Figure  2).    Hence  I  do  not  need  to  
subscribe  to  the  'professionalization  project'  and  look  instead  towards  the  history  of  the  economy,  
especially  to  the  history  of  US  private  sector  financial  activities  and  services.    In  the  first  of  
Khurana's  phases,  in  the  pre-­‐1920s,  business  people  were  probably  more  focused  on  acquiring  or  
resisting  monopolistic  rent-­‐streams,  be  they  based  on  proprietary  advantage  in  metallurgy  
(Wharton),  distribution  (Rockefeller),  manufacturing  (Carnegie  &  Ford),  mining  (Hickey),  or  news  
(Hearst),  or  from  political  connections  (Wharton  again)  or  mass  appeal  (Wrigley's  chewing  gum  
perhaps),  than  they  were  focused  on  the  'higher  aims'  of  public  duty  -­‐  and  because  of  this,  Antitrust  
legislation  was  needed  to  restore  a  balance  between  business  and  the  public  weal.    Thus  I  argue  the  
story  of  the  modern  US  business  school  begins  with  managerial  capitalism  and  the  idea  that  hiring  
better  trained  managers  would  lead  to  better  profits,  the  same  impulses  that  propelled  the  earlier  
proprietary  schools  that  sprang  up  in  the  1750s  (Bossard  &  Dewhurst,  1931;  Khurana,  2007:88;  
Ruch,  2003).    This  frames  most  of  the  early  university  schools  as  local  responses  to  the  local  need  
for  better  managers,  competing  directly  with  the  many  existing  proprietary  schools.    Eventually,  
primarily  through  their  closer  social  and  political  connections  to  the  capitalists  of  the  day,  the  
university-­‐based  schools  became  better  positioned  to  meet  the  national  needs  for  managers  that  
became  particularly  urgent  in  the  post-­‐WW1  period  of  US  economic  expansion.    These  days,  in  
contrast,  we  see  a  rapid  expansion  in  the  education-­‐for-­‐profit  sector,  with  business  studies  leading  
the  way  (Apling,  1993;  Tierney  &  Hentshcke,  2007).  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  40  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

 
As  BSchool  historians  know,  the  early  university  schools'  curriculum  was  not  based  on  any  
theories  or  reasoned  collection  of  American  insights  about  how  firms  or  democratic  capitalism  
worked,  nor  on  the  curricula  offered  in  the  many  proprietary  business  schools  that  focused  on  
book-­‐keeping  and  secretarial  work  such  as  correspondence  and  advertising  (Freedley,  1853,  1879).    
Rather  it  was  transported  from  the  public  policy  schools  in  Germany  where  the  foundational  
concept  was  the  same  as  that  of  Alexander  the  Great  millennia  before  -­‐  that  better  trained  
administrators  would  lead  to  a  more  efficient,  manageable,  and  militarily  and  economically  
powerful  State/Empire  (Redlich,  1957).    Note  the  Prussian  administrators'  concept  of  duty  was  as  a  
state  employee,  not  much  to  do  with  the  19th  century  American  private-­‐sector  entrepreneur's  moral  
contest  of  social  duty  versus  personal  gain.    In  making  the  translation  from  Cameralism  noted  by  
Woodrow  Wilson  (W.  Wilson,  1887),  American  writers  replaced  the  political  process  as  the  source  
of  an  organization's  goals  with  private  sector  market  forces.    By  the  1920s  the  BSchools  syllabus  
had  taken  on  the  familiar  external-­‐internal  analysis  and  arrangement  that  remains  so  familiar  today  
(Marshall,  1921).  The  subsequent  shift  to  investor  capitalism  was,  as  so  often  in  history,  an  
unanticipated  consequence  of  continued  economic  growth  and  the  politically  supported  (and  tax  
structured)  desire  to  widen  share  ownership  and  thereby  to  expand  and  stabilize  the  middle  class,  
and  the  resulting  growth  of  mutual  funds  as  the  US  alternative  to  the  firm  or  cooperative-­‐based  
pension  schemes  typical  in  Europe.    Ordinary  people  ('unsophisticated  investors')  discovered  their  
modest  savings  need  not  lie  dormant  in  the  bank,  but  post-­‐FDIC  especially,  could  be  'managed'  -­‐  and  
thus  a  new  financial  industry  was  spawned.  
 
Third,  especially  when  it  comes  to  the  rise  of  casino  capitalism,  the  story  hinges  on  the  
distinction  between  quantitative  methods,  such  as  statistical  analysis,  that  reveal  relationships  in  
bodies  of  empirical  data  about  past  events  and  those  of  'mathematical  finance'  that  allow  analysts  
to  model  and  price  a  future  event.    In  practice  such  models  facilitated  (a)  making  or  valuing  a  bet  on  
an  anticipated  event,  such  as  a  forward  price  for  oil  and  (b)  making  a  market  for  these  bets,  perhaps  
in  oil  options,  wherein  one  trader's  valuation  may  differ  from  others'  and,  thus,  arbitrage  
opportunities  arise  (Avellaneda,  1999;  Benninga,  2008).    The  distinction  between  analysis  and  
modeling  is  precisely  that  explored  by  Pearson  and,  as  Porter's  work  detailed,  between  the  English  
economists  and  the  French  engineer-­‐economists  many  decades  before  (T.  M.  Porter,  1995:57).    It  
was  also  central  to  Simon's  thinking  and  his  notion  of  ‘empirical  positivism’,  quantification  in  the  
service  of  public  policy  (Spender,  forthcoming).      

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  41  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

 
Managerial  capitalism,  shareholder  capitalism  and  casino  capitalism  all  created  significant  new  
demand  for  MBAs  skilled  in  quantitative  methods,  but  to  be  harnessed  in  very  different  ways.    
Developing  evidence-­‐based  generalizations  from  empirical  data  about  the  world  is  one  thing.    
Developing  models  and  imagining  the  new  worlds  and  markets  that  facilitated  bets  on  the  way  the  
world  turns  out  is  quite  another.    The  games  of  science  fiction,  computer  games  like  Battlefield  2,  or  
open-­‐ended  virtual  worlds  such  as  Second  Life  are  whatever  people  wish  to  make  of  them,  they  are  
abstractions  not  tightly  connected  to  the  lived  life  -­‐  though  social  and  psychological  connections  are  
explored  in  Turkle's  work,  for  instance  (Turkle,  1984).    But  the  distinction  vanishes  in  the  financial  
services  area  for  their  imaginings  are  the  veins  and  arteries  of  our  capitalist  corpus.    The  boundary  
between  the  game  and  the  lived  life  blurs,  for  money  and  markets  are  imagined  constructions  too.    
Indeed  many  of  those  involved  in  the  financial  convolutions  of  2008  described  their  activities  as  
'the  game',  one  they  were  strongly  motivated  and  incentivized  to  'win'  by  scoring  the  biggest  
personal  takes  (Sorkin,  2009).    Clearly  both  types  of  quantitative  skill  are  valuable  and  belong  in  the  
BSchool  curriculum  -­‐  and  there  is  no  compelling  evidence  that  teaching  them  has  much  influence  on  
society  at  large  or  even  on  most  individuals'  personal  philosophy.    If  the  economy  is  plunging  
through  the  type  of  historical  cycle  that  interested  Kondratiev,  Keynes,  Schumpeter  or  Minsky  that  
is  a  social  and  political  matter  and  changing  the  business  school  curriculum  is  not  going  to  have  
much  impact.  
 
Fourth,  the  way  the  BSchool  syllabus's  quantitative  and  non-­‐quantitative  elements  are  
supposed  to  fit  together  as  a  coherent  student  experience  has  not  been  much  discussed,  one  notable  
exception  being  Simon's  1967  article.    The  pedagogical  challenge  is  illuminated  by  the  distinction  
between  multi-­‐disciplinary  and  inter-­‐disciplinary,  the  first  being  aggregative,  the  second  
emphasizing  synthesis.    Many  Deans  talk  optimistically  of  the  beneficial  consequences  of  having  
students  study  across  the  faculty  silos  as  if  multi-­‐  and  inter-­‐  were  pretty  much  the  same.    This  
makes  light  of  the  faculty's  strong  incentives  to  mine  their  disciplinary  silos  and  teach  what  they  
know  best,  and  the  sheer  pedagogical  challenge  of  helping  students  develop  the  indefinite  skills  of  
synthesizing.    What  of  this  can  be  taught  or  graded?    Casework  is  sometimes,  but  not  always,  seen  
as  a  reasonably  economical  and  manageable  way  to  create  the  context  in  which  students  develop  
synthesizing  skills  (Rochford  &  Borchert,  2011).    Sandwich  or  co-­‐op  courses  may  be  less  economic  
but  more  effective  (Berggren  &  Söderlund,  2011;  Blackler  &  Regan,  2009).    Are  there  ways  of  
preparing  students  to  profit  from  this  kind  of  experiential  learning?    The  first  step  is  probably  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  42  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

Deweyian,  opening  the  student's  mind  to  the  possibility  of  alternative  ways  of  viewing  what  is  
already  known,  sometimes  called  'defamiliarization'.    This  means  the  development  of  our  native  
critical  faculties.    Criticism  was  long  regarded  as  the  spur  to  the  growth  of  knowledge  in  the  natural  
sciences  (Lakatos,  1970;  Lakatos  &  Musgrave,  1970).    It  has  a  long  history  and  is  still  taught  in  
literary  fields  as  a  way  to  develop  creative  writing  skills  (Foster,  1968;  Starkey,  Hatchuel,  &  
Tempest,  2004).    But  the  teaching  of  criticism  and  'critical  thinking  skills'  has  few  evident  places  in  
the  BBA  or  MBA  curriculum  and  is  seldom  considered  central  to  the  BSchools'  methodology  courses  
(Reid  &  Anderson,  2012).      Consequently  few  in  our  area  make  any  connection  between  (a)  the  craft  
of  criticism  and  (b)  the  strategic  or  entrepreneurial  synthesizing  process  in  business.    Yet  just  as  in  
Kurt  Lewin's  familiar  'opening  and  closing'  model,  the  second  learning  step  is  synthesis,  
experiential  as  one  closure  at  a  time,  the  antithesis  of  both  generalizing  and  theorizing.  
 
Fifth,  in  spite  of  Simon's  work,  the  success  of  GSIA's  research  into  a  behavioral  theory  of  the  
firm,  and  the  subsequent  theoretical  and  commercial  developments  in  AI  and  expert  systems,  
BSchools  seem  not  much  interested  in  tabulating  business-­‐relevant  heuristics  or  the  processes  by  
which  they  arise.    Note  the  distinction  previously  noted  between  (a)  the  use  of  statistics  to  tease  
correlations  out  of  empirical  data  and  (b)  the  use  of  mathematical  modeling  to  price  against  future  
markets  is  the  distinction  between  heuristic  and  theory  in  different  language.    Heuristics  are  
inductions  from  the  past,  theorizing  is  forecasting  the  future  (Gigerenzer  &  Selten,  2001;  
Gigerenzer,  Todd,  &  The  ABC  Research  Group,  1999;  Welsch  &  Cyert,  1970).    Heuristics  are  
evidence  of  attention,  observation  and  reflection,  often  facilitated  by  discussions  or  
communications  with  others  engaged  in  similar  activity  (Schön,  1983,  1987).    Communities  of  
practice,  industry  and  professional  meetings,  quality  circles  and  so  on  facilitate  the  development  
and  circulation  of  heuristics  (Spender,  1989).    Heuristics  can  be  proto-­‐theories,  suggesting  ongoing  
dependable  patterns.    The  fields  of  medicine  and  engineering  are  marked  by  large  bodies  of  
practical  heuristics,  'best  practices'  and  ways  of  doing  passed  down  through  the  ages,  steadily  
accumulated  through  ongoing  practice  (Eamon,  1994).    Theory  differs  because  it  is  deductive,  
proceeding  from  axioms  to  demonstrations  that  are  only  as  valid  as  the  axioms.    There  can  be  no  
logical  justification  of  the  axioms;  they  are  the  imaginative  presuppositions  that  allow  the  
theorizing  to  begin.    The  debates  around  'positive  economics'  and  the  logical  relationships  between  
predictability  and  axiomatic  validity  are  some  of  the  better-­‐known  consequences  of  thinking  
through  the  difference  between  heuristics  and  theories  (Boland,  1979;  Friedman,  1953).      
 

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  43  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

The  interaction  of  heuristics  and  theory  can  become  fruitful  when  heuristics  lead  the  human  
imagination  to  law-­‐like  relations  -­‐  hypotheses  -­‐  that  are  testable.    It  is  widely  recognized  that  some  
preparation  of  the  mind  can  help.    One  means  is  deep  immersion  in  the  context  of  practices  from  
which  the  heuristics  are  emerging.    The  second  being  the  process  of  mind-­‐clearing  made  possible  
by  critical  thinking,  often  followed  by  a  period  of  mental  diversion,  blanking  the  mind  in  the  
expectation  that  something  will  'pop  up'.    Wittgenstein  would  spend  his  afternoon  at  the  movies  
watching  Westerns;  others  go  to  the  gym  or  for  a  walk.    It  is  widely  argued  that  a  profession  stands  
on  a  body  of  'professional  knowledge',  but  it  is  less  obvious  what  this  actually  comprises  (Abbott,  
1988;  Larson,  1977).    The  positivist  tic,  of  course,  is  that  all  human  knowledge  is  theory,  rigorously  
constructed  and  empirically  validated.    While  there  are  workable  theories  in  some  fields  an  
examination  of  the  'knowledge'  actually  used  by  most  professionals  -­‐  architects,  engineers,  lawyers,  
doctors,  accountants,  etc.  -­‐  suggests  they  use  heuristics  much  more  (Schön,  1983,  1987).    In  
engineering,  for  instance,  piping,  bridge  building,  electrical  systems  design  and  so  on  are  governed  
by  the  government-­‐backed  standards  maintained  by  the  professional  engineering  associations  such  
as  ASME.    While  these  are  often  under  critical  scrutiny  by  academic  scientists,  they  are  largely  built  
up  from  practice-­‐sourced  heuristics.    The  same  is  true  in  medicine,  thought  those  standards  are  less  
tabulated  and  formalized  and  more  the  practices  inculcated  during  training.    In  the  law  there  is  
virtually  no  theory-­‐guided  practice  though  'natural  law'  thinking  remains  a  major  influence  in  the  
US.    Neoclassical  economics,  in  contrast,  is  all  theory  and  no  heuristics  save  for  the  selection  of  its  
axioms,  but  perhaps  economics  is  not  a  profession.    It  is  easy  to  forget  the  European  university  was  
professional  in  origin,  springing  into  existence  as  the  Arab-­‐mediated  translations  of  the  Greek  
classics  provided  European  scholars  with  a  fresh  body  of  knowledge  from  which  to  critique  
medieval  religious  dogma  and  establish  the  new  professions  of  law  and  medicine  (Haskins,  1957).    
The  knowledge  transferred  provided  the  basis  for  new  thinking  and  practice  in  the  law,  notably  at  
Bologna,  and  medicine,  with  translations  of  Hippocrates,  Galen  and  Avicenna.    The  professional  
heuristics  made  available  were  more  immediately  influential  than  the  mathematical  and  
astronomical  theoretical  works  of  Euclid  and  Ptolemy  that  eventually  led  to  the  profession  of  
natural  science.    Professional  theology  and  education  came  later  (Haskins,  1957:54).  
 
Sixth,  Khurana  noted  the  BSchools'  recent  turn  to  'leadership'  (Avolio,  Walumbwa,  &  Weber,  
2009;  Khurana,  2007:352;  Nohria  &  Khurana,  2010)  as  a  result  of  a  ‘crisis  of  identity’  in  the  1990s.    
He  traces  this  to  the  1940s  military-­‐oriented  leadership  studies  at  Ohio  State.    Military  schools  had  
a  long  history  of  interest  in  leadership  and  the  psychological  angles  opened  up  by  the  work  of  the  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  44  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

pragmatists,  Freudians,  and  Gestalt  experiments  had  a  major  impact  on  officer  training  during  
WW2  and  thereafter.    Many  of  the  techniques  and  practices  developed  passed  into  private  sector  
business  through  the  work  of  ex-­‐military  human  resource  managers  and  consultants.    Khurana  
noted  the  distinction  between  leaders  and  managers  popularized  by  Zaleznik,  who  had  no  such  
background.    He  defined  leaders  as  imaginative,  frame  breaking  and  charismatic  while  managers  
focused  on  rationality  and  control,  reaching  back  into  Weber's  distinctions  between  traditional,  
rational  and  charismatic  authority.    A  rather  different  concept  of  leadership  turns  on  synthesis,  
leaders  being  those  able  to  respond  to  uncertainty  by  synthesizing  the  available  evidence  into  
reasoned  action  (Spender,  2008a).    Synthesis  requires  imagination,  of  course,  and  given  that  
everyone  faces  uncertainty  continuously  in  the  real  world,  everyone  synthesizes  -­‐  including  the  
dullest  of  managers.      In  this  event  Zaleznik’s  distinction  cannot  bear  the  weight  and  leadership  
turns  on  how  one  person’s  synthesizing  relieves  others  of  having  to  do  it  for  themselves.    So  
defined,  leadership  turns  not  on  a  solitary  person’s  imaginative  capabilities,  but  on  the  interactions  
between  people  -­‐  leaders  and  led.    This  di-­‐pole  approach  to  leadership  goes  back  to  the  Greeks  and  
beyond,  but  pre-­‐WW2  concerns  about  leadership  in  business  are  equally  obvious  in  the  work  of  
Barnard  and  Follett.    Indeed  a  glance  at  a  typical  19th  century  management  text  like  Freedley  
(Freedley,  1879)  or  an  early  20th  century  text  like  Jones  (Jones,  1914),  shows  the  approach  to  
leadership  as  a  matter  of  personal  character  and  influence  over  others  that  evokes  the  notions  of  
social  duty  and  moral  rectitude  in  Khurana's  first  phase.    It  also  recalls  the  struggle  between  
leadership  as  the  natural  gift  of  the  elite  and  the  development  of  quantitative  methods  to  control  
the  non-­‐elite  mentioned  in  Porter's  analysis  (T.  M.  Porter,  1995).      In  general  I  see  leadership  
research  as  (a)  stymied  by  the  lack  of  a  theory  of  the  ‘led  firm’  or  even  the  leader-­‐led  di-­‐pole,  and  
(b)  caught  between  its  traitist  heritage  and  the  need  to  develop  a  contextually-­‐contingent  approach  
to  human  agency  (Avolio,  et  al.,  2009;  Hunt,  1999;  Spender,  2008a).  
 
During  the  same  period  there  has  been  a  comparable  turn  to  ‘entrepreneurship’  that  is  perhaps  
little  more  that  'leadership'  translated  from  psychological  and  political  discourse  and  into  economic  
language  (Acs  &  Audretsch,  2003;  Sexton  &  Landström,  2000).    Once  more  HBS  was  leading  our  
industry's  curriculum  change  (Keller  &  Keller,  2001:445).    The  study  of  entrepreneurship  goes  back  
as  far  as  that  in  leadership,  though  modern  treatments  begin  with  Defoe  and  Cantillon  and  lead  on  
to  Schumpeter  and  Kirzner.    The  emphasis  is  less  on  the  leader  or  entrepreneur's  personal  
characteristics  than  on  the  economic  context  and  on  how  the  human  qualities  of  imagination  impact  
its  perception.    But  the  turn  to  the  leader  as  the  source  of  economic  order  and  growth  can  also  be  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  45  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

interpreted  as  a  response  to  the  lack  of  a  theory  of  the  managed  firm  I  note  throughout.    Instead  of  
looking  to  the  firm,  as  something  comprehended,  the  analyst's  attention  is  shifted  to  the  
individual/s  who  bring  the  firm  (whatever  that  is)  into  existence  and  direct  it.    Likewise  strategy  
theory  is  a  search  for  the  firm’s  individualistic  or  competitively  differentiating  aspects  in  a  different  
language  or  conceptual  context.    But  the  shift  from  the  firm  as  both  an  entity  and  the  focus  of  
theoretical  attention  and  towards  the  individuals  and  judgments  that  articulate  it  brings  the  
relationship  between  those  leading  and  those  led,  leaders  and  managers  perhaps,  or  managers  and  
the  managed,  or  strategists  and  implementers,  back  into  the  analysis.    Many  BSchools  have  courses  
on  organizational  communication,  just  like  those  in  the  pre-­‐WW2  syllabus,  though  these  tend  to  be  
less  about  composition  and  the  construction  of  messages  than  about  IT  and  moving  data  and  
messages  around.    The  field  has  obviously  been  transformed  by  IT  and  mastering  the  firm's  use  of  
IT  is  clearly  hugely  important  (Ghadar,  1998).    But  the  positivist  disposition  to  presume  all  human  
knowledge  is  theory  and  explicit  diverts  attention  away  from  the  forms  of  human  knowing  that  are  
less  articulable  and  thus  beyond  being  communicated  by  IT  systems.      
 
New  studies  in  ‘knowledge  management’,  largely  propelled  by  Polanyi's  distinction  between  
explicit  and  tacit  knowledge,  have  helped  clarify  the  distinctions  between  the  various  types  of  
knowledge  real  organizations  generate  and  apply  (Choo  &  Bontis,  2002;  Spender,  2008b).    There  
are  many  distinctions  other  than  Polanyi's  and  each  opens  up  a  different  set  of  questions  about  how  
organizations  and  their  communications  might  work.    Mine  spins  around  on  the  differences  
between  data,  meaning  and  skilled  practice  and  suggests  each  needs  to  be  managed  differently,  
thereby  changing  the  problematics  of  organizational  communication  (Spender,  2007a).    While  IT  
moves  data  around  wonderfully,  it  is  of  little  use  when  it  comes  to  moving  meaning  or  best  practice.    
These  other  types  of  human  knowing,  less  familiar  today  than  they  were  in  the  18th  and  19th  century  
before  the  rise  of  positivist  science  and  quantification,  imply  different  kinds  of  communication  
practices.    Chief  among  these  is  the  ancient  art  of  rhetoric  or  persuasion,  the  heuristic-­‐based  
language  practices  that  remain  crucial  to  legal  and  political  professionals.    Rhetoric  was  a  principal  
component  of  the  trivium  and  quadrivium,  the  medieval  education  for  those  aspiring  to  power  in  the  
State  or  the  Church.    Today's  public  speaking  courses  translate  ancient  rhetoric  into  modern  dress  
and  remind  us  that  management  is  not  just  a  matter  of  deciding  but  is  also  a  matter  of  persuading  
others  to  follow  one's  bidding  under  the  conditions  in  which  explicit  incentives  do  not  apply  or  
cannot  be  formulated  (Cheney,  1991;  Denning,  2007;  Leith,  2011;  O'Keefe,  2002).  
 

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  46  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

To  close  this  selection  of  BSchools  challenges  it  is  clear  our  central  lack  is  of  either  a  core  theory  
or  even  an  established  and  ordered  body  of  managerial  heuristics.    It  is  revealing  to  see  that  
Simon's  PhD  thesis,  what  eventually  matured  into  Administrative  Behavior  (Simon,  1947),  began  by  
listing,  and  demolishing,  the  management  heuristics  accepted  at  the  time,  now  generally  known  as  
'classical'  organization  theory’s  principles  or  ‘proverbs’  (Shafritz  &  Ott,  2001).    In  this  sense,  Simon  
threw  organization  theory  and  its  associated  notions  of  managing  into  a  crisis  from  it  has  yet  to  
recover.    Today,  without  a  touchstone,  or  even  a  level  of  practical  agreement,  BSchool  personnel  
have  no  way  of  balancing  the  quantitative  and  non-­‐quantitative  content  of  the  many  different  
materials  that  seem  useful  to  prospective  or  practicing  managers.    It  is  surprising  that  the  active  
pursuit  of  a  core  theory  of  the  firm  has  passed  from  those  most  obviously  dedicated  to  it  -­‐  
organization  theorists  -­‐  to  others  such  as  psychologists,  political  theorists,  cultural  theorists,  even  
biologists,  but  most  importantly  to  a  group  of  micro  economists  prompted  by  Coase.    Transactions  
cost  theory,  principal-­‐agent  theory,  property  rights  theory  and  so  on  are  attempts  to  enter  the  
'black  box'  of  neoclassical  economics  or,  more  precisely,  to  develop  some  sense  of  a  firm's  internal  
structure  and  process  when  some  of  the  axiomatic  prescriptions  of  neoclassical  theory  are  not  met  
(Foss  &  Klein,  2005;  Williamson  &  Winter,  1991).    The  clearest  shortcoming  being  Simon’s  
'bounded  rationality'.    Transaction  costs  theory  grows  out  of  knowledge  asymmetries  between  
markets  and  managers,  principal-­‐agent  theory  out  of  asymmetries  between  principals  (owners,  
perhaps,  or  managers)  and  agents  (managers,  perhaps,  or  employees)  (Spender,  2011a).      
 
In  general  the  micro  economists  presume  firms  are  and  can  do  whatever  markets  cannot  and  
given  they  feel  confident  about  their  understanding  of  markets,  they  can  give  us  some  indication  of  
what  managers  do.    While  micro  economists  have  been  making  these  developments  organization  
theorists  have  done  little  to  move  beyond  the  theory  of  bureaucracy  and  its  dysfunctions  
(Donaldson,  1985).    Yet  the  BSchools'  unmet  need  for  a  core  theory  is  so  considerable  that  many  
different  arguments  have  been  developed,  some  bringing  in  evolutionary  approaches  that  deny  the  
relevance  of  mangers  altogether,  in  ways  not  considered  by  Khurana  as  part  of  'delegitimating'  
them,  such  as  population  ecology  (Hannan  &  Freeman,  1977),  organizational  routines  (Nelson  &  
Winter,  1982),  or  the  firm  as  an  autopoietic  organic  entity  (Beer,  1972;  Maturana  &  Varela,  1980).    
The  most  evident  response  in  BSchools  today  is  to  duck  the  'what  is  the  firm?'  question,  to  simply  
pile  in  courses  that  seem  to  make  sense  intuitively,  and  to  hope  that  the  students  are  able  to  both  
integrate  across  them  into  some  kind  of  coherent  message  and  apply  them  to  everyday  managerial  
practice.    This  is  scarcely  justifiable.    Without  doubt  quantitative  studies  deserve  a  major  place  in  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  47  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

the  curriculum,  perhaps  one  more  extensive  than  we  see.    But  the  students  deserve  some  ways  of  
knowing  how  to  make  use  of  them  and  this  must  be  double-­‐edged.    They  should  be  taught  the  best  
quantitative  techniques  available,  but  also  be  taught  their  limitations,  where  they  have  no  place.      
 
 
Concluding  Comments  
 
Our  historians  have  put  us  in  a  much  better  position  to  understand  the  BSchools'  absorption  of  
quantitative  methods  and,  thereby,  to  look  at  our  present  situation  and  future  through  that  lens.    
Certainly  these  methods’  uptake  was  part  of  the  modernist  cultural  shift  that  eventually  led  to  the  
development  of  casino  capitalism  and  completely  changed  relationships  between  business,  banking  
and  the  citizenry.    Their  development  was  obviously  useful  to  business;  it  led  to  better  control,  
better  market  intelligence,  better  absorption  of  scientific  and  technological  knowledge,  better  
understanding  of  the  differences  between  people  and  cultures,  and  so  on.      
 
Our  history  showed  two  major  concerns  about  the  BSchools’  part  in  this.    First,  without  a  
grounding  theory  of  the  private-­‐sector  managed  firm  in  which  there  was  a  defined  role  for  
managing,  or  even  a  robust  set  of  heuristics  that  could  stand  in  for  this  theory,  neither  professors  
nor  students  could  determine  how  quantitative  methods  should  or  could  be  integrated  into  a  
curriculum  that  had  irreducibly  non-­‐quantitative  components.    Presently  the  AACSB's  MBA  
specifications  include  15  credits  of  'foundation  courses',  all  but  4.5  quantitative,  24  credits  of  'core  
courses',  the  majority  of  which  are  quantitative,  a  further  24  credits  of  'communication'  courses,  
which  includes  the  course  on  'research  methods',  9  credits  of  'management'  which  includes  HRM  
and  strategic  management,  and  a  final  3  credit  capstone  on  'global  business'.      The  tilt  towards  
quantitative  course  is  similarly  evident  in  Navarro's  survey  of  the  top-­‐ranked  US  schools'  curricula  
(Navarro,  2008:112).    Recall  that  at  the  beginning  of  the  post-­‐WW2  curriculum  reform  period  the  
AACSB  still  considered  corporate  strategy  the  MBA  capstone  course,  the  dominant  demarcating  
managerial  topic  that  was  not  yet  subsumed  under  quantitative  methods.    The  strategy  textbooks  of  
the  day  were  grounded  in  the  external/internal  assessment  or  SWOT  model  (Thompson  &  
Strickland,  1987)  or  in  HBS's  strategic  matrix  (Learned,  Christensen,  &  Andrews,  1961).    In  the  
1990s,  echoing  the  wider  transformations  to  the  quant-­‐driven  conglomerates  and  the  evolving  
instruments  of  investor  capitalism,  micro  economists  transformed  strategy  into  a  field  dominated  
by  statistical  analysis  and  modeling  (Rumelt,  Schendel,  &  Teece,  1994).      

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  48  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

 
The  lack  of  a  touchstone  meant  Deans  had  to  manage  the  inter-­‐disciplinary  tensions  implicit  in  
the  MBA  as  a  generalist  program  through  personal  intuition,  charisma  and  political  skill  rather  than  
through  reasoned  debate  at  the  level  of  the  particular  disciplines  clamoring  for  curriculum  space  -­‐  
in  short,  undemocratically.    There  would  be  less  of  a  lack  when  it  came  to  specialist  master's  
programs  that  stressed  a  particular  industry,  discipline  or  technique  and  could  be  shaped  according  
to  what  was  happening  in  the  discipline.    A  rapid  proliferation  of  'specialist'  or  'industry  specific'  
MBAs  followed  that  were  both  difficult  to  distinguish  from  MSc  programs  and  to  justify  as  
preparation  for  management  practice.    The  indications  are  that  these  degrees  are  increasingly  
popular  at  schools  below  the  top  tier  and  so  serve  a  very  different  segment  of  the  market.    At  the  
same  time  the  wider  cultural  turn  to  numbers,  the  explosion  of  IT  assets,  and  the  resulting  
imperative  to  quantify  all  research,  enhanced  by  the  rising  politics  of  rational  choice  liberalism,  
over-­‐prioritized  quantitative  methods  and  unbalanced  the  BSchools.    These  developments  further  
complicated  the  BSchools'  relationships  with  the  rest  of  the  university  and  their  concept  of  
research.  
 
A  second  concern  was  that  the  lack  of  an  anchor  left  the  schools  responding  haphazardly  to  the  
market  forces  pulling  them  this  way  and  that  (D.  Wilson  &  McKiernan,  2011).    We  are  still  unsure  
what  business  wants  from  higher  education,  beyond  'critical  thinking'  and  'problem  solving  skills'  
(Bowers  &  Metcalf,  2008;  Doria,  Rozanski,  &  Cohen,  2003;  Oblinger  &  Verville,  1998).    The  result  is  
inordinate  attention  to  what  can  be  measured,  the  rankings,  and  the  goal-­‐displacement  that  follows  
(Policano,  2001,  2005).    The  role  of  Dean  changed  from  leadership  of  an  educational  product  and  of  
the  schools'  intellectual  processes  and  culture  into  one  of  rankings-­‐boosting  public  relations  
management  and  fund-­‐raising.    The  likelihood  of  major  transformative  intellectual  leadership,  like  
that  of  Hutchins  at  the  University  of  Chicago,  Donham  at  HBS  or  Bain  at  LBS,  was  displaced  by  
institution  and  revenue  building  like  that  achieved,  superbly,  by  Jacobs  at  Northwestern.  
 
In  spite  of  these  concerns  our  industry  prospers  mightily  delivering  'the  world's  most  popular  
degree'  (Fernandes,  2005)  to  what  seems  like  an  ever-­‐expanding  market.    But  if  we  are  to  learn  
anything  from  the  last  few  years,  it  is  that  there  are  no  ever-­‐expanding  markets.    Clearly  we  cannot  
see  what  lies  around  the  corners  on  the  trail  to  our  future,  but  it  might  be  important  for  us  to  filter  
off  some  of  our  ever-­‐more-­‐healthy  revenues  into  researching  the  same  questions  that  were  current  
at  the  time  the  modern  business  school  began  -­‐  and  thereby  prepare  to  reinvent  our  industry  in  the  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  49  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

different  destabilizing  strategic  situation  that  will  surely  arise  with  a  bang.    Khurana  framed  our  
historical  situation  as  a  'professionalization  project',  suggesting  the  overall  task  was  to  help  
transform  management  into  a  profession  (Khurana  &  Nohria,  2008).    But  first  we  need  an  approved  
body  of  knowledge  of  the  type  evident,  even  in  medieval  times,  in  medicine,  law,  architecture,  
engineering,  accounting,  etc.    Business  schools  still  have  no  such  a  body  of  knowledge.    Without  it,  
quite  apart  from  the  question  of  making  management  a  profession,  there  remains  the  question  of  
what  we  think  we  are  doing  -­‐  beyond  helping  democratic  capitalism  function.  
 
The  historian’s  tale  in  this  essay  offers  insights  into  where  we  might  probe  for  this  theory.    In  
particular  it  raises  questions  about  why  we  are  so  smugly  comfortable  with  the  traditional  
discipline-­‐oriented  syllabus,  in  spite  of  our  concerns  about  ‘relevance’.    Khurana  has  shown  us  that  
a  historical  analysis  offers  an  exciting  alternative  that  may  well  suit  practitioner-­‐oriented  students  
much  better.    First,  we  see  that  each  phase  implies  a  different  theory  of  the  managed  firm,  so  we  are  
not  looking  for  a  single  totalizing  answer;  rather,  in  true  post-­‐modernist  style,  for  manageable  
pluralism.    The  search  for  a  totalizing  theory  is  clearly  a  strategic  error,  for  life  is  not  lived  this  way.    
So  almost  all  the  social  sciences  have  taken  this  on  board.    Given  methodological  pluralism,  Simon’s  
1967  discussion  is  re-­‐framed  as  especially  relevant  because  he  took  pluralism  to  a  necessary  
precondition  to  any  effective  management  education  program.    The  schools’  task  is  then  (a)  to  
introduce  the  student  to  a  plurality  of  theories  and  heuristics  that  might  illuminate  the  practical  
situation,  and  (b)  encourage  the  personal  capacity  for  entrepreneurial  synthesis  that  leads  to  
reasoned  action.    To  which  I  would  add  (c)  develop  an  understanding  of  leadership  and,  in  
particular,  the  rhetorical  practices  that  produce  agentic  collaboration  in  the  under-­‐determined  
situations  of  private  sector  business,  those  that  cannot  be  completely  planned.    Leadership  of  the  
delicate  synthesis  of  planned  and  unplanned  activity  is  central  to  management  practice.  
 
But  the  story  also  suggests  the  move  towards  casino  capitalism  is  irreversible,  here  to  stay,  an  
aspect  of  the  tilt  from  the  intensely  person-­‐centered  firm  of  Khurana’s  first  phase  to  the  
increasingly  quantified  and  impersonal  financially-­‐defined  management  now  common.    It  has  
likewise  changed  the  BSchool  agenda  forever.    The  current  calls  for  ‘servant  leadership’,  
‘stakeholder’,  ‘sustainable’,  or  ‘ethical  management’  are  often  naked  nostalgia  for  an  imagined  past  
world  when  owners,  management  and  employees  cohabited  the  socio-­‐economy  peacefully  and  
productively.    As  Veblen  pointed  out,  and  a  cursory  examination  of  the  18th  and  19th  century  
economic  history  reveals,  this  world  never  existed.    The  five-­‐tier  approach  in  this  essay  may  be  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  50  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

useful.    First,  theorizing  managing  as  a  social  duty,  the  idea  that  motivated  Bok,  Khurana  and  many  
others.    Clearly  the  disciplinary  and  institutional  separation  of  BSchools  and  the  schools  of  public  
administration  has  made  re-­‐examining  this  phase  this  more  difficult.    Yet  BSchool  students  need  to  
know  the  public  sector  exists  and  be  able  to  consider  its  organization,  processes  and  contributions  
critically  within  the  political  context  of  the  day.    Firms  need  to  be  situated.    Next  comes  managerial  
capitalism,  theorizing  managing  as  designing  and  operating  firms  in  the  Taylorist  manner,  the  
pursuit  of  efficiency  and  value  creation.    Third,  deploying  and  managing  conglomerates  and  M&A  
activities,  putting  managers  in  the  position  to  trade  firms  and  their  assets  and  so  move  resources  to  
their  highest  value.    Fourth,  theorize  managing  as  shareholder  capitalism,  no  longer  anchored  to  the  
concept  of  the  firm  that  becomes  dispensable  when  the  deal  makes  financial  sense.    Finally,  fifth,  
managing  in  the  context  of  casino  capitalism,  where  everything  in  the  preceding  phases  is  ‘in  play’  
to  those  with  the  necessary  capital,  skills  and  interest  to  take  part.    Casino  capitalism,  perhaps  more  
regulated  and  with  less  of  a  Wild-­‐West  frontier  feel,  will  remain  so  as  long  as  the  current  capitalist  
legislation  that  allows  it  remains  in  place.    Nothing  very  complicated  about  this.    But  each  phase  
implies  a  different,  even  incommensurate,  theory  of  the  firm  or  body  of  heuristics.    BSchools  must  
teach  all,  plus  their  synthesis  towards  purposive  action,  and  so  equip  the  modern  student  to  deal  
with  what  is  ‘out  there’  today.    A  curriculum  that  fails  to  cover  all  phases  fails.      Holding  such  a  
BSchool  together  calls  for  Deans  with  the  prodigious  skills  Simon  identified  half  a  century  ago  -­‐  in  a  
time  considerably  less  complicated  than  today.      
 
The  nature  of  the  firm  in  the  first  four  phases  is  relatively  easy  to  discern.    Each  provides  the  
beginnings  of  a  basis  for  a  curriculum.    The  first  period  firm  is  the  Victorian  combination  of  profit  
seeking  and  social  service.  There  are  certainly  good  reasons  to  strengthen  students’  understanding  
of  the  interplay  of  the  public  and  private  sectors  and  its  management,  and  to  put  forward  a  view  of  
the  firm  as  an  element  in  a  complex  and  heterogeneous  social  network.    The  second  period  firm  is  a  
socially-­‐oriented  instrument  or  ‘engine’  of  the  economy  (Mokyr,  1990;  Nelson,  1990).    In  the  second  
and  third  phases  we  find  the  conventional  firm-­‐centered  aesthetic,  the  idea  the  firm  is  an  isolated  
entity,  confronting  markets  and  competitors  while  trying  to  maximize  under  management’s  control  
-­‐  perhaps  maximize  profit  or  market  share,  perhaps  longevity,  perhaps  some  other  social  ‘objective  
function’  -­‐  but  modeled  as  an  independent  and  controllable  input-­‐output  system.    The  theory  places  
management  at  the  firm’s  center.    The  human  relations  approaches  balance  out  the  more  objective  
finance  and  system  modeling  approaches  -­‐  a  balance  operationalized  in  the  Balanced  Scorecard  as  it  
stresses  the  pluralism  and  multidimensionality  of  the  management-­‐centered  model.    Suspicions  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  51  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

that  management  is  less  central  to  what  happens,  perhaps  even  irrelevant,  have  been  around  for  a  
long  time,  in  the  population  ecology  movement,  of  course,  but  also  in  the  puzzling  work  on  firm  size  
by  Ijiri  and  Simon  (Ijiri  &  Simon,  1977)  and  other  work  on  Zipf-­‐  and  power-­‐laws.    Unlike  the  second  
and  third  phases  that  are  firm-­‐centered,  the  fourth  phase  firm’s  center  is  the  free-­‐floating  investor,  
maybe  restricted  to  ‘sophisticated  investors’  and  their  financial  vehicles,  but  an  entity  for  whom  
shareholder  capitalism  describes  the  entire  world.    Here  the  firm’s  managers,  unavoidable  
hangovers  from  the  earlier  phases  that  presume  real  resources  are  being  transformed  into  real  
profit  in  real  markets,  are  now  reframed  as  ‘the  problem’.  
 
The  management  theory  implications  of  the  fifth  ‘casino  capitalist’  phase  are  relatively  under-­‐
explored  (Sennett,  2006).    The  first  phase  sees  the  firm  as  a  source  of  social  goods  and  services  
including,  of  course,  jobs,  taxes  and  personal  identity.    Political  and  social  reasoning  dominates.    
The  second  phase  sees  the  firm  as  a  production  function,  the  rational  engine  of  profit  and  economic  
growth.    The  third  and  fourth  phases  shift  the  focus  from  the  individual  firm  and  its  survival  to  the  
maximization  and  survival  of  (a)  an  economic  aggregate  such  as  a  conglomerate  versus  (b)  an  
investment  portfolio,  both  phases  accepting  individual  firms  can  be  traded  or  broken  up  as  their  
resources  are  reallocated  in  ‘industrial  restructuring’  moves.    Rationality  and  quantitative  methods  
dominate  the  second,  third  and  forth  phases.    In  the  fifth  phase  the  concept  of  the  firm  is  altogether  
different,  even  when  framed  within  a  portfolio  of  business  opportunities.    The  firm’s  principal  
function  is  now  to  carry  debt  long  enough  for  ‘trades  of  debt’  to  be  closed.    The  profit  comes  from  
selling  debt,  or  acquiring  and  selling  debt-­‐bearing  vehicles,  and  thereby  ‘monetizing’  debt  
differences.    Risk  management  is  central  because  of  the  need  to  evaluate  the  ‘downside’  should  the  
trade  not  close  -­‐  but  the  deal  is  about  managing  debt  not  resources.      
 
Firms  are  thus  defined  and  evaluated  in  terms  of  the  debt  they  can  carry  and  the  deal’s  profit  
possibilities  lie  in  the  arbitrage  opportunities  created  when  potential  owners  differ  in  their  
perceptions  of  the  firm  as  a  debt-­‐carrying  vehicle.    The  firm’s  owners  P  define  the  firm  X  by  its  
capacity  to  carry  debt  DP  while  another  potential  owner  Q,  such  as  a  hedge  fund,  thinks  it  can  carry  
debt  DQ.    The  arbitrage  opportunity  is  (DQ  -­‐  DP),  monetized  by  selling  X  to  Q.    Of  course  Q  only  buys  
X  because  they  believe  it  can  be  sold  on  to  another  owner  R.    The  risk  of  buying  X  can  be  ‘hedged’  at  
cost  H  so  the  yield  is  reduced  to  (DQ  -­‐  DP)  -­‐  H.    At  the  same  time,  in  the  period  while  X  is  held,  it  
might  generate  earnings  of  E,  raising  the  deal’s  yield  to  [(DQ  -­‐  DP)  +  (E-­‐H)].    In  practice,  
restructuring  of  various  types  often  extends  both  the  earnings  and  the  arbitrage  opportunities.    In  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  52  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

current  conditions  we  see  many  firms  driven  into  extinction  as  they  are  passed  from  hand  to  hand,  
like  a  mountain  mule  being  sold  by  one  arriero  to  another  who  then  piles  his  own  possessions  atop  
the  mule’s  previous  load.    Eventually  the  mule  stumbles  to  its  knees  and,  pack  and  all,  falls  into  the  
ravine  where  it  is  fodder  for  corpse-­‐robbers  and  vultures.    This  may  not  work  too  well,  but  some  
theory  of  the  fifth  phase  firm  and  of  its  management  is  vital  if  we  are  to  help  students  understand  
this  aspect  of  contemporary  business  reality,  in  part  because  so  many  are  oriented  towards  it.      
There  is  also  the  intellectual  challenge.  
 
The  institutions,  politics  and  sociology  of  debt  in  the  private  sector  are  very  different  from  those  
of  resources  or  capital  (Dienst,  2011).    The  urge  to  measure  the  firm’s  capital  better,  given  the  gap  
between  market  and  book  values  revealed  by  Tobin’s  q,  has  led  accountants  to  extend  the  notion  of  
capital  to  embrace  tacit  knowledge  and  ‘human  capital’  (Burton-­‐Jones  &  Spender,  2011a,  2011b).    
The  public  sector  gives  private  sector  firms  legal  rights  to  acquire,  trade  and  ‘own’  all  manner  of  
capitals,  justified  by  the  spillovers  and  economy-­‐wide  benefits  flowing  back  into  the  public  sector.    
Today’s  institutional  and  legal  arrangements  give  the  entrepreneur  and  the  shareholders  rights  to  
pursue  profit.    Given  an  efficient  market  for  all  the  various  capitals  needed  to  bring  the  
entrepreneur’s  plans  to  fruition,  the  limits  to  the  growth  of  capital  are  those  of  the  entrepreneur’s  
capacity  for  hard  work  and  imagination.    Given  also  a  reasonably  functional  political  system  
governing  the  distribution  of  benefits,  the  more  the  entrepreneur’s  enterprise  is  tested  the  better  
the  public  results.    But  it  is  rather  different  when  it  comes  to  debt,  as  both  the  US  and  Europe  have  
been  recently  been  reminded.    The  limit  to  debt  lies  in  finding  the  last  fool  prepared  to  pay  out  
capital  to  acquire  a  debt  in  the  hope  that  it  offers  an  arbitrage  gain,  and  this  lies  in  the  imagination.    
The  debt  in  the  housing  market  ended  up  in  the  laps  of  the  house-­‐owners,  who  imagined  being  able  
to  pay,  as  well  as  in  those  who  imagined  profit  but  were  left  holding  the  bag  of  worthless  
derivatives  and  other  financial  products  when  the  music  stopped.    There  are  no  physical,  legal  or  
institutional  limits  to  debt,  so  the  private  sector  has  an  in-­‐built  irresistible  incentive  to  expand  debt  
to  and  beyond  its  socially  useful  limits,  so  gaining  short-­‐term  trading  profits  and  pushing  the  
extinction  of  the  debt  into  the  future.    Managing  capital  is  about  the  difficulties  of  quantifying  
resources  that  can  be  applied  profitably  to  increase  resources;  its  focus  in  on  the  world  of  
experience.    Managing  debt  lies  in  the  world  of  the  imagination  and,  as  we  know,  is  ever  at  risk  to  a  
confrontation  with  experience.  
 

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  53  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

So,  once  again  to  the  question  in  my  essay’s  title  -­‐  the  quants  changed  our  world.    What  can  we  
do  about  it?    BSchools  followed  along  as  the  world  changed  but  for  the  most  part  passively  without  
bothering  or  being  able  to  theorize  how  those  changes  transformed  the  private  sector  firms  that  
remained  the  integral  elements  of  the  economy,  its  micro  foundation.    So  long  as  the  firm  retains  
this  central  place  in  our  lives,  so  must  management  -­‐  and  perhaps  things  are  not  as  dire  as  I  have  
suggested  with  my  persistent  remarks  that  we  have  no  theory  or  body  of  heuristics  to  act  as  our  
touchstone  and  stabilize  our  curriculum  and  debate.    If  we  abandon  the  search  for  a  single  totalizing  
theory  of  the  firm  as  a  relic  of  a  Comtean  positivist  ideology  that  every  other  social  science  has  long  
left  behind,  and  embrace  the  notion  of  pluralism,  our  discipline’s  historians  have  shown  us  the  
content  of  the  curriculum  -­‐  maybe  not  my  five  phases  but  something  like  them.    We  need  to  give  
students  insight  into  the  many  faces  of  the  private  sector  firm,  just  as  in  the  elephant  and  blind  men  
story  -­‐  again.    But  the  hard  part  is  the  same  as  what  confronts  historians,  to  find  implications  and  
connections  that  give  us  some  grip  on  the  present  and  its  options.    How  might  we  do  this?  
 
Which  gets  us  to  methodology.    Perhaps  the  quants’  greatest  gift  to  management  educators  -­‐  as  
opposed  to  their  many  gifts  to  real  managers  -­‐  is  to  remind  us  that  fetishizing  any  methodology,  
such  as  quantification,  leads  academics  to  abandon  their  defining  position  to  generate  knowledge  
by  exercising  the  critical  method.    The  university  is  distinct  from  everyday  life  precisely  because  it  
adopts  this  critical  methodology  in  the  pursuit  of  knowledge  rather  than  the  simpler  pragmatism  of  
acting  in  the  pursuit  of  real-­‐world  goals.    We  often  attribute  the  invention  of  the  critical  method  to  
Bacon.    But  he  was  passing  on  the  gifts  of  Islamic  science,  which  was  earlier  able  to  escape  the  
clutches  of  dogmatic  interpretations  of  the  Greek  and  Roman  literature,  especially  of  Aristotle,  by  
institutionalizing  criticism,  especially  that  based  on  empirical  evidence  (Saliba,  2007).    The  sheer  
power  -­‐  analytic  and  rhetorical  -­‐  of  quantitative  methods  now  overshadows  the  other  
methodologies  necessary  to  the  growth  of  human  knowledge.    This  is  partly  because  we  have  let  
wither  the  theory  and  practice  of  criticism  -­‐  our  defining  professional  characteristic.    Yet  we  know  
that  no  method  can  survive  alone;  every  method  works  by  rejecting  some  aspects  of  the  
phenomena  being  considered.    This  rejection  alone  allows  movement  from  the  particularities  of  
experience  to  the  generalities  of  language.    A  fruitful  interplay  of  methodologies  is  crucial  to  
appreciating  what  we  do  and  do  not  know  and  to  expanding  human  knowledge.    Simon,  whose  
grasp  of  these  matters  was  exceptionally  sound,  summed  this  up  pithily,  noting:  “Reason,  then,  goes  
to  work  only  after  it  has  been  supplied  with  a  set  of  suitable  inputs  or  premises”  (Simon,  1983:7).    
Where  are  these  to  come  from,  and  by  using  what  method?    Popper  struggled  equally  with  where  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  54  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

hypotheses  were  to  come  from  (Popper,  1968,  1969).    We  see  the  BSchool  curriculum  is  either  
vocational  training  in  some  goal-­‐directed  practice,  such  as  portfolio  analysis  or  supply-­‐chain  design,  
or  an  academic  activity  that  provides  students  with  the  capacity  to  critique  those  practices  and  
thereby  seek  their  improvement.    Within  a  business  school  the  faculty  are  in  the  same  position,  the  
curriculum  displaying  our  goal-­‐directed  practice.      We  need  to  exercise  our  critical  capabilities  as  
much  as  we  might  try  to  awaken  and  exercise  them  in  our  students.  
 
The  MBA  curriculum  would  then  be  a  dynamic  knowledge-­‐generating  apparatus  of  some  
complexity,  threatening  to  overwhelm  those  with  little  tolerance  for  pluralism  and  inter-­‐
disciplinarity,  calling  for  time  and  cost  efficient  analysis  (satisficing)  and  the  imaginative  
capabilities  to  synthesize  the  results  into  a  communicable  message  -­‐  followed  by  an  appropriate  
study  of  the  nature  and  practice  of  rhetoric  that  will  enable  the  students  to  comprehend  leadership  
in  the  context  of  the  private  sector  firm.    This  is  not  the  same  as  being  in  a  military  situation,  or  
even  in  the  public  eye.    The  theory  of  leadership  turns  out  to  be  contingent  on  the  implicit  theory  of  
the  firm.    The  curriculum’s  outlines  can  be  sketched  as  a  matrix  (Figure  3)  that  opens  up  a  
conceptual  space  in  which  synthesizing  and  choosing  can  take  place  as  a  human  process,  perhaps  
individual,  perhaps  collaborative.    On  one  axis  is  ‘content’  -­‐  the  actual  things,  names,  entities,  
quantities,  relationships,  preferences,  and  so  on  that  crowd  into  the  manager’s  attention.    The  other  
axis  is  ‘method’.      
 
                                     Methodologies  
        quantitative            -­‐  -­‐  -­‐  -­‐  -­‐  -­‐  -­‐  -­‐  -­‐  -­‐  -­‐            non-­‐quantitative  

  social  duty  

  managerial  capitalism  

Content   conglomerates  /  M&A  

shareholder  capitalism  

casino  capitalism  
 
      Figure  3:  Elements  for  a  Comprehensive  Pluralistic  MBA  Curriculum  
 
Within  each  content  area  -­‐  the  consequence  of  paying  attention  to  history  as  a  way  of  
categorizing  the  elements  the  MBA  program  should  cover  -­‐  a  variety  of  research  methods  can  be  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  55  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

brought  into  play.    We  are  in  an  era  where  we  know  that  numbers  are  useful  wherever  they  can  be  
found,  as  the  Kelvin  quote  suggests.    But  the  quantitative  methods  touched  on  in  this  essay  are  both  
dependent  on  and  complementary  to  the  other  methods  we  humans  have  of  thinking  about  our  
situation  in  a  disciplined  manner  -­‐  as  the  Knight  riposte  suggests.    The  current  discussion  of  
‘qualitative  methodologies’  may  not  exhaust  the  possibilities  here  (K.  Locke,  2011;  Rosanas,  2007;  
Thomas  &  Wilson,  2009,  2011;  Van  Maanen,  2011).    My  essay  obviously  gives  historical  methods  
their  due  and  they  are  by  no  means  easily  captured  in  the  ‘qualitative  methods’  discussion  offered  
in  BSchools  today.    So  I  do  no  more  than  wave  vaguely  in  the  direction  of  those  sociological,  
psychological,  anthropological,  historical,  and  so  on  methodologies  that,  for  one  reason  or  another,  
stand  on  grounds  other  than  those  on  which  quantitative  methods  stand.    While  quantitative  
methodologies  take  their  presuppositions  and  axioms  for  granted,  these  are  only  useful  and  tenable  
when  they  are  exposed  to  criticism.    Ultimately  the  distinguishing  mark  of  the  academic  is  to  have  
more  than  one  method,  for  to  have  but  one  only  is  to  be  a  purveyor  of  dogma,  but  with  no  less  than  
two  methodologies  in  hand  criticism  is  possible.    A  handy  definition  of  an  intelligent  person  is  one  
able  to  hold  two  or  more  contrary  ideas  in  mind  at  the  same  time.    Then  the  application  of  multiple  
methods  means  that  conclusions  require  an  act  of  synthesis  -­‐  whether  the  researcher’s  as  s/he  
comes  to  a  conceptual  conclusion,  or  the  manager’s  as  s/he  arrives  at  a  plan  of  action.  
 
Given  my  assertion  that  the  private  sector  firm’s  historical  phases  are  ‘layered’  on  each  other  
and  persist  beyond  the  time  when  they  come  into  place  for  the  first  time,  a  further  cycle  of  
synthesis  of  these  layers  is  necessary  to  grasp  the  operational  nature  of  the  firm.    This  is  not  unlike  
the  synthesis  of  the  physical,  personal  and  social  ‘sub-­‐economies’  Barnard  examined  and  
considered  the  defining  characteristic  of  executive  work  (Barnard,  1938:251;  O'Connor,  2011).    At  
the  same  time  there  are  persistent  dynamic  tensions  between  the  activities  of  each  phase.    One  such  
is  the  pressure  on  managements  to  grow  the  firm,  the  pressure  coming  from  shareholders  anxious  
to  see  their  stock  rise.    Another  is  the  strategic  question  facing  entrepreneurs;  are  they  building  a  
firm  for  the  ‘long  term’  or  to  treat  the  early  stages  of  the  firm  as  ‘proof  of  concept’  and  cash  out  to  
Google  or  Pfizer?    Are  managers  growing  the  firm  to  ensure  its  survival  or  to  make  it  easier  to  put  it  
‘in  play’?  
 
My  essay  began  by  examining  the  nature  and  history  of  the  quants’  impact.    It  helps  illustrate  
how  the  BSchools  and  their  curriculum  have  responded  to  the  changing  nature  of  private  sector  
business  over  the  last  century.    On  the  whole  the  BSchools’  responses  have  been  passive.    In  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  56  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

particular  this  has  allowed  the  components  of  the  curriculum  to  drift  apart  into  the  well-­‐guarded  
silos  institutionalized  into  the  distinct  disciplines  that  characterize  our  profession  of  management  
education.    But  it  allowed  the  most  crucial  of  management’s  contributions  -­‐  action-­‐oriented  
syntheses  of  available  knowledge  -­‐  to  fall  out  of  sight.    This  has  to  be  seen  as  a  crucial  failing  on  our  
part,  equivalent  to  graduating  surgeons  who  have  never  experienced  cutting  or  lawyers  who  have  
never  argued.    The  work  that  managers  must  do  to  bring  theory,  heuristics  and  intuition  into  
productive  relationship  with  contextualized  action  and  experience  is  now  practically  and  
conceptually  ignored,  in  part  because  we  academics  do  not  have  to  do  it  in  order  to  satisfy  our  
professional  obligations  as  researchers  or  teachers.    We  have  to  learn  how  to  publish.    This  
inconvenient  truth  becomes  evident  as  we  consider  the  impact  of  quantitative  methods.    If  we  then  
move  along  the  trail  Simon  indicated  in  his  1967  paper  and  make  synthesis  the  nub  of  the  MBA  
curriculum  we  can  relocate  it  from  being  contextualized  by  disciplinary  distinctions,  as  we  insist  
today,  and  contextualize  some  other  way.    There  are  many  alternative  framings,  history  is  just  one.    
Each  framing,  of  course,  implies  knowledge  of  the  various  methodologies  that  in  that  framing  are  
the  necessary  complements  to  quantitative  methods.    Those  arguing  business  has  lost  ‘trust’,  and  
that  its  restoration  must  be  the  core  of  curriculum  reform,  put  the  analysis  into  a  sociological  frame.    
Those  who  see  us  submerged  under  ‘big  data’,  see  the  world  in  IT  networked  terms.    Likewise  those  
who  cry  the  end  of  history  or  of  democratic  capitalism  locate  the  debate  in  a  different  frame.    
Ultimately  academic  activity  contributes  to  the  world  of  real  students  and  real  managers  by  giving  
them  the  tools  with  which  to  escape  from  the  absorbing  and  urgent  ‘on-­‐goingness’  of  everyday  to  
open  up  new  possibilities  through  critique.    If  BSchools  fail  here,  they  fail  most  seriously.  
 
 
 

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  57  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

Bibliography  
 
Aaronson,  Susan  A.  (1992).  Serving  America's  Business?  Graduate  Business  Schools  and  American  
Business,  1945-­‐1960.  In  Charles    Harvey    &  Geoffrey  Jones  (Eds.),  Organizational  Capability  and  
Competitive  Advantage  (pp.  160-­‐182).  London:  Frank  Cass  &  Co.  

Abbott,  Andrew  Delano.  (1988).  The  System  of  Professions:  An  Essay  on  the  Division  of  Expert  Labor.  
Chicago  IL:  University  of  Chicago  Press.  

Acs,  Zoltan  J.,  &  Audretsch,  David  B.  (Eds.).  (2003).  Handbook  of  Entrepreneurial  Research:  An  
Interdiscipliary  Survey  and  Introduction.  New  York:  Springer  Science+Business  Media.  

Adler,  Nancy  J.,  &  Harzing,  Anne-­‐Wil.  (2009).  When  Knowledge  Wins:  Transcending  the  Sense  and  
Nonsense  of  Academic  Rankings.  [Article].  Academy  of  Management  Learning  &  Education,  8(1),  
72-­‐95.  

Alvesson,  Mats,  &  Willmott,  Hugh  (Eds.).  (1992).  Critical  Management  Studies.  Newbury  Park  CA:  
Sage  Publications.  

Amadae,  S.  M.  (2003).  Rationalizing  Capitalist  Democracy:  The  Cold  War  Origins  of  Rational  Choice  
Liberalism.  Chicago  IL:  University  of  Chicago  Press.  

Amadae,  S.  M.,  &  de  Mesquita,  Bruce  Bueno.  (1999).  The  Rochester  School:  The  Origins  of  Positive  
Poltical  Theory.  Annual  Review  of  Political  Science,  2,  269-­‐295.  

Ando,  Albert,  Fisher,  Franklin  M.,  &  Simon,  Herbert  A.  (1963).  Essays  on  The  Structure  of  Social  
Science  Models.  Cambridge  MA:  MIT  Press.  

Apling,  Richard  N.  (1993).  Proprietary  Schools  and  Their  Students.  The  Journal  of  Higher  Education,  
64(4,  July-­‐Aug),  379-­‐416.  

Augier,  Mie,  &  March,  James  G.  (2011).  The  Roots,  Rituals,  and  Rhetorics  of  Change.  Stanford  CA:  
Stanford  University  Press.  

Avellaneda,  Marco.  (1999).  Quantitative  Modeling  of  Derivative  Securites:  From  Theory  to  Practice.  
Boca  Raton  FL:  Chapman  &  Hall.  

Avolio,  B.  J.,  Walumbwa,  F.  O.,  &  Weber,  T.  J.  (2009).  Leadership:  Current  Theories,  Research  and  
Future  Directions.  Annual  Review  of  Psychology,  52,  421–449.  

Ayres,  Ian.  (2007).  Super  Crunchers:  Why  Thinking-­‐By-­‐Numbers  Is  the  New  Way  to  Be  Smart.  New  
York:  Bantam  Books.  

Barnard,  Chester  I.  (1938).  The  Functions  of  the  Executive.  Cambridge  MA:  Harvard  University  Press.  

Beer,  Stafford.  (1972).  The  Brain  of  the  Firm.  London:  Allen  Lane.  

Behrman,  Jack  N.  ,  &  Levin,  Richard  I.  (1984).  Are  Business  Schools  Doing  Their  Job?  Harvard  
Business  Review,  Jan  -­‐  Feb,  140-­‐147.  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  58  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

Benninga,  Simon.  (2008).  Financial  Modeling  (3rd  ed.).  Cambridge  MA:  MIT  Press.  

Bennis,  Warren,  &  O'Toole,  James.  (2005).  How  Business  Schools  Lost  Their  Way.  Harvard  Business  
Review,  83(5),  96-­‐104.  

Berg,  Ivar.  (2003).  Education  and  Jobs:  The  Great  Training  Robbery.  Clinton  Corners  NY:  Percheron  
Press.  

Berg,  Norman    (1965).  Strategic  Planning  in  Conglomerate  Companies.  Harvard  Business  Review,  43,  
79-­‐92.  

Berggren,  Christian,  &  Söderlund,  Jonas.  (2011).  Education  for  Practicing  Managers:  Combining  
Academic  Rigor  With  Personal  Change  and  Organizational  Action.  Journal  of  Management  
Education,  35(3),  377-­‐405.  

Bisoux,  Tricia.  (2007).  The  MBA  Reconsidered:  Three  Business  Schools  Make  Radical  Departures  
from  Traditional  MBA  Formats.  BizEd(May/June),  44-­‐48.  

Blackler,  Frank,  &  Regan,  Suzanne.  (2009).  Inentionality,  Agency,  change:  Practice  Theory  and  
Management.  Management  Learning,  40(2),  161-­‐176.  

Bloom,  Alan.  (1987).  The  Closing  of  the  American  Mind.  New  York:  Simon  &  Schuster.  

Bok,  Derek  C.  (1978).  The  President's  Report  1977-­‐1978.  Cambridge  MA:  Harvard  University.  

Bok,  Derek  C.  (2003).  Universities  in  the  Marketplace:  The  Commercialization  of  Higher  Education.  
Princeton  NJ:  Princeton  University  Press.  

Boland,  Lawrence  A.  (1979).  A  Critique  of  Friedman's  Critics.  Journal  of  Economic  Literature,  17(2),  
503-­‐522.  

Booth,  Charles,  &  Rowlinson,  Michael.  (2006).  Management  and  Organizational  History:  Prospects.  
Management  and  Organizational  History,  1(1),  5-­‐30.  

Bossard,  James  H.S.,  &  Dewhurst,  James  F.  (1931).  University  Education  for  Business:  A  Study  of  
Existing  Needs  and  Practices.  Philadelphia  PA:  University  of  Pennsylvania  Press.  

Bouleau,  Nicolas  (2011).  Mathematics  and  Real-­‐World  Knowledge  Real-­‐World  Economics  


Review(57,  Sept),  90-­‐105.  

Bowers,  Mary  Y.,  &  Metcalf,  Marcia  A.  (2008).  What  Employers  Want  and  What  Students  Need:  
Integrating  Business  Communication  into  Undergraduate  and  Graduate  Business  Courses.  Paper  
presented  at  the  Association  for  Business  Communication  Annual  Convention.  

Brown,  Richard,  Mackay,  John  Sturgeon,  Boyd,  Edward,  Fogo,  J.  Row,  Sloan,  Alexander,  &  Patrick,  
Joseph.  (2009).  A  History  of  Accounting  and  Accountants:  General  Books.  

Burton-­‐Jones,  Alan,  &  Spender,  J.-­‐C.  (2011a).  Introduction.  In  Alan  Burton-­‐Jones  &  J.-­‐C.  Spender  
(Eds.),  The  Oxford  handbook  of  Human  Capital  (pp.  1-­‐45).  Oxford:  Oxford  University  Press.  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  59  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

Burton-­‐Jones,  Alan,  &  Spender,  J.-­‐C.  (Eds.).  (2011b).  Oxford  Handbook  of  Human  Capital.  Oxford:  
Oxford  University  Press.  

Cantillon,  Richard.  (2001).  Essay  on  the  Nature  of  Commerce  in  General,  with  a  New  Introduction  by  
Anthony  Brewer  (Henry  Higgs,  Trans.).  New  Brunswick  NJ:  Transaction  Publishers.  

Carroll,  Archie  B.,  &  Shabana,  Kareem  M.  (2010).  The  Business  Case  for  Corporate  Social  
Responsibility:  A  Review  of  Concepts,  Research  and  Practice.  International  Journal  of  
Management  Reviews,  12(1),  85-­‐105.  

Certo,  S.  Trevis,  Sirmon,  David  G.,  &  Brymer,  Rhett  A.  (2010).  Competition  and  Scholarly  
Productivity  in  Management:  Investigating  Changes  in  Scholarship  from  1988  to  2008.  Academy  
of  Management  Learning  &  Education,  9(4),  591-­‐606.  

Chaudhuri,  K.  N.  (1985).  Trade  and  Civilisation  in  the  Indian  Ocean:  An  Economic  History  from  the  
Rise  of  Islam  to  1750.  Cambridge:  Cambridge  University  Press.  

Cheit,  Earl  F.  (1985).  Business  Schools  and  Their  Critics,  California  Management  Review  (Vol.  27,  pp.  
43):  California  Management  Review.  

Cheney,  George.  (1991).  Rhetoric  in  an  Organizational  Soceity:  Managing  Multiple  Identities.  
Columbia  SC:  University  of  South  Carolina  Press.  

Choo,  Chun  Wei,  &  Bontis,  Nick  (Eds.).  (2002).  The  Strategic  Management  of  Intellectual  Capital  and  
Organizational  Knowledge.  New  York:  Oxford  University  Press.  

Clark,  Peter  A.,  &  Rowlinson,  Michael.  (2004).  The  Treatment  of  History  in  Organization  Studies:  
Towards  an  "Historic  Turn"?  Business  History,  46(3),  331-­‐352.  

Clinebell,  Sharon  K.,  &  Clinebell,  John  M.  (2008).  The  Tension  in  Business  Education  Between  
Academic  Rigor  and  Real-­‐World  Relevance:  The  Role  of  Executive  Professors.  Academy  of  
Management  Learning  &  Education,  7(1),  99-­‐107.  

Cohen,  Kenneth  J.,  &  Cyert,  Richard  M.  (1965).  Theory  of  the  Firm:  Resource  Allocation  in  a  Market  
Economy.  Englewood  Cliffs  NJ:  Prentice-­‐Hall.  

Cohen,  Peter.  (1974).  The  Gospel  According  to  the  Harvard  Business  School.  New  York:  Penguin  
Books  Inc.  

Collingwood,  Robin  George.  (1994).  The  Idea  of  History  (Revised  ed.).  Oxford:  Oxford  University  
Press.  

Contardo,  Ianna,  &  Wensley,  Robin.  (2004).  The  Harvard  Business  School  Story:  Avoiding  
Knowledge  by  Being  Relevant.  Organization,  11(2),  211-­‐231.  

Cooper,  Cary  L.  (2011).  Management  Research  in  the  UK:  A  Personal  View.  British  Journal  of  
Management,  22(3),  343-­‐346.  

Copeland,  Melvin  T.  (1958).  And  Mark  an  Era:  The  Story  of  the  Harvard  Business  School.  Boston  MA:  
Little  Brown.  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  60  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

Cornelissen,  Joep,  &  Thorpe,  Richard  E.  (2002).  Measuring  a  Business  School's  Reputation:  
Perspectives,  Problems  and  Prospects.  European  Management  Journal,  20(2),  172-­‐178.  

Cornuel,  Eric.  (2005).  The  Role  of  Business  Schools  in  Society.  Journal  of  Management  Development,  
24(9),  819-­‐829.  

Crainer,  Stuart,  &  Dearlove,  Des.  (1999).  Gravy  Training:  Inside  the  Business  of  Business  Schools.  San  
Francisco  CA:  Jossey-­‐Bass  Publishers.  

Cummings,  Stephen,  &  Bridgman,  Todd.  (2011).  The  Relevant  Past:  Why  the  History  of  Management  
Should  be  Critical  for  Our  Future.  Academy  of  Management  Learning  &  Education,  10(1),  77-­‐93.  

Currie,  Graeme,  Knights,  David,  &  Starkey,  Ken.  (2010).  Introduction:  A  Post-­‐Crisis  Critical  
Reflection  on  Business  Schools.  British  Journal  of  Management,  21(1),  S1-­‐S5.  

Cyert,  Richard  M,  &  March,  James  G.  (1963).  A  Behavioral  Theory  of  the  Firm.  Englewood  Cliffs  NJ:  
Prentice-­‐Hall.  

Dahlsrud,  Alexander.  (2008).  How  Corporate  Social  Responsibility  is  Defined:  An  Analysis  of  37  
Definitions.  Corporate  Social  Responsibility  &  Environmental  Management,  15,  1-­‐13.  

Daniel,  Carter.  (1998).  The  MBA:  The  First  Century.  London:  Routledge.  

Datar,  Srikant  M.,  Garvin,  David  A.,  &  Cullen,  Patrick  G.  (2010).  Rethinking  the  MBA:  Business  
Education  at  a  Crossroads.  Boston  MA:  Harvard  Business  Press.  

DeAngelo,  Harry,  DeAngelo,  Linda,  &  Zimmerman,  Jerold  L.  (2005).  What's  Really  Wrong  with  US  
Business  Schools    http://ssrn.com/abstract=766404.  

Denning,  Stephen.  (2007).  The  Secret  Language  of  Leadership:  How  Leaders  Inspire  Action  Through  
Narrative.  San  Francisco  CA:  John  Wiley  &  Sons.  

Dichev,  Ilia  D.  (1999).  How  Good  Are  Business  School  Rankings?  Journal  of  Business,  72(2),  201-­‐213.  

Dienst,  Richard.  (2011).  The  Bonds  of  Debt.  london:  Verso.  

Dimand,  Robert  W.,  &  Dore,  Mohammed  H.  I.  (2000).  Keynes's  Casino  Capitalism,  Bagehot's  
International  Currency,  and  the  Tobin  Tax:  Historical  Notes  on  Preventing  Currency  Fires.  
Journal  of  Post  Keynesian  Economics,  22(4,  Summer),  515-­‐528.  

Donaldson,  Lex.  (1985).  In  Defence  of  Organization  Theory:  A  Reply  to  the  Critics.  Cambridge:  
Cambridge  University  Press.  

Donham,  Wallace  B.  (1954).  The  Case  Method  in  College  Teaching  of  Social  Science.  In  M.P.  McNair  
&  A.  Hersum  (Eds.),  The  Case  Method  at  the  Harvard  Business  School  (pp.  244-­‐255).  

Doria,  Joyce,  Rozanski,  Horacio,  &  Cohen,  Ed.  (2003).  What  Business  Needs  from  Business  Schools.  
Strategy  +  Business(32),  39-­‐45.  

Drucker,  Peter  F.  (2005).  Peter  Drucker  On  the  Profession  of  Management.  Boston  MA:  Harvard  
Business  School  Publishing.  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  61  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

Duménil,  Gérard,  &  Lévy,  Dominique.  (2011).  The  Crisis  of  Neoliberalism.  Cambridge  MA:  Harvard  
University  Press.  

Durand,  Thomas,  &  Dameron,  Stephanie  (Eds.).  (2008).  The  Future  of  Business  Schools:  Scenarios  
and  Strategies  for  2020.  Basingstoke:  Palgrave  Macmillan.  

Eamon,  William  (1994).  Science  and  the  Secrets  of  Nature:  Books  of  Secrets  in  Medieval  and  Early  
Modern  Culture.  Princeton  NJ:  Princeton  University  Press.  

Engwall,  Lars.  (2004).  The  Americanization  of  Nordic  Management  Education,  Journal  of  
Management  Inquiry  (Vol.  13,  pp.  109-­‐117):  Sage  Publications  Inc.  

Engwall,  Lars.  (2007).  The  Anatomy  of  Management  Education.  [Article].  Scandinavian  Journal  of  
Management,  23(1),  4-­‐35.  

Engwall,  Lars,  &  Danell,  Rikard.  (2011).  Britannia  and  her  Business  Schools.  British  Journal  of  
Management,  223,  432-­‐442.  

Engwall,  Lars,  &  Zamagni,  Vera  (Eds.).  (1998).  Management  Education  in  Historical  Perspective.  
Manchester:  Manchester  University  Press.  

Ewing,  David  W.  .  (1990).  Inside  the  Harvard  Business  School:  Strategies  and  Lessons  of  America's  
Leading  School  of  Business.  New  York:  Times  Books.  

Feldman,  Allan  M.,  &  Serrano,  Roberto.  (2008).  Arrow's  Impossibility  Theorem:  Two  Simple  Single-­‐
Profile  Versions.  Harvard  College  Mathematics  Review,  2(2),  46-­‐57.  

Fernandes,  John.  (2004).  Adapting  to  Market  Place  Demands.  CEO  Strategy(October),  24-­‐26.  

Fernandes,  John.  (2005).  The  World's  Most  Popluar  Degree  -­‐  the  MBA  -­‐  Is  Alive  and  Well.  AACSB  
eNewsline,  4(6),  1-­‐2.  

Ferraro,  Fabrizio,  Pfeffer,  Jeffrey,  &  Sutton,  Robert  I.  (2005).  Economics  Language  and  Assumptions:  
How  Theories  Can  Become  Self-­‐Fulfilling.  Academy  of  Management  Review,  30(1),  8-­‐24.  

Fincham,  Robin,  &  Clark,  Timothy.  (2009).  Introduction:  Can  We  Bridge  the  Rigour-­‐Relevance  Gap?  
Journal  of  Management  Studies,  46(3),  510-­‐515.  

Fine,  Ben,  &  Green,  Francis.  (2000).  Economics,  Social  Capital,  and  the  Colonization  of  the  Social  
Sciences.  In  Stephen  Baron,  John  Field  &  Tom  Schuller  (Eds.),  Social  Capital:  Critical  Perspectives  
(pp.  78-­‐93).  Oxford:  Oxford  University  Press.  

Fisher,  D.  M.,  &  Kiang,  M.  (2007).  A  Value-­‐Added  Approach  to  Selecting  the  Best  Master  of  Business  
(MBA)  Program.  Journal  of  Education  for  Business,  82,  72-­‐76.  

Fligstein,  Neil.  (2010).  Two  Books  on  the  Recent  Financial  Crisis.  Administrative  Science  Quarterly,  
55(1),  150-­‐155.  

Fligstein,  Neil.  (2011).  The  Banks  Did  It.  Contemporary  Sociology,  40(2),  140-­‐142.  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  62  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

Foss,  Nicolai  J.,  &  Klein,  Peter  G.  (2005).  The  Theory  of  the  Firm  and  Its  Critics:  A  Stocktaking  and  
Assessment.  Center  for  Knowledge  Governance,  Copenhagen  School  of  Business,  Working  Paper  
2/2005.  

Foster,  Richard.  (1968).  Reflections  on  Teaching  Criticism.  Contemporary  Literature,  9(3,  Modern  
Criticism),  406-­‐418.  

Fragueiro,  Fernando,  &  Thomas,  Howard.  (2011).  Strategic  Leadership  in  the  Business  School:  
Keeping  One  Step  Ahead.  Cambridge:  Cambridge  University  Press.  

Freedley,  Edwin  T.  (1853).  A  Practical  Treatise  on  Business:  On  How  to  Get,  Save,  Spend,  Give,  Lend,  
and  Bequeath  Money:  With  An  Inquiry  into  the  Chances  of  Success  and  Causes  of  Failure  in  
Business.  Philadelphia  PA:  Lippincott,  Grambo  &  Co.  

Freedley,  Edwin  T.  (1879).  Common  Sense  in  Business:  Practical  Answers  to  Practical  Questions  on  
the  True  Principles  and  Laws  of  Success  in  Farming,  Manufactures,  Speculation  ,  and  Buying  and  
Selling  Merchansdise.  Philadephia  PA:  Claxton,  Remsen  &  Haffelfinger.  

Freeman,  R.  Edward,  Harrison,  Jeffrey  S.,  Wicks,  Andrew  C.,  Parmar,  Bidhan  L.,  &  de  Colle,  Simone.  
(2010).  Stakeholder  Theory:  The  State  of  the  Art.  Cambridge:  Cambridge  University  Press.  

French,  Robert,  &  Grey,  Christopher  (1996).  Rethinking  Management  Education.  London:  Sage  
Publications.  

Friedman,  Milton.  (1953).  Essays  in  Positive  Economics.  Chicago  IL:  University  of  Chicago  Press.  

Friga,  Paul  N.,  Bettis,  Richard  A.,  &  Sullivan,  Robert  S.  (2003).  Changes  in  Graduate  Management  
Education  and  New  Business  School  Strategies  for  the  21st  Century.  Academy  of  Management  
Learning  &  Education,  2(3),  233-­‐249.  

Geanakoplos,  John.  (2005).  Three  Brief  Proofs  of  Arrow's  Impossibility  Theorem.  Economic  Theory,  
26,  211-­‐215.  

Geary,  Janet,  Marriott,  Liz,  &  Rowlinson,  Michael.  (2004).  Journal  Rankings  in  Business  and  
Management  and  the  2001  Research  Assessment  Exercise  in  the  UK.  British  Journal  of  
Management,  15,  95-­‐141.  

Ghadar,  Fariborz  (Ed.).  (1998).  New  Information  Technology  and  its  Impact  of  Global  Business  
Management.  University  Park  PA:  Center  for  Global  Business  Studies,  Penn  State  University.  

Ghoshal,  Sumantra.  (2005).  Bad  Management  Theories  are  Destroying  Good  Management  Practices.  
Academy  of  Management  Learning  &  Education,  4(1),  75-­‐91.  

Ghoshal,  Sumantra,  &  Moran,  James.  (1996).  Bad  for  Practice:  A  Critique  of  Transaction  Cost  Theory.  
Academy  of  Management  Review,  21(1),  13-­‐47.  

Gigerenzer,  Gerd,  &  Selten,  Reinhard  (Eds.).  (2001).  Bounded  Rationality:  The  Adaptive  Toolbox.  
Cambridge  MA:  MIT  Press.  

Gigerenzer,  Gerd,  Todd,  Peter  M.,  &  The  ABC  Research  Group.  (1999).  Simple  Heuristics  That  Make  
Us  Smart.  New  York:  Oxford  University  Press.  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  63  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

Gooday,  Graeme  J.  N.  (2004).  The  Morals  of  Measurement  Accuracy,  Irony,  and  Trust  in  Late  Victorian  
Electrical  Practice.  Cambridge:  Cambridge  University  Press.  

Hambrick,  Donald  C.  (1994).  1993  Presidential  Address  -­‐  What  if  the  Academy  Actually  Mattered.  
Academy  of  Management  Review,  19(1),  11-­‐16.  

Hanlon,  Gerard.  (1996).  "Casino  Capitalism"  and  the  Rise  of  the  "Commercialised"  Serivce  Class  -­‐  An  
Examination  of  the  Accountant.  Critical  Perspectives  in  Accounting,  7,  339-­‐363.  

Hannan,  Michael  T.    ,  &  Freeman,  John  (1977).  The  Population  Ecology  of  Organizations.  American  
Journal  of  Sociology,  82,  929-­‐964.  

Harris,  Robert  G.  (1984).  The  Value  of  Economic  Theory  in  Management  Education.  American  
Economic  Review,  74(2),  122-­‐126.  

Haskins,  Charler  Homer.  (1957).  The  Rise  of  the  Universities.  Ithaca  NY:  Cornell  University  Press.  

Hay,  Amanda,  &  Hodgkinson,  Myra.  (2008).  More  Success  Than  Meets  the  Eye  -­‐  A  Challenge  to  
Critqiues  of  the  MBA:  Possibilities  for  Critical  Management  Management  Education.  
Management  Learning,  39(1),  21-­‐40.  

Hayes,  Robert  H,  &  Abernathy,  William  J.  (1980).  Managing  Our  Way  to  Economic  Decline.  Harvard  
Business  Review,  July/August  58(4),  67-­‐77.  

Heald,  Morrell.  (1988).  The  Social  Responsibilities  of  Buisness:  Company  and  Community,  1900-­‐1960.  
New  Brunswick  NJ:  Transaction  Books.  

Henderson,  Lawrence  J.  (1927).  Business  Education  as  Envisaged  by  the  Scientist.  Harvard  Business  
Review,  4,  420-­‐423.  

Hersh,  Richard  H.,  &  Merrow,  John  (Eds.).  (2005).  Declining  by  Degrees:  Higher  Education  at  Risk.  
New  York:  Palgrave  Macmillan.  

Hirschman,  Albert  O.  (1970).  Exit,  Voice  and  Loyalty:  Responses  to  Decline  in  Firms,  Organizations  
and  States.  Cambridge  MA:  Harvard  University  Press.  

Holtom,  B.,  &  Inderrieden,  E.  (2007).  Investment  Advice:  Go  for  the  MBA.  BizEd(Jan/Feb),  36-­‐40.  

Hsu,  Maxwell  K.,  James,  Marcia  L.,  &  Chao,  Gary  H.  (2009).  An  Efficiency  Comparison  of  MBA  
Programs:  Top  10  Versus  Non-­‐Top  10.  Journal  of  Education  for  Business,  84(5),  269-­‐274.  

Hugstad,  Paul  S.  (1983).  The  Business  School  in  the  1980s:  Liberalism  versus  Vocationalism.  New  
York:  Praeger.  

Hunt,  James  G.  (1999).  Transformational/Charismatic  Leadership's  Tranformation  of  the  Field:  An  
Historical  Essay.  [Article].  Leadership  Quarterly,  10(2),  129.  

Iida,  Yoshio,  &  Oda,  Sobei  H.  (2011).  Does  Economics  Education  Make  Bad  Citizens?  The  Efects  of  
Economics  Education  in  Japan.  Journal  of  Ecucation  for  Business,  86(4),  234-­‐239.  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  64  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

Ijiri,  Y.  ,  &  Simon,  Herbert  A.  (1977).  Skew  Distributions  and  the  Sizes  of  Business  Firms.  Amsterdam:  
North-­‐Holland.  

Jacoby,  Neil  H.  (1956).  Economics  in  the  Curricula  of  Schools  of  Business:  Over-­‐all  Statement  of  the  
Problem  and  Situation.  American  Economic  Review,  46(2),  551-­‐562.  

Jarausch,  Konrad  H  (Ed.).  (1982).  The  Transformation  of  Higher  Learning:  Expansion,  Diversification,  
Social  Opening  and  Professionalization  in  England,  Germany,  Russia  and  the  United  States.  
Chicago  IL:  University  of  Chicago  Press.  

JMS  Editors.  (2004).  Point-­‐Counterpoint:  The  Future  of  the  Business  School.  Journal  of  Management  
Studies,  41(8),  1499-­‐1500.  

Johnson,  H.  Thomas,  &  Kaplan,  Robert  S.  (1987).  Relevance  Lost:  The  Rise  and  Fall  of  Managerial  
Accounting.  Boston  MA:  Harvard  Business  School  Press.  

Jones,  Edward  D.  (1914).  The  Business  Administrator:  His  Models  in  War,  Statecraft,  and  Science.  New  
York:  Engineering  Magazine  Co.  

Kanigel,  Robert.  (1997).  The  One  Best  Way:  Frederick  Winslow  Taylor  and  the  Enigma  of  Efficiency.  
New  York:  Viking  Press.  

Kay,  John  A.  (1991).  Economics  and  Business.  The  Economic  Journal,,  101(404,  Jan),  57-­‐63.  

Keller,  Morton,  &  Keller,  Phyllis.  (2001).  Making  Harvard  Modern:  The  Rise  of  America's  University  
(Updated  ed.).  New  York:  Oxford  University  Press.  

Kelly,  Francis  J.,  &  Kelley,  Heather  Mayfield.  (1986).  What  They  Really  Teach  You  at  the  Harvard  
Business  School.  New  York:  Warner  Books.  

Kemper,  Alison,  &  Martin,  Roger  L.  (2010).  After  the  Fall:  The  Global  Financial  Crisis  as  a  Test  of  
Corporiate  Social  Responsibility  Theories.  European  Management  Journal,  7,  229-­‐239.  

Keynes,  John  Maynard.  (2009).  The  General  Theory  of  Employment,  Interrest  and  Money.  New  York:  
Classic  Books.  

Khurana,  Rakesh.  (2007).  From  Higher  Aims  to  Hired  Hands:  The  Social  Transformation  of  American  
Business  Schools  and  the  Unfulfilled  Promise  of  Management  as  a  Profession.  Princeton  NJ:  
Princeton  University  Press.  

Khurana,  Rakesh,  &  Nohria,  Nitin.  (2008).  It  is  Time  to  Make  Management  A  True  Profession.  
Harvard  Business  Review,  86(10),  70-­‐77.  

Khurana,  Rakesh,  &  Penrice,  Daniel.  (2011).  Business  Education:  The  American  Trajectory.  In  Mette  
Morsing  &  Alfons  Sauquet  (Eds.),  Business  Schools  and  the  Contribution  to  Society  (pp.  3-­‐15).  
London:  Sage  Publications.  

Kitching,  John.  (1967).  Why  Do  Mergers  Miscarry?  Harvard  Business  Review,  45(6),  84-­‐101.  

Klein,  Peter  G.  (2001).  Were  the  Acquisitive  Conglomerates  Inefficient?  RAND  Journal  of  Economics,  
32(4  (Winter)),  745-­‐761.  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  65  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

Knights,  David.  (2008).  Myopic  Rhetorics:  Reflecting  Epistemologically  and  Ethically  on  the  Demand  
for  Relevance  in  Organizational  and  Management  Research.  Academy  of  Management  Learning  
&  Education,  7(4),  537-­‐552.  

Kolb,  Alice  Y.,  &  Kolb,  David  A.  (2005).  Learening  Styles  and  Learening  Spaces:  Enahncing  
Experiential  Learning  in  Higher  Education.  Academy  of  Management  Learning  &  Education,  4(2),  
193-­‐212.  

Kuchinke,  K.  Peter.  (2007).  Birds  of  a  Feather?  The  Critique  of  the  North  American  Business  School  
and  its  Implications  for  Educating  HRD  Practitioners.  Human  Resource  Development  Review,  
6(2),  111-­‐126.  

Lakatos,  Imre.  (1970).  Falsification  and  the  Methodology  of  Scientific  Research  Programmes  In  Imre  
Lakatos  &  Alan  Musgrave  (Eds.),  Criticism  and  the  Growth  of  Knowledge  (pp.  91-­‐196).  
Cambridge  Cambridge  University  Press.  

Lakatos,  Imre,  &  Musgrave,  Alan  (Eds.).  (1970).  Criticism  and  the  Growth  of  Knowledge.  Cambridge:  
Cambridge  University  Press.  

Landes,  David  S.  (1983).  Revolution  in  Time:  Clocks  and  the  Making  of  the  Modern  World.  

Larson,  Margali  S.  (1977).  The  Rise  of  Professionalism:  A  Sociological  Analysis.  Berkeley  CA:  
University  of  California  Press.  

Latour,  Bruno  ,  &  Woolgar,  Steve.  (1986).  Laboratory  Life:  The  Construction  of  Scientific  Facts.  
Princeton  NJ:  Princeton  University  Press.  

Laverty,  Kevin  J.  (1996).  Economic  "Short-­‐Termism":  The  Debate,  the  Unresolved  Issues,  and  the  
Implications  for  Management  Practice  and  Research.  Academy  of  Management  Review,  21(3),  
825-­‐860.  

Learned,  Edmund  P.,  Christensen,  C.  Roland,  &  Andrews,  Kenneth  R.  (1961).  Probelms  of  General  
Management  -­‐  Business  Policy.  Homewood  IL:  Richard  Irwin.  

Leith,  Sam.  (2011).  You  Talkin'  to  Me?  Rhetoric  from  Aristotle  to  Obama.  London:  Profile  Books.  

Lewis,  Harry  R.  (2007).  Excellence  Without  a  Soul:  Does  Liberal  Education  Have  a  Future?  New  York:  
Public  Affairs.  

Light,  Donald  W.  (1983).  The  Development  of  Professional  Schools  in  America.  In  K  H  Jarausch  
(Ed.),  The  Transformation  of  Higher  Learning  1860-­‐1930  (pp.  345-­‐365).  Stuttgart  University  of  
Chicago  Press.  

Locke,  Karen.  (2011).  Field  Research  Practice  in  Management  and  Organization  Studies:  Reclaiming  
its  Tradition  of  Discovery.  Academy  of  Management  Annals,  5(1,  June),  613-­‐652.  

Locke,  Robert  R.  (1984).  The  End  of  Practical  Man:  Entrepreneurship  and  Higher  Education  in  
Germany,  France  and  Great  Britain,  1880-­‐1940.  Greenwich  CT:  JAI  Press.  

Locke,  Robert  R.  (1989).  Management  and  Higher  Education  since  1940:  The  Influence  of  America  
and  Japan  on  West  Germany,  Great  Britain  and  France.  New  York:  Cambridge  University  Press.  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  66  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

Locke,  Robert  R.  (1996).  The  Collapse  of  the  American  Management  Mystique.  New  York:  Oxford  
University  Press.  

Locke,  Robert  R.  (1998).  Management  Education.  Guilford:  Ashgate.  

Locke,  Robert  R.  (2004).  American  Business  School  Education  and  the  Revolution  in  Interactive  
Information  Technology.  In  Paul  Jeffcutt  (Ed.),  The  Foundations  of  Management  Knowledge  (pp.  
66-­‐82).  London:  Routledge.  

Locke,  Robert  R.,  &  Schone,  Katja.  (2004).  The  Entrepreneurial  Shift:  Americanization  in  European  
High-­‐Tech  Management  Education.  Cambridge:  Cambridge  University  Press.  

Locke,  Robert  R.,  &  Spender,  J.-­‐C.  (2011).  Confronting  Managerialism:  How  the  Business  Elite  and  
Their  Schools  Threw  Our  Lives  Our  of  Balance.  London:  Zed  Books.  

Lorange,  Peter.  (2005).  Strategy  Means  Choice:  Also  for  Today’s  Business  School!  Journal  of  
Management  Development,  24(9),  783-­‐790.  

Lorange,  Peter.  (2008).  Thought  Leadership  Meets  Business:  How  Business  Schools  Can  Become  More  
Successful.  Cambridge:  Cambridge  University  Press.  

Lowell,  A.  Lawrence  (1923).  The  Profession  of  Business.  Harvard  Business  Review,  1(2),  129-­‐131.  

Lundstrom,  William  J.  (2011).  MBA  Attitudes  Toward  Business:  What  We  Don't  Know  Can  Hurt  Us  
or  Help  Us.  Journal  of  Education  for  Business,  86(3),  178-­‐185.  

Macfarlane,  Bruce.  (1998).  Business  Ethics  and  the  Idea  of  a  Higher  Education.  Teaching  Business  
Ethics  2:  35–47,  1998,  2(1),  35-­‐47.  

Madansky,  Albert.  (2008).  Teaching  History  in  Business  Schools:  An  Outsider's  View.  Academy  of  
Management  Learning  &  Education,  7(4),  553-­‐562.  

Mäki,  I.  Uskalki.  (1997).  Universals  and  the  Methodenstreit:  A  Reexamination  of  Carl  Menger's  
Conception  of  Economics  as  an  Exact  Science.  Studies  in  History  and  Philosophy  of  Science,  28,  
475-­‐495.  

March,  James  G.,  &  Simon,  Herbert  A.  (1958).  Organizations.  New  York:  John  Wiley.  

Marginson,  David,  &  McAulay,  Laurie.  (2008).  Exploring  the  Debate  on  Short-­‐Termism:  A  
Theoretical  and  Empirical  Analysis.  Strategic  Management  Journal,  29(3),  273-­‐292.  

Marshall,  Leon  C.  (Ed.).  (1921).  Business  Administration.  Chicago  IL:  University  of  Chicago  Press.  

Marston,  C.  L.,  &  Craven,  B.  M.  (1998).  A  Survey  of  Corporate  Perceptions  of  Short-­‐Termism  among  
Analysts  and  Fund  Managers.  European  Journal  of  Finance,  4(3),  233-­‐256.  

Maturana,  Humberto  R,  &  Varela,  Francisco  J.  (1980).  Autopoiesis  and  Cognition:  The  Realization  of  
the  Living.  Dordrecht,  Holland:  D.  Reidel.  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  67  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

McCabe,  Donald  L.,  Dukerich,  Janet  M.,  &  Dutton,  Jane  E.  (1994).  The  Effects  of  Professional  
Education  on  Values  and  the  Resolution  of  Ethical  Dilemmas:  Business  School  vs.  Law  School  
Students.  Journal  of  Business  Ethics,  13(9),  693-­‐700.  

McCormack,  Mark  H.  (1989).  They  Still  Don't  Teach  You  at  Harvard  Business  School.  New  York:  
Bantam.  

McGuire,  J.  W.  (1982).  Management  Theory:  Retreat  to  the  Academy.  Business  Horizons,  25(4),  31-­‐
37.  

McKenzie,  Rex  A.  (2011).  Casino  Capitalism  with  Derivatives:  Fragility  and  Instability  in  
Contemporary  Finance.  Review  of  Radical  Political  Economics,  43(2),  198-­‐215.  

McNair,  Malcolm  P.,  &  Hersum,  Anita  (Eds.).  (1954).  The  Case  Method  at  the  Harvard  Business  
School.  New  York:  McGraw-­‐Hill.  

Metcalf,  Henry  C.  (1926).  Scientific  Foundations  of  Business  Administration.  Baltimore  MD:  Williams  
&  Wilkins  Company.  

Metcalf,  Henry  C  (Ed.).  (1927).  Business  Management  as  a  Profession.  Chicago  IL:  A.  W.  Shaw  
Company.  

Mintzberg,  Henry.  (2004).  Managers  not  MBAs:  A  Hard  Look  at  the  Soft  Practice  of  Managing  and  
Management  Development.  San  Francisco  CA:  Berrett-­‐Koehler  Publishers.  

Mokyr,  Joel.  (1990).  The  Lever  of  Riches:  Technological  Creativity  and  Economic  Progress.  New  York:  
Oxford  University  Press.  

Molho,  Ian.  (1997).  The  Economics  of  Information:  Lying  and  Cheating  in  Markets  and  Organizations.  
Oxford:  Blackwell.  

Montgomery,  David  B.,  &  Ramus,  Catherine  A.  (2011).  Caoibrating  MBA  Job  Preferences  for  the  21st  
Century.  Academy  of  Management  Learning  &  Education,  10(1),  9-­‐26.  

Morgeson,  Frederick  P.,  &  Nahrgang,  Jennifer  D.  (2006).  Same  as  It  Ever  Was:  Recognizing  Stability  
in  the  Business  Week  Rankings.  Paper  presented  at  the  Academy  of  Management  Annual  
Meeting.    

Morsing,  Mette,  &  Sauquet,  Alfons  (Eds.).  (2011).  Business  Schools  and  Their  Contiribution  to  Society.  
London:  Sage  Publications.  

Munir,  Kamal  A.  (2011).  Financial  Crisis  2008-­‐2009:  What  Does  the  Silence  of  Institutional  
Theorists  Tell  Us?  Journal  of  Management  Inquiry,  20(2),  114-­‐117.  

Nasr,  Vali.  (2009).  The  Rise  of  Islamic  Capitalism.  New  York:  Free  Press.  

Navarro,  Peter.  (2008).  The  MBA  Core  Curricula  of  Top-­‐Ranked  US  Business  Schools:  a  Study  in  
Failure?  Academy  of  Management  Learning  &  Education,  7(1),  108-­‐123.  

Neale,  A.  D.  (1970).  The  Antitrust  Laws  of  the  U.S.A.:  A  Study  of  Competition  Enforced  by  Law  (2nd  
ed.).  Cambridge:  Cambridge  University  Press.  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  68  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

Nelson,  Richard  R.  (1990).  Capitalism  as  an  Engine  of  Progress.  Research  Policy,  19,  193-­‐214.  

Nelson,  Richard  R.,  &  Winter,  Sidney  G.  (1982).  An  Evolutionary  Theory  of  Economic  Change.  
Cambridge  MA:  Belknap  Press.  

Neumark,  David,  Wall,  Brandon,  &  Zhang,  Junfu.  (2011).  Do  Small  Business  Create  More  Jobs?  New  
Evidence  for  the  United  States  from  the  National  Establishment  Time  Series.  Review  of  
Economics  &  Statistics,  93(1),  6-­‐29.  

Nohria,  Nitin,  &  Khurana,  Rakesh  (Eds.).  (2010).  Handbook  of  Leadership  Theory  and  Practice:  A  
Harvard  Business  School  Centennial  Colloquium.  Boston  MA:  Harvard  Business  School  Press.  

O'Brien,  George  Dennis.  (1998).  All  the  Essential  Half-­‐Truths  about  Higher  Education.  Chicago  IL:  
University  of  Chicago  Press.  

O'Connor,  Ellen  S.  (2011).  Creating  New  Knowledge  in  Management:  Appropriating  the  Field's  Lost  
Foundations.  Stanford  CA:  Stanford  Business  Books.  

O'Keefe,  Daniel  J.  (2002).  Persuasion:  Theory  and  Research  (2nd  ed.).  Thousand  Oaks  CA:  Sage.  

Oblinger,  Diana  G.,  &  Verville,  Anne-­‐Lee.  (1998).  What  Business  Wants  from  Higher  Education.  
Phoenix  AZ:  Oryx  Press.  

Owton,  Helen.  (2011).  The  Trouble  with  Higher  Education:  A  Critical  Examination  of  Our  
Universities.  Studies  in  Higher  Education,  36(2),  243-­‐245.  

Özbilgin,  Mustafa  F.  (2009).  From  Journal  Rankings  to  Making  Sense  of  the  World.  [Article].  
Academy  of  Management  Learning  &  Education,  8(1),  113-­‐121.  

Palmer,  Timothy  B.,  &  Short,  Jeremy  C.  (2008).  Mission  Statements  in  U.S.  Colleges  of  Business:  An  
Empirical  Examination  of  Their  Content  with  Linkages  to  Configuration  and  Performance.  
Academy  of  Management  Learning  &  Education,  7(4),  454-­‐470.  

Partnoy,  Frank.  (2004).  Infectious  Grteed:  How  Deceit  and  Risk  Corrupted  the  Finanical  Markets.  
London:  Profile  Books.  

Patterson,  Scott.  (2010).  The  Quants:    How  a  New  Breed  of  Maths  Whizzes  Conquered  Wall  Street  and  
Nearly  Destroyed  It.  New  York:  Crown  Business.  

Peck,  James.  (2010).  Constructions  of  Neoliberal  Reason.  Oxford:  Oxford  University  Press.  

Pelikan,  Jaroslav  (1992).  The  Idea  of  The  University:  A  Reexamination.  New  Haven  CT:  Yale  
University  Press.  

Perriton,  Linda.  (2007).  Really  Useful  knowledge?  Critical  Management  Education  in  the  UK  and  the  
US.  [Article].  Scandinavian  Journal  of  Management,  23(1),  66-­‐83.  

Pettigrew,  Andrew  M.  (2001).  Management  Research  after  Modernism.  British  Journal  of  
Management,  12(Special  Issue),  S61-­‐S70.  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  69  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

Pfeffer,  Jeffrey.  (2005).  Why  Do  Bad  Management  Theories  Persist?  A  Comment  on  Ghoshal.  
Academy  of  Management  Learning  &  Education,  4(1),  96-­‐100.  

Pfeffer,  Jeffrey.  (2007).  What's  Right  and  Still  Wrong  with  Business  Schools.  
BizEd(January/February),  42-­‐49.  

Pfeffer,  Jeffrey,  &  Fong,  Christina  T.  (2002).  The  End  of  Business  Schools?    Less  Success  Than  Meets  
the  Eye.  Academy  of  Management  Learning  and  Education,  1(1),  78-­‐95.  

Policano,  Andrew  J.  (2001).  Ten  Easy  Steps  to  a  Top-­‐25  MBA  Program.  Selections,  1(2),  39-­‐40.  

Policano,  Andrew  J.  (2005).  What  Price  Rankings?  BizEd(September/October),  26-­‐32.  

Popper,  Karl  R.  (1968).  The  Logic  of  Scientific  Discovery.  London:  Hutchinson.  

Popper,  Karl  R.  (1969).  Conjectures  and  Refutations:  The  Growth  of  Scientific  Knowledge  (3rd  ed.).  
London:  Routledge  and  Kegan  Paul.  

Porter,  Michael  E.  (1992).  Capital  Disadvantage:  America's  Failing  Capital  Investment  System.  
Harvard  Business  Review,  70(5),  65-­‐82.  

Porter,  Theodore  M.  (1986).  The  Rise  of  Statistical  Thinking  1820-­‐1900.  Princeton  NJ:  Princeton  
University  Press.  

Porter,  Theodore  M.  (1995).  Trust  in  Numbers:  The  Pursuit  of  Objectivity  in  Science  and  Public  Life.  
Prineton  NJ:  Princeton  University  Press.  

Preston,  Lee  E.,  &  Post,  James  E.  (1974).  The  Third  Managerial  Revolution.  Academy  of  Management  
Journal,  17(3,  Sept),  476-­‐486.  

Preston,  Lee  E.,  &  Post,  James  E.  (1975).  Private  Management  and  Public  Policy.  Englewood  Cliffs,  NJ:  
Prentice-­‐Hall.  

Previts,  Gary  John,  &  Merino,  Barbara  Dubis.  (1998).  A  History  of  Accounting  in  teh  United  Staes:  The  
Cultural  Significance  of  Accounting.  Columbus  OH:  Ohio  State  University  Press.  

Redlich,  Fritz  (1957).  Academic  Education  for  Business:  Its  Development  and  the  Contribution  of  
Ignaz  Jastrow  (1856-­‐1937).  Business  History  Review,  31,  35-­‐91.  

Regatiero,  Andre.  (2010).  Revisting  Firm  Size  and  Job  Creation.  CMU  Working  Paper.  

Rehder,  Robert  R.  (1982).  American  Business  Education  -­‐  Is  It  Too  Late  to  Change?  Sloan  
Management  Review,  23(2  Winter),  63-­‐71.  

Reid,  Joanne  R.  ,  &  Anderson,  Phyllis  R.  (2012).  Critical  Thinking  in  the  Business  Classroom.  Journal  
of  Education  for  Business,  87(1),  52-­‐59.  

Revans,  Reginald  W.  (1967).  Professor  Simon  on  Business  Schools,  Journal  of  Management  Studies  
(Vol.  4,  pp.  168):  Blackwell  Publishing  Limited.  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  70  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

Revans,  Reginald  W.  (1971).  Developing  Effective  Managers:  A  New  Approach  to  Business  Education.  
New  York:  Praeger  Publishers.  

Rhoades,  Gary,  &  Sporn,  Barbara.  (2002).  New  Models  of  Management  and  Shifting  Modes  and  Costs  
of  Production:  Europe  and  the  United  States.  Tertiary  Education  and  Management,  8(1),  3-­‐28.  

Rochford,  Linda,  &  Borchert,  Patricia  S.  (2011).  Assessing  Higher  Level  Learning:  Developing  
Rubrics  for  Case  Analysis.  Journal  of  Education  for  Business,  86,  258–265.  

Rosanas,  Josep  M.  (2007).  On  the  Methodology  of  Management  Research.  IESE  Working  Paper  #  692,  
1-­‐18.  

Rötheli,  Tobias  F.  (2010).  Causes  of  the  financial  crisis:  Risk  misperception,  policy  mistakes,  and  
banks’  bounded  rationality.  Journal  of  Socio-­‐Economics,  39,  119-­‐126.  

Rowlinson,  Michael,  Clark,  Peter  A.,  Delahaye-­‐Dado,  Agnes,  Booth,  Charles,  &  Procter,  Stephen.  
(2008).  The  Uses  of  History  as  Corporate  Knowledge.  In  Harry  Scarbrough  (Ed.),  The  Evolution  
of  Business  Knowledge  (pp.  339-­‐356).  Oxford:  Oxford  University  Press.  

Ruch,  Richard  S.  (2003).  Higher  Ed.  Inc:  The  Rise  of  the  For-­‐Profit  University.  Baltimore  MD:  Jaohns  
Hopkins  University  Press.  

Ruef,  Martin.  (2008).  Book  Review:  From  Higher  Aims  to  Hired  Hands:  The  Social  Transformation  of  
American  Business  Schools  and  the  Unfulfilled  Promise  of  Management  as  a  Profession.  Rakesh  
Khurana.  Princeton,  NJ:  Princeton  University  Press,.  Administrative  Science  
Quarterly(December),  745-­‐752.  

Rumelt,  Richard  P.,  Schendel,  Dan    E.  ,  &  Teece,  David  J.  (Eds.).  (1994).  Fundamental  Issues  in  
Strategy:  A  Research  Agenda.  Boston  MA:  Harvard  Business  School  Press.  

Saliba,  George.  (2007).  Islamic  Science  and  the  Making  of  the  European  Renaissance.  Cambridge  MA:  
MIT  Press.  

Schön,  Donald  A.  (1983).  The  Reflective  Practitioner:  How  Professionals  Think  in  Action.  New  York:  
Basic  Books.  

Schön,  Donald  A.  (1987).  Educating  the  Reflective  Practitioner.  San  Francsico  CA:  Jossey-­‐Bass.  

Sen,  Amartya  K.  (1979).  Personal  Utilities  and  Public  Judgements:  Or  What's  Wrong  with  Wlefare  
Economics.  Economic  Journal,  89(355),  537-­‐558.  

Senn,  Peter.  (2005).  The  German  Historical  Schools  in  the  History  of  Economic  Thoujght.  Journal  of  
Economic  Studies,  32(3),  185-­‐255.  

Sennett,  Richard.  (2006).  The  Culture  of  the  New  Capitalism.  New  Haven  CT:  Yale  University  Press.  

Sexton,  Donald  L.,  &  Landström,  Hans  (Eds.).  (2000).  Blackwell  Handbook  of  Entrepreneurship.  
Oxford:  Blackwell.  

Shafritz,  Jay  M.,  &  Ott,  J.  Steven  (Eds.).  (2001).  Classics  of  Organization  Theory  (5th  ed.).  Belmont  CA:  
Wadsworth.  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  71  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

Sheppard,  Sheri  D.,  Macatangay,  Kelly,  Colby,  Anne,  &  Sullivan,  William  M.  (2008).  Educating  
Engineers:  Designing  For  the  Future  of  the  Field.  San  Francisco  CA:  Jossey-­‐Bass.  

Simon,  Herbert  A.  (1947).  Administrative  Behavior:  A  Study  of  Decision-­‐Making  Processes  in  
Administrative  Organization  (1st  ed.).  New  York:  Macmillan.  

Simon,  Herbert  A.  (1967).  The  Business  School:  A  Problem  in  Organizational  Design.  Journal  of  
Management  Studies,  4(1),  1-­‐16.  

Simon,  Herbert  A.  (1983).  Reason  in  Human  Affairs.  Stanford  CA:  Stanford  University  Press.  

Smiddy,  Harold  F.,  &  Naum,  Lionel.  (1954).  Evolution  of  a  "Science  of  Managing"  in  America.  
Management  Science,  1(1),  1-­‐31.  

Sorkin,  Andrew  Ross.  (2009).  Too  Big  to  Fail:  The  Inside  Story  of  How  Wall  Street  and  Washington  
Fought  to  Save  the  Financial  System  -­‐  and  Themselves.  New  York:  Viking.  

Spender,  J.-­‐C.  (1989).  Industry  Recipes:  The  Nature  and  Sources  of  Managerial  Judgement.  Oxford:  
Blackwell.  

Spender,  J.-­‐C.  (2005).  Speaking  about  Management  Education:  Some  History  of  the  Search  for  
Legitimacy  and  the  Ownership  and  Control  of  Management  Knowledge.  Management  Decision  
incorporating  the  Journal  of  Management  History,  43(10),  1282-­‐1292.  

Spender,  J.-­‐C.  (2007a).  Data,  Meaning  and  Practice:  How  the  Knowledge-­‐Based  View  Can  Clarify  
Technology's  Relationship  With  Organizations.  International  Journal  of  Technology  
Management,  38(1/2),  178-­‐196.  

Spender,  J.-­‐C.  (2007b).  Management  as  a  Regulated  Profession:  An  Essay.  Journal  of  Management  
Inquiry,  16(1),  32-­‐42.  

Spender,  J.-­‐C.  (2008a).  Can  Simon's  Notion  of  `Bounded  Rationality'  Give  Us  New  Ideas  About  
Leadership?  Leadership,  4,  95-­‐109.  

Spender,  J.-­‐C.  (2008b).  Organizational  Learning  and  Knowledge  Management:  Whence  and  
Whither?  Management  Learning,  39(2),  159-­‐176.  

Spender,  J.-­‐C.  (2011a).  Human  Capital  and  Agency  Theory.  In  Alan  Burton-­‐Jones  &  J.-­‐C.  Spender  
(Eds.),  The  Oxford  Handbook  of  Human  Capital  (pp.  186-­‐217).  Oxford  Oxford  University  Press.  

Spender,  J.-­‐C.  (2011b).  On  Green  Business  and  Green  Values.  In  Christos  Pitelis,  Jack  Keenan  &  Vicky  
Pryce  (Eds.),  Green  Business,  Green  Values,  and  Sustainability  (pp.  141-­‐154).  London:  Routledge.  

Spender,  J.-­‐C.  (forthcoming).  Herbert  Alexander  Simon:  Philosopher  of  the  Organizational  Life-­‐
World.  In  Morgen  Witzel  &  Malcolm  Warner  (Eds.),  Oxford  Handbook  of  Management  Thinkers.  
Oxford:  Oxford  University  Press.  

Spender,  J.-­‐C.,  &  Kijne,  Hugo  (Eds.).  (1996).  Scientific  Management:  Frederick  Winslow  Taylor's  Gift  to  
the  World?  Norwell  MA:  Kluwer.  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  72  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

Starkey,  Ken,  Hatchuel,  Armand,  &  Tempest,  Sue.  (2004).  Rethinking  the  Business  School,  Journal  of  
Management  Studies  (Vol.  41,  pp.  1521):  Blackwell  Publishing  Limited.  

Starkey,  Ken,  &  Tiratsoo,  Nick.  (2007).  The  Business  School  and  the  Bottom  Line.  Cambridge:  
Cambridge  University  Press.  

Stewart,  Matthew.  (2009).  The  Management  Myth:  Why  the  Experts  Keep  Getting  It  Wrong.  New  
York:  W.  W.  Norton.  

Strange,  Susan.  (1997).  Casino  Capitalism.  Manchester:  Manchester  University  Press.  

Thomas,  Howard,  &  Wilson,  Alexander  D.  (2009).  An  Anallysis  of  the  Environment  and  Competitive  
Dynamics  of  Management  Research.  Journal  of  Management  Development,  28(8),  668-­‐684.  

Thomas,  Howard,  &  Wilson,  Alexander  D.  (2011).  ‘Physics  Envy’,  Cognitive  Legitimacy  or  Practical  
Relevance:  Dilemmas  in  the  Evolution  of  Management  Research  in  the  UK.  British  Journal  of  
Management,  22,  443–456.  

Thompson,  Arthur  A.,  &  Strickland,  A.  J.  (1987).  Strategic  Management:  Concepts  and  Cases  (4th  Ed.).  
Plano  TX:  Business  Publications  Inc.  

Tierney,  William  G.,  &  Hentshcke,  Guilbert  C.  (2007).  New  Players,  Different  Game:  Understanding  
the  Rise  of  the  For-­‐Profit  Colleges  and  Universities.  Baltimore  MD:  Johns  Hopkins  University  
Press.  

Turkle,  Sherry.  (1984).  The  Second  Self:  Computers  and  the  Human  Spirit.  New  York:  Simon  and  
Schuster.  

Van  Fleet,  David  D.,  &  Wren,  Daniel  A.  (2005).  Teaching  History  in  Business  Schools:  1982-­‐2003.  
Academy  of  Management  Learning  &  Education,  4(1),  44-­‐56.  

Van  Maanen,  John.  (2011).  Ethnography  as  Work:  Some  Rules  of  Engagement.  Journal  of  
Management  Studies,  48(1),  218-­‐234.  

Vaughn,  Karen  I.  (1994).  Austrian  Economics  in  America:  The  Migration  of  a  Tradition.  Cambridge:  
Cambridge  University  Press.  

Veblen,  Thorstein.  (1965).  The  Theory  of  the  Business  Enterprise.  New  York:  Augustus  M.  Kelley.  

Washburn,  Jennifer.  (2005).  University,  Inc.:  The  Corporate  Corruption  of  American  Higher  Education.  
New  York:  Basic  Books.  

Wedlin,  Linda.  (2011).  Going  Global:  Rankings  as  Rhetorical  Devices  to  Construct  an  International  
Field  of  Management  Education.  Management  Learning,  42(23),  199-­‐218.  

Welsch,  Lawrence  A,  &  Cyert,  Richard  M  (Eds.).  (1970).  Management  Decision  Making:  Selected  
Readings.  Harmondsworth:  Penguin  Books.  

Wensley,  Robin.  (2011).  Getting  Too  Close  to  the  Fire:  The  Challenge  of  Engaging  Stories  and  Saving  
Lives.  British  Journal  of  Management,  22,  370-­‐381.  

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  73  of  74  


EFMD  Zurich  Draft  v4.4  

Westerman,  James  W.,  Bergman,  Jacqueline  Z.,  Bergman,  Shawn  M.,  &  Daly,  Joseph  P.  (forthcoming).  
Are  Universities  Creating  Narcissistic  Employees?  An  Empirical  Examionation  of  Narcissism  in  
Business  Students  and  Its  Implications.  Journal  of  Management  Education.  

Whitley,  Richard  D,  Thomas,  Alan  ,  &  Marceau,  Jane  (1981).  Masters  of  Business?  Business  Schools  
and  Business  Graduates  in  Britain  and  France.  London:  Tavistock  Publications.  

Williamson,  Oliver  E.,  &  Winter,  Sidney  G.  (Eds.).  (1991).  The  Nature  of  the  Firm:  Origins,  Evolution,  
and  Development.  New  York:  Oxford  University  Press.  

Wilshire,  Bruce  (1990).  The  Moral  Collapse  of  the  University:  Professionalism,  Purity,  and  Alienation.  
Albany  NY:  State  University  of  New  York  Press.  

Wilson,  David,  &  McKiernan,  Peter.  (2011).  Global  Mimicry:  Putting  Strategic  Choice  back  on  the  
Business  School  Agenda.  British  Journal  of  Management,  22,  457-­‐469.  

Wilson,  Woodrow  (1887).  The  Study  of  Administration.  Political  Science  Quarterly,  2,  197-­‐220.  

Windsor,  Duane.  (2006).  Corporate  Social  Responsibility:  Three  Key  Approaches.  Journal  of  
Management  Studies,  43(1),  93-­‐114.  

Witzel,  Morgen.  (2011).  A  History  of  Management  Thought.  Abingdon  Oxon:  Routledge.  

Wright,  Robert  E.  (2010).  Teaching  History  in  Business  Schools:  An  Insider’s  View.  Academy  of  
Management  Learning  &  Education,  9(4),  697-­‐700.  

Zeckhauser,  Richard.  (2010).  Causes  of  the  Financial  Crisis:  Many  Responsible  Parties.  .  HKS  Faculty  
Research  Working  Paper  Series,  RWP10-­‐016,  John  F.  Kennedy  School  of  Government,  Harvard  
University.  

Zemsky,  Robert,  Wegner,  Gregory  R,  &  Massy,  William  F.  (2005).  Remaking  the  American  University:  
Market-­‐Smart  and  Mission-­‐Centered.  New  Brunswick  NJ:  Rutgers  University  Press.  

Zimmerman,  Jerold  L.  (2001).  Can  American  Business  Schools  Survive?  Working  Paper  FR01-­‐16:  
William  E.  Simon  Graduate  School  of  Business  Administration,  University  of  Rochester.  
 
 

11-­‐Jan-­‐12                     Page  74  of  74  

Вам также может понравиться