Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 4

Modes of Production

Donald L Donham, University of California, Davis, CA, USA


Ó 2015 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Abstract

Marxist social theory is often thought of as ‘materialist’ and ‘determinist.’ Just how misleading this characterization can be
emerged principally in the 1970s in a wide-ranging conversation about modes of production. This article attempts to
summarize the lasting contribution of this intervention by reviewing what modes of production are, how they are structured,
and why they change over world history.

Concepts in the social sciences often go through intense phases The grand evolutionary teleology in Marx’s view of history –
of development followed by periods in which they take on the circular but progressive spiral from primitive to modern
background status. In the latter times, ideas remain alive, but communism – accounts for much of the political appeal of
they are no longer being extended or deepened. One example is Marx’s ideas. Ironically, that appeal was felt mainly in countries
Karl Marx’s notion of modes of production. First developed in on the periphery of capitalist development such as Russia in
the nineteenth century, the idea of modes of production 1917, China in 1949, and Ethiopia in 1974; in such locations,
underwent a dramatic transformation in the late 1960s and the notion of stages of history appeared to offer a road map to
1970s as anthropologists, economists, historians, and philos- a better future, a way to skip ahead to modernity. But this
ophers were drawn into a wide-ranging conversation. The aspect of Marx’s work also accounts for its ambivalent reception
critical impulse was largely spent by the 1980s, but by that among social scientists who, even if they identified with
point, aspects of Marx’s thought had been developed in strik- progressive politics, distrusted apparent teleologies and grap-
ingly new directions. Some might even think that Marx had pled with refractory evidence.
been stood on his head. As Marxism began to provide the legitimating ideology of
This article is an attempt to set out some of the enduring socialist states in the twentieth century, it tended to stagnate
legacies of this discussion. It defines forces and relations of there. In the capitalist West, however, Marx’s ideas received
production and describes how the first may be thought to critique and development, principally during periods of crisis.
determine the second in the creation of distinctive ways or Dogmas of various sorts were questioned, and eventually
modes of producing social life. Karl Marx’s term Pro- a more flexible version of Marxist theory took its place along-
duktionsweise is usually translated into English as ‘mode of side others in the social sciences.
production,’ but it might be more simply rendered as ‘way of In the field of anthropology this began after the upheavals
producing.’ Never precisely defined in Marx’s work – yet argu- of 1968, particularly in France where, under the influence of
ably at the center of it – Produktionsweise refers to both a form or structuralist philosopher Louis Althusser, scholars such as
structure and a way of producing. One might say that Marx’s Claude Meillassoux, Pierre-Philippe Rey, Maurice Godelier,
object in Capital was to show how the first – a particular and Emmanuel Terray attempted to extend the notion of
structure of unequal power and wealth – was both the cause modes of production to so-called precapitalist societies. In this
and the result of the second, men, and women pursuing their article, I attempt to summarize the lasting legacy of this
individual ends within capitalist cultural assumptions. conversation. I do so, not in the structuralist vocabulary of the
One notable aspect of the capitalist mode of production is, time, but in reference to what I regard as the clarifying, later
according to Marx, its inherent instability. Crises are necessary, work of British analytical philosopher G.A. Cohen.
built-in features of this way of producing; they are not What, then, is a mode of production? Perhaps the simplest
somehow accidents caused by factors outside it. As individuals answer is that it is a model of certain basic regularities that hold
pursue their capitalist projects, there comes a point, finally, across and therefore define historical epochs. At the heart of
when the entire social system can no longer be reproduced. these regularities is the interrelationship between technology in
Then, social revolution appears on the horizon, and the mode some broad sense and forms of social inequality. According to
of production stands to be fundamentally transformed. Marx, the first (Produktivkräfte, or productive forces) determines
Even though Marx referred at times to other modes of the second (Produktionsverhältnisse, or relations of production).
production – primitive communist, the ancient, Asiatic, feudal, These two constitute the base of a mode of production, which,
socialist, and finally modern communist – his only developed in turn, determines the superstructure.
work was on capitalism. On what would come after capitalism,
he offered only the vaguest of outlines; it would fall to Lenin
and others to construct actually existing socialisms. And Productive Forces
on what came ‘before,’ Marx sometimes reflected only the
European prejudices of the nineteenth century. For example, he Productive forces are anything that can be used in productive
thought that the Asiatic mode of production was inherently interaction with nature. On this reading, productive forces are
static and would waken to change only through the effects of not simply raw materials or tools; more inclusively, they are
Western imperialism. human skills, productive knowledge, and even the technical

714 International Encyclopedia of the Social & Behavioral Sciences, 2nd edition, Volume 15 http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/B978-0-08-097086-8.12110-5
Modes of Production 715

aspects of human cooperation in the labor process. These constituted – whether by economic, coercive, or religious
factors Marx considered as equally ‘material’ in that all can be means (or some mix of these). This makes the reformed notion
utilized to produce. But most current readers would probably of modes of production quite different from what is often
classify objects, knowledge, and the technical aspects of coop- assumed of Marxism; most particularly, it is not a form of
eration as, respectively, material, ideal, and social. economic reductionism.
The most striking aspect of productive forces has been their Why do productive inequalities occupy a central place in
tendency to expand over human history. In the most general Marx’s thought? The answer is that they locate the basic divi-
sense, the anterior cause of this tendency appears to be located sions within any society, the lines of potential opposition – of
in human nature itself. Humans everywhere develop their contradiction. Marx saw these as the potential fault lines along
powers and skills in a continuous dialectic with nature, and which tensions tend to build up are routinely dissipated by
when presented with a choice between more or less efficient small readjustments, and are sometimes violently resolved by
means of production, humans everywhere (with certain limited radical realignments. These fault lines are structural; they do
exceptions) choose the first. not necessarily lead to actual struggle and conflict (indeed, the
If productive forces have tended to expand, this fact can be function of the superstructure is precisely to prevent such
established only at the world level. Some individual societies occurrences). Nevertheless, contradictions always exist as
have stagnated; some have even experienced local declines in potentialities; they lie just below the surface.
the level of productive powers. As will become clear in this
article, relations of production can prevent technical develop-
ment beyond a certain point. For any particular society in stasis, Forces Determine Relations
there is no reason to believe that new social relations
compatible with the further expansion of forces must develop. Ordinarily, if a factor X is said to determine factor Y, then X is
In fact, technical knowledge tends to diffuse from place to taken to cause Y. Given X, Y is uniquely specified. Transferred to
place, and typically the most ‘advanced’ societies are not the Marx’s scheme given here, this understanding of determination
ones that give rise to the next development. Rather, peripheral yields what has been called ‘vulgar Marxism.’ Such an inter-
groups that are the recipients of the productive knowledge of pretation can be supported by some of Marx’s own, more
their more ‘advanced’ neighbors often leapfrog ahead. incautious summary statements: “The handmill gives you
Just what determines the level of development of productive society with the feudal lord; the steam mill society with the
forces should be considered. A society’s mass of productive industrial capitalist.” Empirically, it is clear that the same
forces is determined by two factors: the first is the average technology can exist in different modes of production.
productivity of labor, and the second is population. The A great deal of effort has been expended by commentators
product of these two factors yields the level of productive to explicate Marx’s notion of determination – from examina-
forces. In this formulation, population itself is not a productive tion of dialectics to, in Engels’ phrase, determination only ‘in
force, yet it enters into the determination of the level of the last instance.’ Probably the best way to clarify Marx’s claims
productive powers. is to note that they are forms of functional, not causal, expla-
nation. Immediately, a distinction needs to be drawn between
functional explanations and the theoretical school known as
Relations of Production functionalism in sociology and anthropology: Marx used
functionalist explanations, but he was not a ‘functionalist’ in
Relations of production are not, as the English phrase suggests, the second sense.
simply the social relationships formed in the actual process of Functional explanations have a distinct logical form in
production. Rather, they are the de facto power relationships that which the effects of a trait enter into the explanation of the
both underlie and are the result of the division of the fruits of presence of that trait: for example, when Y’s presence is partly
a society’s total labor. Household head versus dependents, chief explained by some positive consequence Y has for X. In such
versus subjects, master versus slaves, feudal lord versus peasants, a case, X can be said to determine or ‘select’ Y because of Y’s
and capitalist versus workers – relations of production are basic effect on X.
asymmetries of power grounded in the organization of material Marx believed that the level of productive forces selects
life. In capitalism, relations of production rest upon actual relations of production. For any given level of development of
control over productive forces in the process of production, but forces, there is only a limited set of relations possible –
in other modes of production, as anthropologists and historians namely, those that are compatible with and in fact promote
eventually showed, this is not necessarily the case. the further development of forces. Here, X hardly causes Y in
In relation to the last point, consider the contrast between a one-way pattern of determination. Rather, the reverse is
capitalism and precolonial chiefdoms in Africa. Capitalists put closer to the truth: it is Y’s effect on X that is paramount.
the production process into motion; they or their representa- Particular relations cause expansion in the forces. Herein lies
tives oversee and supervise in order to ensure that a profit is the rub, however. As forces expand, they reach a level that is
produced at the end of the work cycle. In many chiefdoms, no longer compatible with the existing relations of produc-
chiefs did not control the production process itself. Yet, having tion. At that point, according to Marx, revolution becomes
produced, subjects brought tribute, the fruits of their own a possibility. In this way, continuous incremental change
labors, to the chief. This contrast illustrates the fact that rela- (in forces) is mapped onto occasionally discontinuous revo-
tions of production, by definition, correspond to the basic lutionary change (in relations) in the base of modes of
structures of power in a society, however that power is production.
716 Modes of Production

Bases Determine Superstructures


D
One of the important contributions of G.A. Cohen was
a clarification of the notion of superstructure. If Marx claims

Relations
that the base or, more precisely, relations of production
determine the superstructure, then a definition of relations C
and superstructure must be found in which the two are clearly
B
distinguished. The difficulty is that power as we find it in any
social formation is inevitably encased in particular cultural A
and legal concepts (i.e., superstructural notions). It was for
this reason that Cohen defined relations of production as the
de facto distribution of power. Every culturally encoded right, Forces
he argued, can be matched with a de facto power. And it is de
Figure 1 A possible set of forces and relations of production when
facto power that determines culturally specific notions, rather functional alternatives exist.
than the reverse.
One important effect of this definitional move is to place
the long-term dynamic of a mode of production outside of Marx’s ideas. Carl Hempel and others have called attention to the
culture itself. Eventually, culture corresponds to de facto power difficulties of actually carrying out functional explanations. Not
rather than the reverse. But in the short term, it places culture at the least of these stem from the problem of functional alterna-
the very center of the analysis of modes of production, for it is tives. That is, there is often more than one Y (Y1, Y2, Y3, .) that
precisely the superstructure that defines and stabilizes relations can fulfill any given function. That being so, the particular pres-
of production. Once again, the logic of functional explanation ence of Y1, say, cannot be explained simply by referring to its
turns the ordinary expectations about Marxism upside-down. If function, for Y2 or Y3 could have served the same need.
something is described as having a base and a superstructure, The critical question becomes “What is the size of the set of
we think of the base as a foundation. It supports the super- functional alternatives?” Implicitly, Marx appears to have
structure; without the foundation, the superstructure would fall believed that alternatives are quite limited – typically to the set
to the ground. Yet, the logic of functional explanation requires of one. Consider such a limiting case. For each level of devel-
the opposite: it is the superstructure that defines the base. opment of productive forces, there is only one set of relations
To adapt a visual image from Cohen (1978), consider the possible. History therefore proceeds in a series of discrete steps
following: Four pieces of wood of the same length are driven from A to B to C. Both the past and the future are specified –
a little way into the ground. They stand, but they are easily socialism is inevitable because it is supposedly the only
blown over by a strong wind. A top is attached to the four struts economic system consistent with highly developed forces.
such that the whole becomes a table. The struts, now legs, stand A different story emerges if the number of functional
solidly upright. They do not wobble in the wind. Of the alternatives is even moderately few. If several different sets of
tabletop, one can say that (1) it is supported by the legs, and relations of production are compatible with any given level of
(2) its very existence is required for the legs to be legs. Without forces, then the grand design of world history becomes
the top, the legs would not be legs – only sticks of wood of considerably more complex. One possible trajectory in
such-and-such a length. Here, we have a building whose base Figure 1, for example, would be A to C to B to D. In this
and superstructure relate in the proper way. reading, the future looks considerably more open. There may
The conclusion to this line of thought (heretical to some indeed be functional alternatives to socialism – if indeed
Marxists) is that Capital is an analysis of the capitalist super- socialism as we have known it is compatible with developed
structure – the set of culturally specific and legally encoded forces.
meanings and practices that tend to stabilize capitalist relations
of production. In a comparative sense, this conclusion is crucial
since it sets capitalism on the same analytical plane as any other Conclusion
mode of production. On this view, the analysis of modes of
production becomes a matter of locating effective power The notion of a mode of production is a deliberate simplifi-
difference over material production as they are reflected in cation. It provides a model of certain central relationships that
differential control over the total social product and analyzing define epochal forms. As such, the analysis of modes of
the meanings and practices that tend to reproduce such powers production cannot substitute for the examination of particular
– what Antonio Gramsci called hegemonic culture. It goes cases in specific spatial and temporal contexts. In this sense,
without saying that it is always misleading to import the mode-of-production analyses do not constitute historical
cultural logic of one mode of production (such as capitalism) explanations.
into the understanding of others. In a larger sense, however, the concept of ways of producing
furnishes the necessary scaffolding without which local
historical explanation would be impossible. Comparison and
Functional Alternatives contrast, whether explicitly or implicitly carried out, depend
upon an overarching framework. This is what Marx’s notion of
If this reading of Marx’s notion of determination solves many modes of production provides: a way of understanding society
conceptual problems, it also creates others in the application of and history in the broadest terms.
Modes of Production 717

The present is once again a moment of deep crisis in world


See also: Marx, Karl (1818–83).
capitalism. Accordingly, it would not be surprising if the
social sciences produced another efflorescence of Marxist-
inspired ideas, but if so, it will unlikely do so in reference to
a comparative analysis of modes of production. After the
Bibliography
disintegration of the Soviet Union and the elimination of
Althusser, L., Balibar, E., 1970. Reading Capital (B. Brewster, Trans.). Pantheon,
socialism as a world model, nothing remains but capitalism.
New York.
In 1968, it was possible at least to imagine large parts of the Anderson, P., 1974a. Lineages of the Absolutist State. New Left Books, London.
earth as ‘noncapitalist,’ but now there is, for the first time in Anderson, P., 1974b. Passages from Antiquity to Feudalism. New Left Books, London.
human history, one truly globalized world capitalist system. Aston, T.H., Philpin, C.H.E. (Eds.), 1985. The Brenner Debate: Agrarian Class Structure
Deepening the analysis of the present will require taking into and Economic Development in Pre-industrial Europe. Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge, UK.
account what was learned in the 1970s: namely, that capi- Cohen, G.A., 1978. Karl Marx’s Theory of History: A Defence. Clarendon Press,
talism is no more ‘economic’ than other modes of production Oxford, UK.
and no less dependent upon a series of culturally peculiar Donham, D.L., 1999. History, Power, Ideology: Central Issues in Marxism and
ideas. Once the analysis of modes of production is truly Anthropology, second ed. University of California Press, Berkeley, CA.
Kahn, J.S., Llobera, J.R. (Eds.), 1981. The Anthropology of Pre-capitalist Societies.
leveled in this respect, we will have a more powerful
Macmillan, London.
approach to capitalism itself, one that does not naturalize Moore, S., 1980. Marx on the Choice between Socialism and Communism. Harvard
capitalist culture. University Press, Cambridge, MA.

Вам также может понравиться