Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 22

C ONTRACT F ARMING AND F OOD S ECURITY

M ARC F. B ELLEMARE AND L INDSEY N OVAK

Contract farming has often been associated with an increase in the income of participating house-
holds. It is unclear, however, whether contract farming increases other aspects of household welfare.
We use data from six regions of Madagascar and a selection-on-observables design in which we con-
trol for a household’s marginal utility of participating in contract farming, which we elicited via a
contingent valuation experiment, to show that participating in contract farming reduces the duration
of a household’s hungry season by about eight days on average. Moreover, participation in contract

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ajae/article-abstract/99/2/357/2632247 by guest on 03 July 2020


farming makes participating households about 18% more likely to see their hungry season end at
any time. Further, we find that these effects are more pronounced for households with more children,
and for households with more girls. This is an important result as children—especially girls—often
bear the burden of food insecurity.

Key words: Contract farming, outgrower schemes, grower-processor contracts, agricultural value
chains, food security.
JEL codes: L24, O13, O14, Q12.

Although the benefits of economic specializa- two crops for sale—is the emergence of an in-
tion have been widely understood since the termediate sector between the agricultural
publication of Adam Smith’s 1776 Wealth of and manufacturing sectors. The institution
Nations (1976), if not earlier, a persistent lack that perhaps best represents the emergence
of specialization is one of the prime factors en- of such an agro-industrial sector is contract
abling economic underdevelopment in most of farming, or the economic institution wherein
the world’s poorest countries. In such coun- a processing firm contracts the production of
tries, whose economies remain largely agrar- commercial crops out to smallholder farmers;
ian, the structural transformation, or transition this institution is the cornerstone of agricul-
from subsistence to commercial agriculture, tural value chains. In one of the earliest stud-
has so far proven elusive. ies of contract farming in economics, Grosh
One of the first steps in the transition from (1994) noted that this institution can resolve
subsistence to commercial agriculture—that several market failures that result from risk
is, the transition from many smallholder and uncertainty, imperfect factor markets,
farmers producing small quantities of several and reluctance to adopt new technology.
crops for home consumption to fewer large Since then, contract farming has been studied
farms producing large quantities of one or in many countries and across many crops, and
policy makers have often hailed the institu-
tion as a tool for rural poverty alleviation.
Bellemare is an associate professor in the Department of
But does participation in agricultural value
Applied Economics and Director, Center for International Food chains make people better off? Although an
and Agricultural Policy, University of Minnesota. Novak is a important body of literature explores the ef-
PhD candidate in the Department of Applied Economics,
University of Minnesota. The authors are grateful to the
fects of participation in contract farming on
National Institute of Food and Agriculture for funding this work household income or some variant thereof
through grant MIN-14-061, “Smallholder Participation in (Porter and Phillips-Howard 1997; Singh
Agricultural Value Chains: Evidence from Madagascar.” The au-
thors thank Teevrat Garg for invaluable help getting the data or- 2002; Warning and Key 2002; Simmons 2005;
ganized. We also thank Benjamin Wood, Ali Hill, Travis Maertens and Swinnen 2009; Minten,
Lybbert, Matthieu Stigler, two anonymous reviewers, seminar Randrianarison, and Swinnen 2009; Miyata,
participants at Cornell, as well as participants at the 2014 AAEA
annual meetings, the 2014 POLICOFA conference in Dar es Minot, and Hu 2009; Rao and Qaim 2011;
Salaam, and the 2015 CSAE conference at Oxford for comments Barrett et al. 2012; Bellemare 2012;
and suggestions that made for a much-improved manuscript. All
remaining errors are ours. Correspondence to be sent to:
Michelson 2013; Narayanan 2014), we study
mbellema@umn.edu. whether participation in contract farming

Amer. J. Agr. Econ. 99(2): 357–378; doi: 10.1093/ajae/aaw053


Published online July 28, 2016
C The Authors 2016. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the Agricultural and Applied Economics
V
Association. All rights reserved. For permissions, please e-mail: journals.permissions@oup.com.
358 March 2017 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

improves food security, defined here as the Discussions have incorporated think-
reported duration of the hungry season expe- ing around value chain frameworks,
rienced by a household, that is, the length of which emerged in the late 1990s to
time during which one member of the house- help development actors design in-
hold or more goes without three meals a terventions that responded to the
day.1,2,3 This question is important for three needs of the private sector and con-
reasons. First, because the hungry season co- tributed to development outcomes.
incides with those months before households Value chain approaches can provide
obtain cash for their crops (both contracted useful frameworks to examine the
and not contracted) at harvest, it is not imme- food system and the potential to
diately obvious that the households involved achieve improved nutritional out-

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ajae/article-abstract/99/2/357/2632247 by guest on 03 July 2020


in contract farming can or will save the extra comes by leveraging market-based
income from contract farming (Dupas and systems (Gelli et al. 2015).
Robinson 2013); there is value in knowing
whether income gains translate into other Using a sample of 1,200 households that
gains.4 Second, self-control problems are covers more than 10 contracted crops across
more common among the poor and those six regions of Madagascar, we look at whether
who live “at the margin” (Banerjee and participation in contract farming appears to
Mullainathan 2010), and it is not clear decrease the reported length of the hungry
whether the cash a household receives at har- season experienced by households.5 Because a
vest will be spent on necessities like food. household’s decision to participate in contract
Third, as a recent International Food Policy farming is likely to be jointly determined with
Research Institute discussion paper put it: the reported duration of the hungry season ex-
perienced by the same household, we use the
Income growth alone cannot solve results of a field experiment aimed at eliciting
the problem of malnutrition. . . The respondent willingness to pay (WTP) to par-
challenge from the nutrition perspec- ticipate in contract farming. We then use this
tive is how to sustainably improve WTP variable to help disentangle the poten-
the quality of diets, as well as other tial causal relationship flowing from participa-
health-nutrition related behaviors, tion in contract farming to the reported
across different populations and age duration of the hungry season from the corre-
groups? (sic) In nutrition debates in lation between the two. We first use this WTP
developing countries there is grow- information in a regression context for a
ing interest in the capacity of the selection-on-observables design (Angrist and
private sector to contribute to im- Pischke 2009). We then use this WTP informa-
proved nutrition outcomes. . . tion in hazard and duration models in order to
estimate likelihood of the household exiting
the hungry season. Finally, we use this WTP
1
information to estimate average treatment ef-
There are two notable exceptions. Dedehouanou, Swinnen,
and Maertens (2013) look at the impact of contracting on the fects using propensity score matching meth-
subjective well-being of farmers in Senegal. Montalbano, ods, since the same assumption that makes the
Pietrelli, and Salvatici (2015) study various levels of participation selection-on-observables design possible also
in the agricultural supply chain and food security, but their study
does not specifically address or identify households that partici- makes the conditional independence assump-
pate in contract farming.
2
tion likely to hold. Our work thus represents a
This is undoubtedly only one aspect of food security. Ideally
we would have additional measures of food security such as each
dual departure from Bellemare (2012), who
household member’s consumption of calories, macronutrients, uses the same data set and a similar identifica-
and micronutrients. This would require detailed information at tion strategy to study the welfare impacts of
the individual level. The data used in this analysis were not col-
lected for the specific purpose of measuring food security and contract farming. First, we look at food (in)se-
thus do not include such detailed consumption information.
3
curity rather than income as our outcome of
Because some of the households in our data experienced two interest. Second, we use WTP for contract
hungry seasons, each respondent was asked in which month (and
when during that month, i.e., beginning, middle, or end) each epi- farming as a control in a selection-on-
sode of hungry season began, and in which months (and when observables design to obtain an average treat-
during that month) each episode ended. We define “reported du-
ration of the hungry season” as the sum of those two episodes of
ment effect rather than as an instrumental
hungry season for each household, measured in months.
4
The contracts we study in this paper take place during the
main agricultural season in Madagascar. Consequently, it is al-
5
ways the case in the data that people get paid for their contracted Supplementary online appendix table A12 describes what
crops immediately after the hungry season ends. the primary contracted crops are for each region in our sample.
Bellemare and Novak Contract Farming and Food Security 359

variable in a two-stage least squares design to Ordinary Least Squares and Duration
obtain a local average treatment effect. Models
Our core regression results suggest that par- The core equation we estimate is
ticipation in contract farming decreases the re-
ported duration of the hungry season by ð1Þ yi ¼ a1 þ b1 xi þ c1 Di þ ei
approximately eight days (i.e., 0.28 months)
for the average household in our data; propen- where yi  0 is the reported duration of the
sity score matching results are largely consis- hungry season experienced by household i
tent with those regression results. Our hazard measured in months, xi is a vector of control
and duration model results suggest that partic- variables (which, in a slight abuse of notation,
ipation in contract farming increases the likeli- also includes district dummies), Di is a vari-

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ajae/article-abstract/99/2/357/2632247 by guest on 03 July 2020


hood that a household’s hungry season will able equal to one if household i participates
end at any given time by about 18%. in contract farming and equal to zero other-
In addition, an exploratory analysis indi- wise, and ei is an error term with a mean of
cates that the beneficial effects of participation zero.6
in contract farming are more pronounced (a) We are primarily interested in the coeffi-
the greater the number of children, and (b) cient c which, if D were exogenous to y,
the greater the number of female children in a would be the average treatment effect (ATE)
participant household. This is important be- of participating in contract farming on the re-
cause children—especially girls—are often the ported duration of the hungry season, or
ones who bear the burden of food insecurity
given unequal intrahousehold allocations of
ð2Þ c ¼ E½yi jDi ¼ 1  E½yi jDi ¼ 0:
food, calories, and nutrients (Barrett 2002).
Longer reported hungry seasons—our mea-
The treatment variable D, however, is en-
sure of food insecurity—can cause wasting,
dogenous to y because household participa-
stunting, and a number of other health prob-
tion in contract farming is not assigned at
lems, and children who go hungry during their
random. Therefore, we estimate the following
developmental process are more likely to
version of equation 1:
have worse educational and health outcomes
later on in life (Alderman, Hoddinott, and
Kinsey 2006; Ruel and Alderman 2013). ð3Þ yi ¼ a2 þ b2 xi þ c2 Di þ d2 wi þ gi
The rest of this article is organized as fol-
lows. In the following section we discuss our where gi is an error term with a mean of zero,
empirical framework and present the details and wi is a vector of dummy variables that
of our estimation and identification strate- captures our respondents’ answers to an ex-
gies. We then present the data and some de- perimental question aimed at eliciting WTP
scriptive statistics, followed by a presentation to participate in a hypothetical contract farm-
and discussion of our empirical results, as ing agreement. Our claim is that this WTP
well as their limitations. We conclude by dis- proxies for each respondent’s marginal utility
cussing the implications of our work for fu- of participating in contract farming, which in
ture research and for policy. turn controls for a number of unobservable
characteristics that explain selection into con-
tract farming. We thus attempt to identify the
Empirical Framework ATE of participating in contract farming on
the reported duration of the hungry season
This section first presents the estimation strat- using a selection-on-observables design, in
egy we use to study the impact of participation which a coefficient is identified because the
in contract farming on the reported duration of right-hand side variables (here, x and w) ac-
the hungry season (defined here as the number count for selection into a given treatment
of months during which at least one member (here, D).
of the household goes without three meals a Because we are dealing with duration
day) experienced by the households in our data—that is, the left-hand-side (LHS) vari-
data. Then, because the reported duration of able measures the reported number of
the hungry season experienced by a household
is likely endogenous to its participation in con-
tract farming, we explain the details of the 6
Boldface type is used throughout this paper to denote
identification strategy we rely on. vectors.
360 March 2017 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

months a household’s most recent hungry consider two things. The first is the number
season lasted—we use three distinct estima- of non-participating households to match to
tors to estimate equation (3). The first is the participating households. When matching
ordinary least squares (OLS) estimator, with replacement, matching only one house-
wherein c tells us how much shorter the hun- hold raises the likelihood that the two
gry season is, on average, for households that matched households are very similar.
participate in contract farming. The next two Increasing the number of matched house-
estimators are the Cox proportional hazards holds can decrease the similarity between
model and the survival time regression matched households but increase the pool of
model, two workhorse estimators used in the households upon which we draw inferences.
study of duration data (Lancaster 1992).7 In The second important consideration is the

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ajae/article-abstract/99/2/357/2632247 by guest on 03 July 2020


these two models, c tells us how likely a caliper size, which determines how similar
household is to “exit” the condition repre- two households’ propensity scores must be in
sented by the hungry season at any given order for the corresponding households to be
point in time. Thus, if participation in con- matched. If the caliper size is large, it is possi-
tract farming has the hypothesized beneficial ble to match households with very dissimilar
effects on food security, we would expect c < propensity scores. If the caliper is very small,
0 in the OLS specifications (i.e., contract it becomes difficult to find suitable matches,
farming is associated with shorter reported and thus a large portion of observations will
hungry seasons), and c > 0 in the Cox propor- be dropped from the sample, and the stan-
tional hazards and survival time regression dard errors become inflated.
models (i.e., contract farming is associated To address these trade-offs we use three
with a higher likelihood of exiting the hungry routines to match households, matching with
season at any point in time). replacements: (a) one nearest neighbor with
a caliper size of 0.01 standard deviation; (b)
three nearest neighbors with a caliper size of
Propensity Score Matching 0.01 standard deviation; and (c) three nearest
neighbors with a caliper size of 0.001 stan-
Propensity score matching (PSM) is a valu- dard deviation. We then estimate three treat-
able estimation strategy in the case of selec- ment effects: (a) the average treatment effect
tion on observables (Imbens 2015). on the treated (ATT); (b) the average treat-
Therefore, we use PSM as an additional esti- ment effect on the untreated (ATU); and (c)
mator in an effort to assess the robustness of the average treatment effect (ATE). The
our findings. In the first stage, we estimate a ATT is standard reporting for propensity
probit model such that score matching and tells us how treated
households are affected by their participation
ð4Þ Di ¼ j þ kxi þ hwi þ ni in contract farming. The ATE is the same es-
timator that is reported in our OLS estimates,
where the variables are labeled the same as and is thus of greatest interest here. One
in equation (3). would expect the ATT to be the largest, in
The parameters of this model are then absolute value, followed by the ATE, and
used to estimate the propensity score for then ATU, since those who are likely to ben-
each individual. The propensity score is an efit the most from contract farming are also
estimate of each household’s likelihood of more likely to select into participation.
participation in contract farming, given its
observable characteristics and the respon- Identification Strategy
dent’s answer to the WTP question.
We then match households that participate As discussed, we rely on a selection-on-
in contract farming to households that do observables identification strategy in order to
not participate in contract farming but have estimate the impact of participation in contract
similar propensity scores. In selecting a farming on the reported duration of the hungry
matching algorithm it is important to season. This section first explains the experi-
mental setup we used to elicit WTP to partici-
pate in contract farming. It then explains how
7
The survival time regression requires that one make an as- WTP for contract farming should purge the er-
sumption on the distribution of the survival function. We make
the common assumption that the survival function follows a ror term g of much of its correlation with the
Weibull distribution throughout this article. variables on the right-hand side of equation (3).
Bellemare and Novak Contract Farming and Food Security 361

The contingent valuation experiment used respondent is asked whether he would partic-
in this article is the same as that used in ipate in a contract farming agreement costing
Bellemare (2012). Each respondent was $62.50, we have coded all other amounts,
asked whether he would participate in a con- $12.50, $25.00, $37.50, $50.00, and $75.00, as
tract farming agreement that would raise his “No.” In order to remedy this shortcoming,
income by 10% in exchange for a one-time in an additional set of estimations we enforce
monetary investment. The amount of the monotonic switching on the part of our re-
monetary investment was randomly selected spondents. That is, if a respondent answers
from six investment amounts of $12.50, “Yes” to participating in the hypothetical
$25.00, $37.50, $50.00, $62.50, or $75.00.8 contract farming agreement for a given ran-
The size of investment was determined at domly selected investment value, we code all

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ajae/article-abstract/99/2/357/2632247 by guest on 03 July 2020


random by the throw of a regular (i.e., six- lower investment values as “Yes” responses.
sided and fair) die. To put these six invest- Even with this modification, our measure of
ment amounts in context, consider that the WTP is a lower bound on respondents’ actual
average household annual income for house- WTP to participate in a contract farming
holds in our sample is approximately $968. agreement.
Thus, these investment amounts range be- In a final set of results, we impute, on the
tween 1.3% and 7.7% of average household basis of observables, what each respondent’s
annual income. answers would be to all investment ques-
For each respondent, the data include the tions.9 So a respondent who rolls a five on the
random dollar amount associated with the die throw and responds “Yes,” meaning that
roll of the die and a “Yes” or “No” answer to he would like to participate in a contract
whether the respondent would pay an initial farming agreement that would raise his in-
investment equal to the random dollar come by 10%, but would require him to pay
amount in order to participate in a contract an initial cost of $62.50, would have a w vec-
farming agreement that would increase his in- tor equal to (w^ 1, w
^ 2, w
^ 3, w
^ 4 , 1, w
^ 6 ), where w
^i
come by 10%. denotes an imputed value in the ith position.
The vector w in equation (3) captures re- Because the level of investment required of
spondent answers to the WTP question. each respondent (i.e., $12.50, $25.00, $37.50,
Thus, in contrast to Bellemare (2012), who $50.00, $62.50, or $75.00) was determined at
uses WTP as an instrumental variable in a random as part of the experiment, the level
two-state least squares setup, we use WTP as of investment is unrelated to a respondent’s
a control variable in a selection-on- observable and unobservable characteristics,
observables design. For example, a respon- which means that the imputed responses to
dent who rolls a five on the die throw would the unasked questions are unbiased. The
be asked whether he would like to participate shortcoming of this approach is that it relies
in a contract farming agreement that would on generated regressors; we deal with this is-
raise his income by 10%, but would require sue by bootstrapping the standard errors
him to pay an initial investment of $62.50. whenever we include imputed variables as
If he answered “Yes,” his w vector would regressors.
be equal to (w1 , w2 ; w3 ; w4 ; w5 ; w6 ) ¼ (0,0,0, In all cases, the identifying assumption we
0,1,0). A respondent who rolls a four on the make is that a respondent’s answer to the
die throw would be asked whether he would WTP question is correlated with his WTP to
like to participate in a contract farming participate in contract farming, and so the vec-
agreement that would raise his income by tor w serves as a proxy for a respondent’s mar-
10%, but would cost $50.00. If he answered ginal utility from participating in contract
“No,” his w vector would be equal to
(0,0,0,0,0,0).
Note that the foregoing ascribes a “No” an- 9
swer to all questions that a respondent was We do those imputations by running a linear regression for
each of w1 , . . ., w6 on all the control variables (i.e., the variables
not asked. In the example above in which the in x) in equation 1. Whenever an observation is missing for a de-
pendent variable, we replace it with its predicted value from that
dependent variable’s imputing regression. For example, if an ob-
servation is missing for w2 , we replace that observation with w ^ 2,
which is equal to the respondent’s values in x multiplied by the
relevant estimated coefficients from the aforementioned linear
8
The U.S. dollar figures were expressed in local currency dur- regression. We leave nonmissing values the same. Thus, in a
ing fieldwork so respondents could more easily relate to the slight abuse of notation, the variables w ^ 6 are mixtures of
^ 1 , . . ., w
amounts. observed and imputed (or predicted) values.
362 March 2017 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

farming. The next section explains why this be more likely to participate in contract farm-
constitutes a selection-on-observables re- ing. This would compromise the identification
search design in the context of regression or, of the ATE, and it could definitely be a con-
alternatively, why it satisfies the conditional cern in our application given that households
independence assumption in the context of with better access to food may be more will-
matching. ing to enter into contract farming agree-
ments. It should be the case, however, that a
Identification respondent who is more willing to enter into
a contract farming agreement because he is
How does a set of proxies for a respon- more food secure will have a higher marginal
dent’s marginal utility from participating in utility of participating in contract farming.

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ajae/article-abstract/99/2/357/2632247 by guest on 03 July 2020


contract farming help identify the causal im- Our WTP measure controls for this issue
pact of participation in contract farming on much as it did for other changes in prefer-
the reported duration of the hungry season? ences, which should alleviate concerns about
There are three sources of statistical endoge- reverse causality.
neity: unobserved heterogeneity, reverse cau- Finally, measurement error refers to the
sality, and measurement error. We look at statistical endogeneity problem that arises
each of these in turn in the remainder of this from there being measurement error in
section. whether a household participates in contract
Unobserved heterogeneity refers to the farming. This is highly unlikely to be a prob-
problem of omitted variables such as a re- lem in our application given that there is no
spondent’s preferences for risk and ambigu- obvious advantage or disadvantage to misre-
ity, his entrepreneurial ability, his technical porting whether or not one participates in
ability, and his preferences in general, all of contract farming. In addition, the sample was
which can compromise the identification of choice-based, that is, the survey team aimed
the ATE if they happen to be correlated with for a sample in which one-half of the respon-
both the reported duration of the hungry sea- dents participated in contract farming and
son and any of the variables on the right-hand the other half did not, and the sampling
side of equation 1. In this application, a great frame was established with village chiefs, who
deal of this unobserved heterogeneity can be know who participated in contract farming
captured by differences in a respondent’s and who did not. This sampling strategy thus
marginal utility from participation in contract served as a consistency check for whether
farming. Take, for example, a respondent people truly did participate in contract
who is price risk averse (Bellemare, Barrett, farming.
and Just (2013)). Such a respondent might In sum, our identification strategy allows us
prefer to participate in contract farming be- to rule out a number of sources of bias that
cause such arrangements typically insure plague the identification of a causal effect in
growers against price risk. Alternatively, a re- this context. Because we are dealing with ob-
spondent who is very entrepreneurial might servational data, however, it is impossible to
have little to no use for contract farming rule out all sources of statistical endogeneity
given that she has her own micro-enterprise. with certainty. As a result, we caution the
Such a respondent might prefer not to partici- reader against interpreting our estimate of c
pate in contract farming because of the op- as causal, although it can certainly be inter-
portunity cost of time associated with being preted as suggestive of the effect of participa-
in a grower-processor contract. In all such tion in contract farming on the reported
cases where a respondent’s marginal utility duration of the hungry season experienced by
from participating in contract farming varies grower households.
because of some omitted variable, the varia-
tion in WTP measure captures the variation
in respondent marginal utility, which should
largely obviate concerns about unobserved Data and Descriptive Statistics
heterogeneity between respondents.
Reverse causality refers to the statistical The data used in this article are the same as
endogeneity problem that arises from the fact in Bellemare (2012), and this section neces-
that the dependent variable might cause the sarily echoes the discussion of the same data
variable of interest. In this case, households in that article. The data were collected be-
that experience a shorter hungry season may tween July and December of 2008 for a study
Bellemare and Novak Contract Farming and Food Security 363

of contract farming commissioned by the and though the piece rate paid to growers by
World Bank. The data cover six regions and processors tends to be fixed, there was one
two communes per region. Three of these re- processor in particular that paid a floating (i.
gions were chosen because they exhibited a e., market conditions-driven) piece rate.
relatively high prevalence of contract farm- Most processors are Malagasy companies,
ing; the other three were chosen because the with the notable exception of Sodexo, a
government of Madagascar viewed them as French company that is perhaps best known
high-priority areas for economic develop- for operating cafeterias in universities, hospi-
ment. In all regions, the two communes with tals, and other workplaces.
the highest density of contract farming were We present descriptive statistics for our
surveyed. Commune-level data were ob- sample in table 1, broken down by whether

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ajae/article-abstract/99/2/357/2632247 by guest on 03 July 2020


tained from the 2007 census of communes in or not households participate in contract
Madagascar; Moser (2008) presents the meth- farming, along with balancing tests. The aver-
odology used for the commune census. age reported duration of the hungry season—
Within each of the 12 communes, two lists the number of months during which members
were generated: one was a list of all house- of the household go without three meals per
holds that participated in contract farming, day, that is, our proxy for food insecurity—
the other was a list of all households that did for the households in our sample is 3.7
not. Then, 50 households were randomly se- months for households that do not participate
lected from the list of households that partici- in contract farming versus 3.3 months for
pated in contract farming, and 50 were households that do. Approximately half of
randomly selected from the list of households the surveyed households participate in con-
that did not. We use sampling weights repre- tract farming (not shown in table 1). The av-
sentative at the commune level throughout erage household has between five and six
this article to account for this choice-based members, and almost half of the individuals
sampling (Manski and Lerman 1977), and to in any given household are dependents, that
bring our sample as close as possible to a ran- is, they are either younger than 15, or older
dom sample. than 65. The average household head is mar-
The survey was conducted in rural areas of ried and male, but is more likely to be female
Madagascar, and almost all (96%) of the and single among households that do not par-
households in our sample derived at least ticipate in contract farming. The average
some of their income from agricultural activi- household head is 43 years old, with a small,
ties. For each household, data were collected statistically significant difference between the
at the household, plot, crop, and contract heads of households that participate in con-
level. Households were asked to recall events tract farming (42 years old on average) and
from the 12 months prior to the survey. the heads of households that do not (44 years
Before discussing the data used in this arti- old). The average household head has almost
cle, we briefly discuss the nature of the six years of education, and has over 20 years
contract farming agreements we are studying. of agricultural experience. Almost 30% of
Supplementary online appendix Table A1 household heads are members of a farm orga-
lists the primary contracted crops by region. nization other than a contract farming organi-
Many of those crops are food staples— zation among households that do participate
especially rice in the context of Madagascar, in contract farming, a proportion that falls by
but also maize and barley—which might play half for those households that do not partici-
a role in enhancing the food security of con- pate in contract farming. The average house-
tract farming participants, a speculation we hold head is forbidden from doing
return to below when discussing mechanisms. agricultural work for more than 20 days per
The contract farming agreements in our data year for religious reasons.10
take many shapes, from the processor provid-
ing no seeds, pesticides, and fertilizer (both
organic and chemical), to the processor pro-
10
viding all of those, with several scenarios in The Malagasy observe a system of taboos and interdictions
that dictate everything from the orientation of buildings to what
between. Likewise, contracts can be both a person may eat. Those taboos tend to vary at several levels, be-
signed between the processor and an individ- tween individuals, households, villages, ethnic groups, and so on.
ual grower or between the processor and a See Ruud (1960) for a thorough treatment, and Stifel,
Fafchamps, and Minten (2007) for an investigation of the effects
group of growers. Contracts are written more of days on which agricultural work is forbidden on agricultural
often than not, but they can also be verbal; productivity.
364 March 2017 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

Table 1. Descriptive Statistics by Participation Regime and Balance Tests


Participates in
Contract Farming?
Variables No Yes Diff.

Duration of hungry season 3.696 3.316 ***


(Months) (0.109) (0.105)
Household size 5.452 5.692 **
(Individuals) (0.108) (0.104)
Dependency ratio 0.452 0.446

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ajae/article-abstract/99/2/357/2632247 by guest on 03 July 2020


(0.012) (0.010)
Household head single 0.158 0.089 ***
(Dummy) (0.017) (0.014)
Household head female 0.119 0.057 ***
(Dummy) (0.016) (0.011)
Household head migrant 0.124 0.125
(Dummy) (0.015) (0.015)
Household head age 44.428 42.110 **
(Years) (0.652) (0.554)
Household head education 5.650 5.715
(Years) (0.154) (0.147)
Household head agricultural experience 21.074 20.165
(Years) (0.653) (0.566)
Household head member of farm org. 0.149 0.296 ***
(Dummy) (0.017) (0.022)
Days agricultural work forbidden 23.968 20.427
(Days/year) (1.684) (1.424)
Household income 14.843 24.255 ***
(100,000 ariary) (1.198) (2.762)
Household working capital 2.872 6.021 ***
(100,000 ariary) (0.380) (0.973)
Household assets 11.672 16.277 ***
(100,000 ariary) (1.099) (1.359)
Household landholdings 113.438 177.956 ***
(100 square meters) (8.982) (18.146)
Children in the Household 2.502 2.654
(Number of children) (1.791) (1.697)
Male children in the household 1.256 1.367
(Number of children) (1.181) (1.245)
Female children in the household 1.246 1.287
(Number of children) (1.223) (1.101)
"Yes" to $12.50 investment 0.129 0.135
(Dummy) (0.015) (0.016)
"Yes" to $25.00 investment 0.173 0.185
(Dummy) (0.018) (0.018)
"Yes" to $37.50 investment 0.142 0.172
(Dummy) (0.016) (0.018)
"Yes" to $50.00 investment 0.117 0.150 **
(Dummy) (0.015) (0.016)
"Yes" to $62.50 investment 0.065 0.073
(Dummy) (0.012) (0.013)
"Yes" to $75.00 investment 0.047 0.085
(Dummy) (0.009) (0.013)
Observations 599 579
Note: Standard errors appear in parentheses. Asterisks denote the following: ***¼ p < 0.01, **¼ p < 0.05, and * ¼ p < 0.1.
Bellemare and Novak Contract Farming and Food Security 365

Average household annual income—that confounding factors in the decision to partici-


is, a household’s cash income from selling an- pate in contract farming, it merely displays
imals and animal byproducts, wage labor, the relationship between contract farming
nonagricultural activities, leases (land, cattle, and the reported duration of the hungry sea-
and equipment rentals), sales of non- son. Thus, we then present parametric evi-
contracted crops, and contract farming—is dence using the selection-on-observables
approximately $968 per year with an average regression methodology discussed in the
per capita income of $174.11 There are sharp empirical framework section, as well as pro-
differences in income between contract farm- pensity score matching methods. We then, in
ing participants and nonparticipants, with the an exploratory analysis, look at treatment
former type of household seeing its income heterogeneity, first by determining whether

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ajae/article-abstract/99/2/357/2632247 by guest on 03 July 2020


almost 65% higher than the latter type, on the effects of participation in contract farm-
average. In Madagascar in 2008, GDP per ing on food security are more pronounced for
capita was $468, meaning households in our households with more children, and second
sample were significantly poorer than the na- by looking at whether the effects of participa-
tional average. The average household owns tion in contract farming on food security are
about $220 worth of agricultural equipment more pronounced for households with more
and tools, but contract farming participants girls. We then discuss the results of a number
own about twice as much as nonparticipants. of robustness checks, and conclude this sec-
Likewise, the average household owns about tion by discussing the limitations of our
$700 in other assets such as a house, TV, ra- approach.
dio, and livestock, but the value of contract
farming participants’ assets is significantly
higher. Similarly, households that do partici-
Nonparametric Evidence
pate in contract farming own significantly
more land than those that do not. We begin with nonparametric estimations of
Lastly, table 1 displays the results of the the relationship between contract farming
WTP contingent valuation experiment. As and the reported duration of the hungry sea-
expected, the proportion of respondents who son in order to establish whether a relation-
are willing to participate in contract farming ship exists between participation in contract
generally declines as the investment required farming and food security. Kaplan-Meier
grows, except for an initial bump between (i.e., nonparametric) estimates of the survival
$12.50 and $25.00.12 functions for households that participate in
contract farming and households that do not
are displayed in figure 1. These estimates
Empirical Results show that contract farming participants are
more likely to exit the hungry season earlier
than non-participants.
We begin this section by presenting nonpara-
metric evidence of the relationship between
participation in contract farming and re- Kaplan-Meier Estimates
1.00

ported duration of the hungry season experi-


enced by households. This nonparametric
Proportion of Households

relationship does not account for


0.75
0.50

11
USD 1  2,000 Ariary at the time the data were collected.
12
Such idiosyncrasies are conceivable given the random as-
0.25

signment to which investment level respondents are asked to pay


to participate in the hypothetical contract farming agreement.
We conducted a series of balance tests and find that the majority
0.00

of our explanatory variables are balanced across the groups of


households asked if they would invest the six different invest- 0 2 4 6 8 10
ment amounts. The few exceptions are that respondents who Duration of Hungry Season (Months)
rolled a one on the dice, and were consequently asked if they
were willing to invest $12.50 in order to participate in the hypo- CF Nonparticipant CF Participant
thetical contract farming agreement, were slightly more likely to
have a household head that is single, female, and less likely to be Figure 1. Kaplan-Meier estimates of the ef-
a member of a farm organization—three variables that are highly
correlated with one another—than respondents whom we asked fect of participation in contract farming (CF)
about other investment amounts. on the duration of the hungry season
366 March 2017 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

Distribution of Hungry Season Duration those variables. Before discussing the results
in table 2, however, we discuss the results of
.2

Hausman tests aimed at determining whether


.15

our variable of interest—the contract farming


dummy—is endogenous. The first of these
Density
.1

tests compares the OLS results in tables 2a


and 2b under the null that both sets of coeffi-
.05

cients (for those variables common to both


tables) are identical. In this case, the
0

0 5 10 Hausman test has a p-value of 0.98, which


Duration of Hungry Season
supports the null of exogeneity. For the sec-

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ajae/article-abstract/99/2/357/2632247 by guest on 03 July 2020


Does Not Participate in CF
Participates in CF ond Hausman test, we begin by running the
kernel = epanechnikov, bandwidth = 1.0000
first-stage regression (not shown) of the con-
tract farming dummy on all control variables
Figure 2. Kernel density estimates of the du- and the WTP dummies. The error term from
ration of the hungry season by contract farm- this first-stage regression is then incorporated
ing participation status as an additional regressor in equation (2).
The coefficient on the residual of the first-
stage regression is the object of the test, with
Similarly, figure 2 displays kernel density the null hypothesis being that the contract
estimates of the distribution of the reported farming dummy is exogenous to the reported
number of months spent in the hungry season duration of the hungry season. Once again we
for households that participate in contract fail to reject the null, and the t-test has a p-
farming and households that do not. value of 0.49. But even given the foregoing,
Consistent with the results in table 1, house- for the remainder of this article we focus on
holds that participate in contract farming re- results where we control for respondent WTP
port that they experience a shorter hungry to participate in contract farming by includ-
season than those that do not participate. ing WTP as a regressor. We do so both be-
Both figures suggest there is a relationship cause a failure to reject the null in a
between a household participating in contract Hausman test is rarely convincing when argu-
farming and a shorter hungry season reported ing that a certain variable is exogenous, and
by that same household, but neither figure because the WTP dummies are jointly signifi-
can help ascertain whether that relationship cant in the OLS specification in the first col-
is causal. In order to disentangle the potential umn of table 2b.
causal relationship between contract farming Assuming that a month lasts 30 days on av-
and food security, we now turn to parametric erage, the OLS results in table 2b suggest
evidence. that participating in contract farming is asso-
ciated with an eight-day decrease (0.277
Ordinary Least Squares and Duration Models months  30 days per month) in the reported
duration of the hungry season. Similarly, the
We now estimate the relationship between Cox proportional hazards and survival time
participation in contract farming and re- regression estimation results, respectively,
ported duration of the hungry season using suggest that a household that participates in
the estimation and identification strategies contract farming is 17% and 19%, respec-
discussed in the estimation strategy section. tively, more likely to exit the hungry season
We account for the endogenous choice to at any given time than a household that does
participate in contract farming or not by us- not participate in contract farming.
ing proxy variables for respondents’ marginal Additionally, female-headed households ex-
utility. This proxy is derived from the contin- perience a hungry season that is about three
gent valuation field experiment to elicit will- weeks (0.73  30) longer than male-headed
ingness to pay to participate in contract households, and are 32% less likely to exit
farming. the hungry season at any given time, accord-
Table 2 presents two sets of OLS, Cox pro- ing to the Cox proportional hazards model,
portional hazards, and survival time regres- and 39% less likely to do so according to the
sion estimation results: table 2a omits the survival time regression. Likewise, an in-
variables capturing respondent answers to crease in a household head’s years of educa-
the WTP questions, whereas table 2b includes tion and his years of agricultural experience,
Bellemare and Novak Contract Farming and Food Security 367

Table 2a. Estimation Results for OLS, Cox Proportional Hazard, and Survival-time
Regressions Omitting WTP Variables
Variables OLS Cox Survival Time
Dependent Variable: Duration of Hungry Season
Contract farming participant 0.294** 0.150** 0.171**
(0.142) (0.062) (0.070)
Household size 0.050 0.011 0.013
(0.036) (0.015) (0.017)
Dependency ratio 0.576 0.254 0.286
(0.365) (0.157) (0.181)

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ajae/article-abstract/99/2/357/2632247 by guest on 03 July 2020


Household head single 0.078 0.051 0.082
(0.338) (0.148) (0.169)
Household head female 0.723* 0.339* 0.413**
(0.400) (0.176) (0.206)
Household head migrant 0.033 0.031 0.027
(0.216) (0.103) (0.118)
Household head age 0.024** 0.005 0.005
(0.009) (0.004) (0.005)
Household head education 0.069*** 0.020* 0.024**
(0.022) (0.010) (0.012)
Household head agricultural experience 0.032*** 0.006 0.006
(0.010) (0.004) (0.005)
Household head member of farm organization 0.104 0.111 0.147
(0.185) (0.089) (0.102)
Days agricultural work forbidden 0.003 0.000 0.000
(0.002) (0.001) (0.001)
Household income 0.004** 0.000 0.000
(0.002) (0.001) (0.002)
Household working capital 0.002 0.006*** 0.007***
(0.003) (0.002) (0.002)
Household assets 0.013*** 0.004*** 0.005***
(0.003) (0.001) (0.002)
Household landholdings 0.000 0.000 0.000
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
Constant 3.533*** 3.997***
(0.433) (0.246)
Observations 1,178 1,045 1,045
District dummies Yes Yes Yes
R-squared 0.197 – 0
Note: Robust standard errors appear in parentheses. Asterisks denote the following: ***¼ p < 0.01, **¼ p < 0.05, and *¼ p < 0.1.

as well as the value of the assets owned by his In an effort to identify the mechanism
household are all associated with a shorter through which participation in contract farm-
hungry season and a greater likelihood of ing might reduce the length of the hungry
exiting the hungry season at any given time. season (in the OLS specification) or increase
According to the OLS results, an increase in the likelihood of exiting the hungry season
household income in associated with a (in the Cox proportional hazards and survival
shorter hungry season, while income is statis- time regression specifications), we estimated
tically insignificant in the Cox proportional additional specifications (not shown) similar
hazards and survival time regression results. to those in table 2 but in which we include (a)
This lends credence to our claim that it is in- an additional control variable that measures
sufficient to infer nutritional outcomes based the proportion of all crops under contract
solely on income changes. Lastly, though the that are rice crops, or (b) an additional con-
contingent-valuation dummies are not indi- trol variable that measures the proportion of
vidually significant in any of the models pre- all crops under contract that are food crops.
sented in table 2, they are jointly significant Including those additional controls allows us
at less than the 10% level for the OLS model. to determine whether participation in
368 March 2017 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

Table 2b. Estimation Results for OLS, Cox Proportional Hazard, and Survival-time
Regressions Including WTP Variables
Variables OLS Cox Survival Time
Dependent Variable: Duration of Hungry Season
Contract farming participant 0.277* 0.166*** 0.188***
(0.145) (0.063) (0.071)
Household size 0.052 0.013 0.015
(0.036) (0.015) (0.017)
Dependency ratio 0.517 0.226 0.247
(0.366) (0.158) (0.181)

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ajae/article-abstract/99/2/357/2632247 by guest on 03 July 2020


Household head single 0.126 0.042 0.068
(0.343) (0.147) (0.167)
Household head female 0.732* 0.323* 0.390*
(0.402) (0.175) (0.202)
Household head migrant 0.064 0.014 0.009
(0.219) (0.101) (0.115)
Household head age 0.021** 0.003 0.003
(0.009) (0.004) (0.005)
Household head education 0.068*** 0.022** 0.026**
(0.022) (0.010) (0.011)
Household head agricultural experience 0.029*** 0.005 0.004
(0.010) (0.004) (0.005)
Household head member of farm organization 0.091 0.095 0.125
(0.183) (0.088) (0.100)
Days agricultural work forbidden 0.003 0.000 0.000
(0.002) (0.001) (0.001)
Household income 0.004** 0.000 0.000
(0.002) (0.001) (0.002)
Household working capital 0.002 0.006*** 0.007***
(0.003) (0.002) (0.002)
Household assets 0.013*** 0.004*** 0.005***
(0.003) (0.001) (0.002)
Household landholdings 0.000 0.000 0.000
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
"Yes" to $12.50 investment 0.218 0.033 0.027
(0.217) (0.095) (0.107)
"Yes" to $25.00 investment 0.396* 0.106 0.127
(0.226) (0.091) (0.104)
"Yes" to $37.50 investment 0.388* 0.126 0.147
(0.211) (0.097) (0.111)
"Yes" to $50.00 investment 0.205 0.018 0.017
(0.243) (0.112) (0.128)
"Yes" to $62.50 investment 0.142 0.004 0.006
(0.299) (0.136) (0.158)
"Yes" to $75.00 investment 0.151 0.226 0.234
(0.342) (0.169) (0.186)
Constant 3.793*** – 4.152***
(0.456) (0.256)
Observations 1,178 1,045 1,045
District dummies Yes Yes Yes
p-value (Joint significance of WTP dummies) 0.08 0.34 0.36
R-squared 0.206 – –
Note: Robust standard errors appear in parentheses. Asterisks denote the following: ***¼ p < 0.01, **¼ p < 0.05, and *¼ p < 0.1.

contract farming improves food security via leakage (whereby contract farming partici-
some sort of positive spillover (whereby con- pants might steal some of the crops they grow
tract farming participants become more pro- under contract in order to eat them). In no
ductive on their own food crops because they case was the coefficient on those interaction
grow food crops under contract) or via terms significant at less than the 10% level,
Bellemare and Novak Contract Farming and Food Security 369

which allows us to rule out those female children? Though our data do not al-
mechanisms. low us to determine the precise mechanism
behind these findings, it is not unlikely that
Treatment Heterogeneity because children—specifically girls—require
fewer calories, we may see that the addition
We now turn to treatment heterogeneity by of calories in the household creates a larger
number of children and by number of chil- reduction in the number of skipped meals for
dren of each gender in the household. Table households with more children. In other
3 shows estimation results for OLS, Cox pro- words, the marginal welfare impacts of partic-
portional hazards, and survival time regres- ipating in contract farming will be highest for
sion models in which the treatment variable children, specifically girls, and so it is not sur-

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ajae/article-abstract/99/2/357/2632247 by guest on 03 July 2020


(i.e., the dummy for whether a household prising that the effects of participation in con-
participates in contract farming) is interacted tract farming on food security would be
with the number of children in the household. especially pronounced for households with
Similarly, table 4 shows estimation results for more children and with more girls. To ex-
OLS, Cox proportional hazards, and survival plore this further, we estimated a specifica-
time regression models in which the treat- tion (not shown) in which we interacted the
ment variable (i.e., the dummy for whether a contract farming participation dummy with
household participates in contract farming) is gender-age categories (i.e., female children,
interacted with the number of children of male children, working-age women, working-
each gender in the household. Though the age men, elderly men, and elderly women).
WTP dummies are generally not individually The results from that regression show that
significant in any of the models presented in the estimated coefficients for those interac-
tables 3 and 4, they are jointly significant at tions are statistically significant and negative
less than the 10% level in the OLS models in for female children, male children, and el-
both tables 3 and 4. derly women, with the remainder being statis-
The results in table 3 show that participa- tically insignificant. Those results indicate
tion in contract farming is associated with that the beneficial effects of contract farming
greater decreases in the reported duration of on food security are especially pronounced
the hungry season the more children there for households with more kids of either gen-
are in the household. Specifically, for every der and more elderly women. Interestingly,
child in the household, the reported duration those are the groups that eat the least in a
of the hungry season decreases by about six typical developing-country household, so it is
days (-0.19 months  30 days per month) in perhaps not surprising that the food security
households that participate in contract farm- gains from participating in contract farming
ing, and the likelihood that the household come first from those groups. This supports
will exit the hungry season increases by 6% our hypothesis that it is easier to make food
and 7%, according to the Cox proportional security gains the more children and the
hazards and the survival time regression more girls there are in a given household,
model, respectively. simply because the marginal returns, in terms
Likewise, the results in table 4 show that of fewer skipped meals, to participating in
participation in contract farming is associated contract farming are higher among children
with greater decreases in the reported dura- and girls than among working-age adults. But
tion of the hungry season the more girls there given that our data do not allow us to study
are in the household. Specifically, for every how many meals each member of the house-
girl in the household, the reported duration hold consumes, this explanation is necessarily
of the hungry season decreases by about one tentative and speculative.
week (0.22 months  30 per month), and
the likelihood that the household will exit the Propensity Score Matching
hungry season increases by 12% and 14%, ac-
cording to the Cox proportional hazards and Table 5 displays the results from the probit
the survival time regression model, regression of participation in contract farm-
respectively. ing on household characteristics and our
Why would the beneficial effects of partici- measure of WTP to participate in contract
pation in contract farming be more pro- farming. Households with a younger house-
nounced for households with more children, hold head and households in which the head
and specifically for households with more is a member of a farm organization are more
370 March 2017 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

Table 3. Estimation Results for OLS, Cox Proportional Hazard, and Survival-time
Regressions Exploring Treatment Heterogeneity I
Variables OLS Cox Survival Time
Dependent Variable: Duration of Hungry Season
Contract Farming Participant 0.210 0.009 0.004
(0.253) (0.109) (0.125)
Contract farming participant x number of kids 0.191** 0.060* 0.070*
(0.082) (0.034) (0.039)
Number of kids in household 0.172 0.053 0.060
(0.121) (0.050) (0.057)

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ajae/article-abstract/99/2/357/2632247 by guest on 03 July 2020


Household sze 0.007 0.002 0.002
(0.059) (0.028) (0.032)
Dependency ratio 0.255 0.168 0.187
(0.583) (0.231) (0.259)
Household head single 0.164 0.056 0.085
(0.349) (0.150) (0.171)
Household head female 0.765* 0.330* 0.399*
(0.406) (0.176) (0.204)
Household head migrant 0.066 0.006 0.002
(0.219) (0.102) (0.115)
Household head age 0.024** 0.004 0.004
(0.010) (0.004) (0.005)
Household head education 0.068*** 0.022** 0.026**
(0.022) (0.010) (0.012)
Household head agricultural experience 0.029*** 0.004 0.003
(0.010) (0.004) (0.005)
Household head member of farm organization 0.087 0.088 0.115
(0.180) (0.086) (0.097)
Days agricultural work forbidden 0.003 0.000 0.001
(0.002) (0.001) (0.001)
Household income 0.004** 0.000 0.000
(0.002) (0.001) (0.002)
Household working capital 0.002 0.005*** 0.007***
(0.003) (0.002) (0.002)
Household assets 0.013*** 0.004*** 0.005***
(0.003) (0.001) (0.001)
Household landholdings 0.000 0.000 0.000
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
"Yes" to $12.50 investment 0.197 0.028 0.022
(0.217) (0.095) (0.107)
"Yes" to $25.00 investment 0.415* 0.107 0.126
(0.227) (0.091) (0.104)
"Yes" to $37.50 investment 0.372* 0.124 0.144
(0.211) (0.098) (0.112)
"Yes" to $50.00 investment 0.196 0.004 0.000
(0.238) (0.108) (0.124)
"Yes" to $62.50 investment 0.142 0.011 0.014
(0.291) (0.136) (0.157)
"Yes" to $75.00 investment 0.194 0.245 0.258
(0.341) (0.171) (0.188)
Constant 3.592*** – 4.078***
(0.487) (0.271)
Observations 1,178 1,045 1,045
District fixed effects Yes Yes Yes
R-squared 0.213 – –
Note: Robust standard errors appear in parentheses. Asterisks denote the following: ***¼ p < 0.01, **¼ p < 0.05, and *¼ p < 0.1.
Bellemare and Novak Contract Farming and Food Security 371

Table 4. Estimation Results for OLS, Cox Proportional Hazard, and Survival-Time
Regressions Exploring Treatment Heterogeneity II
Variables OLS Cox Survival Time
Dependent Variable: Duration of Hungry Season
Contract farming participant 0.206 0.005 0.013
(0.254) (0.109) (0.125)
Contract farming participant x girls 0.215* 0.118** 0.137**
(0.120) (0.054) (0.061)
Contract farming participant x boys 0.163 0.015 0.018
(0.120) (0.048) (0.054)

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ajae/article-abstract/99/2/357/2632247 by guest on 03 July 2020


Number of girls in the household 0.214 0.067 0.076
(0.133) (0.056) (0.063)
Number of boys in the household 0.129 0.026 0.028
(0.141) (0.057) (0.065)
Household size 0.007 0.002 0.003
(0.059) (0.028) (0.032)
Dependency ratio 0.258 0.196 0.223
(0.584) (0.231) (0.258)
Household head single 0.167 0.058 0.088
(0.348) (0.148) (0.169)
Household head female 0.766* 0.336* 0.406**
(0.406) (0.175) (0.202)
Household head migrant 0.061 0.001 0.009
(0.221) (0.102) (0.116)
Household head age 0.024** 0.004 0.004
(0.010) (0.004) (0.005)
Household head education 0.067*** 0.023** 0.027**
(0.023) (0.010) (0.012)
Household head agricultural experience 0.029*** 0.004 0.003
(0.010) (0.004) (0.005)
Household head member of farm organization 0.084 0.096 0.123
(0.179) (0.086) (0.098)
Days agricultural work forbidden 0.003 0.000 0.001
(0.002) (0.001) (0.001)
Household income 0.004** 0.001 0.001
(0.002) (0.001) (0.002)
Household working capital 0.002 0.005*** 0.006***
(0.003) (0.002) (0.002)
Household assets 0.013*** 0.004*** 0.005***
(0.003) (0.001) (0.001)
Household landholdings 0.000 0.000 0.000
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
Yes to $12.50 investment 0.191 0.025 0.017
(0.216) (0.095) (0.106)
Yes to $25.00 investment 0.420* 0.104 0.122
(0.226) (0.091) (0.104)
Yes to $37.50 investment 0.366* 0.122 0.143
(0.212) (0.098) (0.111)
Yes to $50.00 investment 0.193 0.015 0.012
(0.238) (0.108) (0.125)
Yes to $62.50 investment 0.138 0.003 0.003
(0.290) (0.137) (0.159)
Yes to $75.00 investment 0.193 0.250 0.265
(0.342) (0.171) (0.189)
Constant 3.586*** – 4.069***
(0.486) (0.271)
Observations 1,178 1,045 1,045
District fixed effects Yes Yes Yes
R-squared 0.213 – –
Note: Robust standard errors appear in parentheses. Asterisks denote the following: ***¼ p < 0.01, **¼ p < 0.05, and *¼ p < 0.1.
372 March 2017 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

Table 5. Probit Regression Results for


Propensity Score Estimation
Variables Probit
Dependent Variable:
Contract Farming Participant
Household size 0.013
(0.019)
Dependency ratio 0.019
(0.191)
Household head is single 0.162

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ajae/article-abstract/99/2/357/2632247 by guest on 03 July 2020


(0.188)
Household head is female 0.189
(0.217)
Household head is migrant 0.040
(0.123) Figure 3. Distribution of propensity scores by
Household head age 0.014** participation regime
(0.006) Note: Solid lines denote participants in contract farming; dashed lines de-
Household head education 0.015 note nonparticipants.
(0.013)
Household head agricultural 0.008 likely to participate in contract farming.
experience Households in which the survey respondent
(0.006)
answered that he would be willing to pay the
Household head member 0.472***
of farm organization random dollar amount in order to participate
(0.097) in a hypothetical contract farming agreement
Days agricultural work is 0.002 are more likely to participate in contract
forbidden farming than households in which the respon-
(0.001) dent answered “No.”
Household income 0.002 Figure 3 displays the distribution of the
(0.002) propensity scores by participants and non-
Household working capital 0.004 participants in contract farming for the full,
(0.004) untrimmed sample. There is a substantial
Household assets 0.001
amount of overlap in the propensity scores
(0.002)
Household landholdings 0.000* between participants and non-participants.
(0.000) This overlap is crucial to estimating reliable
Yes to $12.50 investment 0.299** effects of contract farming because it implies
(0.131) that there are participating and non-
Yes to $25.00 investment 0.433*** participating households with similar charac-
(0.122) teristics. Moreover, Supplementary online
Yes to $37.50 investment 0.434*** appendix tables A10 to A12 present balance
(0.123) statistics for the matched samples in all three
Yes to $50.00 investment 0.596*** of our matching specifications.
(0.129)
Table 6 displays estimation results for the
Yes to $62.50 investment 0.372**
(0.167) unmatched sample along with the estimation
Yes to $75.00 investment 0.569*** results for the three treatment effect estima-
(0.158) tors (i.e., ATT, ATE, and ATU) for each of
Constant 0.131 our three matching routines. These results es-
(0.247) timate (a) the effect of participation in con-
Observations 1,178 tract farming on the length of the hungry
District dummies Yes season experienced by the household for
Pseudo R-squared 0.069 households that participated in contract farm-
Log likelihood 760.359 ing (ATT); (b) what the effect of participa-
Note: Standard errors appear in parentheses. Asterisks denote the following: tion in contract farming would have been for
***¼ p < 0.01, **¼ p < 0.05, and *¼ p < 0.1. households that did not participate in con-
tract farming (ATU); and (c) what the aver-
age effect of participation in contract farming
would have been for all households in the
sample had all households participated
Bellemare and Novak Contract Farming and Food Security 373

Table 6. Outcome Variable: Duration of Hungry Season


1 Neighbor 3 Neighbors 3 Neighbors
Sample Caliper 0.01 Caliper 0.01 Caliper 0.001
Unmatched sample 0.400*** 0.400*** 0.400***
(0.123) (0.123) (0.123)
Average treatment effect on the treated 0.194 0.305 0.295
(0.234) (0.223) (0.255)
Average treatment effect on the untreated 0.062 0.204 0.249
(0.225) (0.207) (0.269)
Average treatment effect 0.127 0.252 0.272

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ajae/article-abstract/99/2/357/2632247 by guest on 03 July 2020


(0.204) (0.196) (0.241)
Note: Standard errors appear in parentheses; standard errors calculated using three neighbors to calculate conditional variance as in Abadie and Imbens
(2006). Asterisks denote the following: ***¼ p < 0.01, **¼ p < 0.05, and *¼ p < 0.1.

(ATE). As expected, the results for all three detailed in the subsection Identification
matching routines show that the largest effect Strategy. Because imputations yield gener-
(in absolute value) is for households that did ated regressors, we bootstrap the standard er-
participate, followed by the effect for all rors but omit sampling weights in
households in the sample, and lastly the ef- Supplementary online appendix tables A2,
fect for those households that did not partici- A3, and A4.13 Given the results in
pate. Recall that the estimated ATE is most Supplementary online appendix tables A2,
comparable to the estimated effects for the A3, and A4, our core results appear to be ro-
OLS results because OLS reports the ATE. bust to a change in how we proxy for respon-
The ATE ranges from -0.127 to -0.272. dent marginal utility to participate in a
This represents a reduction in the length of hypothetical contract farming agreement that
the hungry season by between four and eight would increase household income by 10%.
days—an effect that is very close to what we Similarly, when we include sampling weights
find using our OLS specification in the first but do not bootstrap the standard errors in
column of table 2b. The effect for participat- Supplementary online appendix tables A5,
ing households is larger, that is, the ATT A6, and A7, our core results appear once
ranges from -0.194 to -0.305. This is a reduc- again robust to a change in how we proxy for
tion in the length of the hungry season by six respondent marginal utility to participate in a
to nine days. hypothetical contract farming agreement that
would increase household income by 10%.
Supplementary online appendix table A8
Robustness Checks presents the results of treatment regressions
In order to ensure that our results are ro- wherein responses to the contingent-valuation
bust, we estimate a number of alternative questions are used as instrumental variables
specifications. Table 5 presents the results of for participation in contract farming, as in
two estimators that aim to minimize the ef- Bellemare (2012). Taking both the OLS re-
fects of outliers. The first specification is a sults in table 2b and the treatment regression
median regression. Intuitively, a median re- results in Supplementary online appendix ta
gression is similar to an OLS regression, ex- ble A8 at face value—that is, assuming that
cept that it focuses on the conditional median they both identify causal impacts—would sug-
rather than the conditional mean. The second gest that the local average treatment effect
specification is a robust regression (LATE; i.e., the estimated coefficient on par-
(Rousseeuw and Yohai 1987). In both cases, ticipation in contract farming in either column
results are very similar to the core OLS result of Supplementary online appendix table A8)
in the first column of table 2b. is much larger than the ATE (i.e., the esti-
In Supplementary online appendix tables mated coefficient on participation in contract
A2 to A7, we present estimation results simi- farming in the first column of table 2b). In
lar to our core results in tables 2, 3, and 4, re-
spectively, but with one important difference.
In tables A2, A3, and A4, the responses to 13
We do not show results in which we use sampling weights
the contingent-valuation questions that were and bootstrapped standard errors, because the use of the latter
not posed to the respondent are imputed, as precludes incorporating the former.
374 March 2017 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

other words, if one is willing to believe that the reported duration of the hungry season for
both specifications are well-specified and iden- those households that were induced to partici-
tify causal relationships, one would conclude pate because they would derive a higher mar-
that participating in contract farming is associ- ginal utility from participating in the
ated with an almost two-month decrease in hypothetical contract farming arrangement.

Table 7. Estimation Results for Median and Robust Regressions


(1) (2)
Variables Median Robust
Dependent Variable: Duration of Hungry Season

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ajae/article-abstract/99/2/357/2632247 by guest on 03 July 2020


Contract farming participant 0.306** 0.255**
(0.147) (0.121)
Household size 0.023 0.040
(0.035) (0.029)
Dependency ratio 0.331 0.364
(0.354) (0.291)
Household head single 0.275 0.114
(0.347) (0.285)
Household head female 0.095 0.290
(0.396) (0.326)
Household head migrant 0.034 0.070
(0.227) (0.187)
Household head age 0.022** 0.024***
(0.011) (0.009)
Household head education 0.040* 0.049**
(0.023) (0.019)
Household head agricultural experience 0.022** 0.026***
(0.011) (0.009)
Household head member of farm organization 0.092 0.037
(0.180) (0.148)
Agricultural work forbidden 0.002 0.003
(0.003) (0.002)
Household income 0.008*** 0.006***
(0.002) (0.002)
Household working capital 0.002 0.002
(0.004) (0.003)
Household assets 0.011*** 0.012***
(0.003) (0.002)
Household landholdings 0.000 0.000
(0.000) (0.000)
"Yes" to $12.50 investment 0.217 0.191
(0.246) (0.202)
"Yes" to $25.00 investment 0.489** 0.419**
(0.229) (0.188)
"Yes" to $37.50 investment 0.248 0.269
(0.231) (0.190)
"Yes" to $50.00 investment 0.480** 0.356*
(0.242) (0.199)
"Yes" to $62.50 investment 0.158 0.185
(0.313) (0.257)
"Yes" to $75.00 investment 0.285 0.191
(0.298) (0.245)
Constant 3.999*** 3.751***
(0.472) (0.388)
Observations 1,178 1,178
District fixed effects Yes Yes
R-squared – 0.200
Note: Standard errors appear in parentheses. Asterisks denote the following: ***¼ p < 0.01, **¼ p < 0.05, and *¼ p < 0.1.
Bellemare and Novak Contract Farming and Food Security 375

But taking into account the potential effect of order to believe that our estimates are causal,
participating in contract farming for one must trust that our proxies for respon-
everyone—including nonparticipants—the ef- dent marginal utility of participation in con-
fect is severely moderated. In other words, the tract farming derived from our contingent
fact that the LATE exceeds the ATE implies valuation experiment fully account for the se-
that compliers (i.e., those households that par- lection process whereby households choose
ticipate in contract farming because they derive to participate in contract farming. This is an
higher marginal utility from doing so and those assumption that is untestable. Moreover,
households that do not participate because comparing the OLS specification in the first
they would not derive higher marginal utility columns of tables 2a and 2b shows that the
from doing so) derive higher benefits than de- coefficients are not statistically different

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ajae/article-abstract/99/2/357/2632247 by guest on 03 July 2020


fiers (i.e., those households that participate but between the two models. The coefficient
derive lower marginal utility from doing so, or on the contract farming dummy only goes
households that do not participate but would from -0.293 in table 2a to -0.277 in table 2b.
derive higher marginal utility from doing so). This suggests one of two things: either (a)
Finally, Supplementary online appendix ta the WTP questions do not do a good job of ac-
ble A9 includes the results for the model in counting for selection into contract farming, or
which we enforce monotonic switching in the (b) participation in contract farming is not en-
set of WTP questions. This model yields re- dogenous to the reported duration of the hun-
sults that are identical to those in table 2. We gry season experienced by households. In order
thus conclude from these robustness checks to investigate claim (a), we use an OLS regres-
that our core results are robust to alternative sion (not shown) of contract farming participa-
estimators and specifications. tion on the right-hand side variables in table 2,
Lastly, for ease of comparison, table 8 syn- and find that a joint significance test of the
thesizes all of the estimated treatment effects WTP dummies shows that those dummies are
in tables 2 to 7. jointly significant at a confidence level that ex-
ceeds 99%. Similarly, the probit regression re-
Limitations sults in table 5 show that WTP is highly
correlated with participation in contract farm-
Despite their robustness, our results suffer ing. In other words, responses to the WTP ex-
from some important limitations in terms of periment appear to explain selection into
internal validity, and in terms of the measure- contract farming, which would invalidate (a)
ment of food insecurity. above, leaving us to conclude that (b) holds.
In terms of internal validity, it bears re- In terms of measurement of food insecurity,
peating that our estimates of the effect of we wish to reiterate that we are only measur-
household participation in contract farming ing one aspect of food insecurity, that is, the
on the reported duration of the hungry sea- reported length of time during which at least
son experienced by that household is only as one household member goes without eating
good as our identification strategy. Here, in three meals a day. But food insecurity could

Table 8. Synthesis of Estimated Treatment Effects


Estimator Treatment Effect Type Estimated Effect (in Months)
OLS regression without WTP controls ATE 0.294
OLS regression ATE 0.277
Median regression ATE 0.306
Robust regression ATE 0.255
PSM 1 nearest neighbor, caliper 0.01 ATE 0.127
PSM 3 nearest neighbors, caliper 0.01 ATE 0.252
PSM 3 nearest neighbors, caliper 0.001 ATE 0.272
PSM 1 nearest neighbor, caliper 0.01 ATT 0.194
PSM 3 nearest neighbors, caliper 0.01 ATT 0.305
PSM 3 nearest neighbors, caliper 0.001 ATT 0.295
PSM 1 nearest neighbor, caliper 0.01 ATU 0.062
PSM 3 nearest neighbors, caliper 0.01 ATU 0.204
PSM 3 nearest neighbors, caliper 0.001 ATU 0.249
Treatment regression LATE 1.930
376 March 2017 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

be measured much more precisely by measur- These are important results given that chil-
ing each household member’s consumption of dren, particularly girls, bear the largest bur-
calories, macronutrients (e.g., carbohydrates, den of food insecurity, the consequences of
fat, and protein), or micronutrients (i.e., spe- which include stunting, wasting, listlessness,
cific vitamins and minerals). The data used in and cognitive impairment (Alderman,
this article were not collected for the specific Hoddinott, and Kinsey 2006; Ruel and
purpose of studying food insecurity, and mea- Alderman 2013). Our results suggest that pol-
suring food insecurity accurately would re- icies that lower barriers to entering contract
quire individual-level rather than household- farming agreements for households with chil-
level survey questionnaires. dren, and particularly girls, may lead to big
gains in terms of food security.

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ajae/article-abstract/99/2/357/2632247 by guest on 03 July 2020


From a behavioral perspective, our results
Concluding Remarks suggest that smallholders in Madagascar save
a portion of the additional income they re-
We have used data on 1,200 households ceive from participating in contract farming
across six regions of Madagascar to investi- in order to spend it on food in the months in
gate the relationship between contract farm- which they would otherwise need to skip
ing and food security by examining whether meals.15 Alternatively, our results may sug-
participation in contract farming is associated gest that the improvement in food security
with a decrease in the reported duration of that results from contract farming is a result
the hungry season experienced by the house- of participants growing staple or other food
holds in our data. crops, that is, via some positive productivity
Our results show that participation in con- spillover to the staple crops those participants
tract farming is associated with a reduction in grow for their subsistence or via a misappro-
the reported duration of the hungry season priation of some of what they grow under
by about eight days for the average house- contract. Our tests of those hypotheses, how-
hold, and that it increases the likelihood that ever, showed that it is very unlikely that that
a household will exit the hungry season at the cultivation of rice or food crops is the
any point in time by about 18%, on average. mechanism whereby participation in contract
These are important results because even farming improved food security in this con-
though published research has shown that text. From a policy perspective, our findings
contract farming increases the income of par- suggest that policies that facilitate the devel-
ticipating farmers (Porter and Phillips- opment of agricultural value chains, beyond
Howard 1997; Singh 2002; Warning and Key their direct welfarist effect on the incomes of
2002; Simmons 2005; Maertens and Swinnen those who participate as growers, can also
2009; Minten, Randrianarison, and Swinnen have indirect nonwelfarist effects on those
2009; Miyata, Minot, and Hu 2009; Rao and same growers’ food security.
Qaim 2011; Bellemare 2012; Michelson 2013;
Narayanan 2014), there has so far been no at-
tempt to study whether contract farming
leads to improvements in food security, and Supplementary Material
the link between agricultural value chains
and nutrition has been deemed a high priority Supplementary material is available at http://
by policy makers (Gelli et al. 2015; FAO oxfordjournals.org/our_journals/ajae/.
2013).14 Moreover, the estimated effects of
participation in contract farming on the re-
ported duration of the hungry season experi- References
enced by households are especially
pronounced for households with more chil- Abadie, Alberto, and Guido W. Imbens. 2006.
dren, and for households with more girls. Large Sample Properties of Matching

14 15
Again, the difference between Bellemare (2012) and this A reviewer commented that households that participate in
study is twofold. First, whereas Bellemare looked at income as contract farming might see their hungry seasons start later than
his outcome variable, we look at the duration of the hungry sea- nonparticipant households. Looking into whether that is the
son as ours. Second, whereas Bellemare used respondent WTP to case, we found that the start date of the hungry season was not
participate in contract farming as an instrumental variable, we significantly different for households that do and do not partici-
use it as a control variable in a selection-on-observables design. pate in contract farming.
Bellemare and Novak Contract Farming and Food Security 377

Estimators for Average Treatment Imbens, G. 2015. Matching Methods in


Effects. Econometrica 74 (1): 235–267. Practice: Three Examples. Journal of
Alderman, H., J. Hoddinott, and B. Kinsey Human Resources 50 (2): 373–419.
2006. Long-term Consequences of Early Lancaster, T. 1992. The Econometric Analysis
Childhood Malnutrition. Oxford of Transition Data. Cambridge:
Economic Papers 58 (3): 450–74. Cambridge University Press.
Angrist, J.D., and J.-S. Pischke. 2009. Mostly Maertens, M., and J.F.M. Swinnen. 2009.
Harmless Econometrics. Princeton: Trade, Standards, and Poverty: Evidence
Princeton University Press. from Senegal. World Development 37 (1):
Banerjee, A.V., and S. Mullainathan. 2010. 161–78.
The Shape of Temptation: Implications Manski, C.F., and S.R. Lerman. 1977. The

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ajae/article-abstract/99/2/357/2632247 by guest on 03 July 2020


for the Economic Lives of the Poor. Estimation of Choice Probabilities from
NBER Working Paper. Choice Based Samples. Econometrica 45
Barrett, C.B. 2002. Food Security and Food (8): 1977–88.
Assistance Programs. Handbook of Michelson, H.C. 2013. Small Farmers, NGOs,
Agricultural Economics. Amsterdam, and a Walmart World: Welfare Effects of
Netherlands: Elsevier Science B.V. Supermarkets Operating in Nicaragua.
Barrett, C.B., M.E. Bachke, M.F. Bellemare, American Journal of Agricultural
H.C. Michelson, S. Narayanan, and T.F. Economics 95 (3): 628–49.
Walker. 2012. Smallholder Participation Minten, B., L. Randrianarison, and J.F.M.
in Contract Farming: Comparative Swinnen. 2009. Global Retail Chains and
Evidence from Five Countries. World Poor Farmers: Evidence from
Development 40 (4): 715–30. Madagascar. World Development 37 (11):
Bellemare, M.F. 2012. As You Sow, So Shall 1728–41.
You Reap: The Welfare Impacts of Miyata, S., N. Minot, and D. Hu. 2009.
Contract Farming. World Development Impact of Contract Farming on Income:
40 (7): 1418–34. Linking Small Farmers, Packers, and
Bellemare, M.F., C.B. Barrett, and D.R. Just. Supermarkets in China. World
2013. The Welfare Impacts of Development 37 (11): 1781–90.
Commodity Price Volatility: Evidence Montalbano, P., R. Pietrelli, and L. Salvatici.
from Rural Ethiopia. American Journal 2015. Food Security and Value Supply
of Agricultural Economics 95 (4): Chain: The Case of Ugandan Maize.
877–99. Unpublished manuscript, University of
Dedehouanou, S.F.A., J. Swinnen, and M. Sussex and University of Roma Tre.
Maertens. 2013. Does Contracting Make Moser, Christine M. 2008. Report on the
Farmers Happy? Evidence from Senegal. 2007 commune census. Working Paper,
Review of Income and Wealth 139 (S1): Western Michigan University.
S138–60. Narayanan, S. 2014. Profits from
Dupas, P., and J. Robinson. 2013. Savings Participation in High-value Agriculture:
Constraints and Microenterprise Evidence of Heterogeneous Benefits in
Development: Evidence from a Field Contract Farming Schemes in Southern
Experiment in Kenya. American India. Food Policy 44: 142–57.
Economic Journal: Applied Economics Porter, G., and K. Phillips-Howard. 1997.
5 (1): 163–92. Comparing Contracts: An Evaluation of
Food and Agriculture Organization of the Contract Farming Schemes in Africa.
United Nations. 2013. The State of Food World Development 25 (2): 227–38.
and Agriculture. Rome: FAO. Rao, E.J.O., and M. Qaim. 2011.
Gelli, A., C. Hawkes, J. Donovan, J. Harris, S. Supermarkets, Farm Household Income,
Allen, A. de Brauw, S. Henson, N. Johnson, and Poverty: Insights from Kenya. World
J. Garrett, and D. Ryckembusch. 2015. Development 39 (5): 784–96.
Value Chains for Nutrition. Discussion Rousseuw, P., and A.M. Leroy. 2005. Robust
Paper 01413, International Food Policy Regression and Outlier Detection. New
Research Institute. York: Wiley.
Grosh, B. 1994. Contract Farming in Africa: Rousseeuw, P.J., and V. Yohai. 1987. Robust
An Application of the New Institutional Regression by Means of S-estimators. in:
Economics. Journal of African J., Franke, W., H€ardle, and D. Martin
Economies 3 (2): 231–61. (eds) Robust and Nonlinear Time Series
378 March 2017 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

Analysis, Lecture Notes in Statistics No. in the Indian Punjab. World


26 (Berlin: Springer Verlag), pp. Development 30 (9): 1621–38.
256–272. Smith, A. 1976. An Inquiry into the Nature
Ruel, M.T., and H. Alderman. 2013. and Causes of the Wealth of Nations.
Nutrition-sensitive Interventions and Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Programmes: How Can They Help to Stephens, E.C., and C.B. Barrett. 2011.
Accelerate Progress in Improving Incomplete Credit Markets and Commodity
Maternal and Child Nutrition? The Marketing Behavior. Journal of Agricultural
Lancet 382 (9891): 536–51. Economics 62 (1): 1–24.
Ruud, J. 1960. Taboo: A Study of Malagasy Stifel, D., M. Fafchamps, and B. Minten.
Customs and Beliefs. Oslo: Oslo 2007. Taboos, Agriculture, and Poverty.

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ajae/article-abstract/99/2/357/2632247 by guest on 03 July 2020


University Press. Journal of Development Studies 47 (10):
Simmons, P., P. Winters, and I. Patrick. 1455–81.
2005. An Analysis of Contract Farming Warning, M., and N. Key. 2002. The Social
in East Java, Bali, and Lombok, Performance and Distributional
Indonesia. Agricultural Economics 33 Consequences of Contract Farming: An
(s3): 513–25. Equilibrium Analysis of the Arachide de
Singh, S. 2002. Contracting Out Solutions: bouche Program in Senegal. World
Political Economy of Contract Farming Development 30 (2): 255–63.

Вам также может понравиться