Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 24

Ecological Modelling 193 (2006) 271–294

A simulation model of sustainability of coastal communities:


Aquaculture, fishing, environment and labour markets
W.D. McCausland a , E. Mente b,c,∗ , G.J. Pierce b , I. Theodossiou a
a Centre for European Labour Market Research, University of Aberdeen Business School,
Dunbar Street, AB24 3QY Aberdeen, Scotland, UK
b Department of Zoology, School of Biological Sciences, University of Aberdeen, Tillydrone Avenue,

AB24 2TZ Aberdeen, Scotland, UK


c Laboratory of Ichthyology and Hydrobiology, Department of Agriculture, Animal Production and Aquatic Environment,
University of Thessaly, Fytokou Street, Nea Ionia, GR-38446 Volos, Greece

Received 11 August 2004; received in revised form 5 July 2005; accepted 25 August 2005
Available online 5 October 2005

Abstract

A bio-socio-economic model was developed to simulate (a) biological interactions related to traditional fishing, aquaculture,
and the physical marine environment and (b) coastal labour market interactions and the regulatory environment. The model was
calibrated using published information on fish farms, fishing, fished stocks and labour activity. Fished stocks were considered
as a single unit undergoing constant natural regeneration. Aquaculture production was described by a standard Cobb–Douglas
production function. The labour force in the coastal community was taken to comprise four components: (a) traditional fishing,
(b) aquaculture, (3) other employment, and (4) the unemployed labour. Simulations investigating the effect of stricter regulation
of traditional fishing and aquaculture on biomass, fish production and employment suggested that while stricter regulation of
fishing inevitably leads to declining employment in fisheries, increased regulation of aquaculture will not necessarily stem
growth in that sector. The importance of aquaculture as an alternative source of employment is emphasised. Nevertheless, the
present model ignores the potential adverse effects of catastrophic stochastic events on the fishing and aquaculture sectors (e.g.
recruitment failure in wild fish populations, loss of farm stock) and the relatively optimistic outlook suggested for the aquaculture
industry should therefore be viewed with caution.
© 2005 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Aquaculture; Sustainability; Fisheries; Simulation model; Employment; Coastal communities

1. Introduction

∗ Corresponding author. Tel.: +44 1224 272867;


Fishing and aquaculture are both important eco-
fax: +44 1224 272396. nomic activities in the European Union (European
E-mail address: e.mente@abdn.ac.uk (E. Mente). Commission, 2001, 2002). The aquaculture industry

0304-3800/$ – see front matter © 2005 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.ecolmodel.2005.08.028
272 W.D. McCausland et al. / Ecological Modelling 193 (2006) 271–294

Fig. 1. Total aquaculture production (EU + EFTA) (FAO Fish Stat). EU15 + EFTA—Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany,
Greece, Ireland, Italy, Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, United Kingdom, Iceland, Norway, Switzerland.

has grown fast in recent years and played its part in pean waters, many exploited finfish stocks are cur-
satisfying an increasing consumer demand for marine rently judged to be outside safe biological limits (ICES,
fish (Fig. 1). It has been argued that aquaculture has 2002), notably cod in the North Sea. The decline of
the potential to bridge the growing gap between the important resource species such as cod has resulted in
global demand and supply of fish products (Goulding increasingly stringent regulation of catches (reduced
et al., 2000). Aquaculture constitutes around 17% of quotas) and in the setting up of decommissioning
the weight and 27% of the value of total fishery pro- schemes.
duction of the European Union (total production being While the fishing (capture fishery) sector’s con-
defined as the sum of landings in the ports of EU tribution to the gross national product of EU Mem-
Member States and aquaculture production; European ber States is generally less than 1%, its impact is
Commission, 19/9/2002). The annual output of the highly significant as a source of employment in coastal
aquaculture industry in the EU is worth over D 2.4 areas, where there are often few alternatives. How-
billion (European Commission, 2001). World aquacul- ever, the number of fishermen has declined in recent
ture production has been projected to double by 2030, years, with a loss of 66,000 jobs in the catching sec-
exceed 2.5 million tonnes by 2015 and reach 4 million tor (an overall decrease of 22%) and a 14% decline
tonnes by 2030 (FAO, 2002). in employment in the processing sector between 1990
In recent years, the harvest of fish from natural and 1998 (DG Fisheries, 17.01.03); a trend that may
waters in many European fishing grounds has appar- threaten the viability of small coastal communities
ently reached its upper limit, but the demand for fish- in the absence of suitable alternative employment
ery products is still growing (FAO, 2002). In Euro- locally.
W.D. McCausland et al. / Ecological Modelling 193 (2006) 271–294 273

Employment in world aquaculture production has Commission, 19/9/2002, 2000). In addition there are
remained relatively stable since 1995 and it was esti- perceived to be environmental problems associated
mated, in 2000, to be 20% of the combined total with aquaculture that may be threatening capture fish-
employment in capture fisheries and aquaculture (FAO, eries.
2002). In recent years, aquaculture has been the only It is difficult for producers, regulators and envi-
segment of the fisheries industry in the European ronmental managers to determine the proper balance
Community to experience a rise in employment. In between the interests of the environment and the legit-
1998, fish processing provided employment for a fur- imate pursuit of sustainable economic activity. It is
ther 89,468 individuals (Green Paper, 2005; European important to base the debate on verifiable and sci-
Commission, 2001). In 1998, aquaculture in the EU entific facts and testable hypotheses of the interac-
employed at least 80,000 full-time or part-time work- tion between production and the environment (Cromey
ers, mostly in coastal and rural areas (European et al., 2000; Henderson et al., 2001). Indeed, the long-
Commission, 19/9/2002). In Norway, employment in term sustainability of aquaculture depends on (among
the aquaculture sector rose from virtually zero to other things) the maintenance of environmental quality
about 3500 people in 1995, in Ireland 2200 people in order to provide a good growing environment for the
are employed, in France 4700 people are employed fish.
in oyster farming and in Galicia (Spain) there are Sustainability and sustainable development are
13,500 jobs in aquaculture (European Commission, complex issues that are difficult to define and apply in
19/9/2002). aquaculture. According to Black (2001), sustainability
While the aquaculture industry has grown rapidly, is where environmental effects meet socio-economics
so have concerns regarding its environmental and social and markets. Phillips et al. (2001) argued that sustain-
impacts. For example, the accumulation of wasted ability could be split into three separate components:
food and faecal material results in a sedimentary envi- social sustainability, economic sustainability and envi-
ronment under fish cages characterized by low redox ronmental sustainability. Other authors add institu-
potentials (Hargrave et al., 1993), high content of tional sustainability to this list. Some European coun-
organic material (Hall et al., 1990; Holmer, 1992) tries have already developed legal frameworks and poli-
and the accumulation of nitrogenous and phosphorous cies for managing aquaculture development (Table 1).
compounds (Hall et al., 1992; Holby and Hall, 1991; Aquaculture is frequently regulated by many agencies
Karakassis et al., 1998). These changes in sediment under a variety of laws (e.g. Greece, Portugal, Fin-
characteristics induce conspicuous changes in local land), though in some countries there is an integrated
benthic communities (Pearson and Rosenberg, 1978; legal framework (e.g. UK). Developing a comprehen-
O’Connor et al., 1989; Weston, 1990; Pocklington sive regulatory framework for the sector is often legally
et al., 1994) and secondary disturbance may prolong and institutionally complex (Henderson and Davies,
recovery after cessation of fish farming (Karakassis 2001). It has been argued that existing administra-
et al., 1999). Although significant impacts on benthos tive and legal frameworks need to be reviewed and
composition have been reported at distances as far as adjusted to address the changing characteristics and
100 m from the cages (Weston, 1990), in general this needs of the sector and to set out clearly the privileges
type of impact (at least, with respect to salmon culture and responsibilities of aquaculturists (Henderson and
in UK waters), is localized to within 20–50 m around Davies, 2000).
the cages (Beveridge, 1996). The development of aquaculture in coastal areas,
Marine aquaculture interacts with (European) coupled with the difficulties presently faced by the
coastal fisheries in a country-specific manner but there capture fishing industry, poses questions about the
are some underlying similarities. There are concerns social, economic, environmental and ecological sus-
that coastal fisheries are not sustainable at present tainability of coastal communities across Europe, such
levels and that aquaculture may be adversely affect- as:
ing fisheries. The employment and welfare of local
and non-local people need to be considered in the (1) How does employment in rural communities
conflicting environment that has developed (European change with the arrival of aquaculture?
274 W.D. McCausland et al. / Ecological Modelling 193 (2006) 271–294

Table 1
List of EU environnemental legislation relevant to aquaculture
EU directives/conventions Objective
Fish and shellfish waters, 1978 Water quality for fish and shellfish
Habitat and species, 1988 Special areas of conservation, Natura 2000
Integrated coastal zone management A European strategy for integrated coastal management
Directive on the conservation of wild birds, 1997 Habitats and the environnent
(97/49/EEC), special protection areas (SPAs)
Habitats directive, 1992 (92/43/EEC), special areas of Concerns the protection and conservation of natural habitats
conservation (SACs) (NATURA 2000 and Ramsar sites)
Directive other substances, 1976 (76/464/EEC) Protection of the aquatic environment
Directive on waste disposal, 1975 (75/442/EEC) Habitats and the environment
Strategic environmental assessment (SEA) directive Habitats and the environment
(pending)
Directive on the quality of shellfish waters, 1979 Water quality and management
(79/923/EEC)
Water framework directive, 2000 (60/2000/EC) Water quality and management
Environmental impact assessment directive Thresholds are set by each Member country
85/337/EEC and 97/11/EC Environmental impact statements (EISs)
Directive 91/493/EEC as amended by 95/71/EC Controls the animal health conditions
Directive 91/67/EEC aquatic animal health Consumer protection
Directive 90/220/EEC genetically modified organisms Release into the environment of live GMOs the use of genetically
(GMOs) and 90/219/EEC modified micro-organisms
Directive 91/67/EEC as amended by 93/54/EC and Marketing of aquaculture animals and products
95/22/EC
The dangerous substances directive (76/464/EEC) Lists toxic substances (those which have deleterious effects on
aquatic environment)
The shellfish waters directive (79/923/EEC) Concerns the quality of shellfish waters in designated areas
The shellfish hygiene directive (91/492/EEC) Classifies shellfish production areas according to the amount of
microbiological contamination
EC directive 91/67 Approved Zone status for Bonamia and Marteilia diseases
Directive 1999/29/EC, 2001/102/EC and EC 2375/2001 Undesirable substances in animal nutrition (dioxins), regarding
and Reg. 1436/98/EC additives in feeds
Directive 96/23/EEC Monitoring antibiotic residues in food
Directive 82/471/EEC Regarding certain products used in animal nutrition
Barcelona 1975, 2000 (Convention) Mediterranean Sea, protection of the marine environment
HELCOM, 1974, 1992 (Convention) Baltic Sea and Baltic catchment area, protection of the marine
environment
FAO, 1995, 1999 (Convention) Code of conduct for responsible fisheries
UNCLOS (UN convention on law of the sea) 1982 Global Covered a global area. Law of the sea (a) Northeast Atlantic.
(a) OSPARCOM, 1972, 1974, 1992 (Convention) (b) Protection of the marine environment, (b) covers impacts on water
OSPAR- PARCOM (The Paris commission recom- quality and the environment (i.e. limitation of density of fish in
mendation) 1994/1996 on aquaculture code of best pens, avoidance of the use of chemicals prophylactically, following
environmental practise (international agreements) (c) periods, washing and drying of nets instead of the use of antifoulant
The Paris convention 1974 for the protection of the compounds), (c) requires the reduction by at least 50% by 1995 of
North Sea and North-east Atlantic (international agree- discharges of various toxic and persistent chemicals (i.e. dichlorvos
ments) for sea-lice treatment).
Code of conduct for European aquaculture, 2000 Adopted by the Federation of European aquaculture producers
ICES codes of practise and manual procedures Introductions and transfers of marine and freshwater organisms
NASCO (North Atlantic conservation organization) Minimize salmon escapes
W.D. McCausland et al. / Ecological Modelling 193 (2006) 271–294 275

(2) What are the predictions for socio-economic, envi- The situation modelled is based on conditions on the
ronmental and biological sustainability resulting west coast of Scotland but should be readily applicable
from the interactions between aquaculture and fish- to other areas. The model (presently) excludes vari-
eries? ous types of stochastic “catastrophic” events, which
(3) What recommendations can be made for coastal sometimes befall aquaculture installations, such as loss
resource management in areas where aquaculture of stock due to failure of nets, disease outbreaks (e.g.
and fisheries coexist? infectious salmon anaemia (ISA)) or invasions of jelly-
fish. The model explores the likely impact of four key
Progress towards carrying out socio-economic eval- shocks that might strike the aquaculture installations,
uations of the effect of the aquaculture industry on namely (a) changes in demand of the aquaculture prod-
local communities and its interaction with employment uct, (b) changes in the regulations [for both aquaculture
in coastal fisheries and other local opportunities has and fishing] brought in by the European Community,
been slow. Relatively little is known about fishermen’s (c) changes in effectiveness of traditional feeding for
behaviour, preferences and strategies when confronted farmed fish and (d) changes in the technology used for
with an expanding aquaculture industry, taking into fish production. The model attempts to capture biolog-
account the availability of other employment oppor- ical, physical environmental, economic and social pro-
tunities. There is a need not only to assess the current cesses within a complex system and inevitably presents
socio-economic importance of the interaction of aqua- a highly simplified characterization of these processes.
culture industry and coastal fisheries but also to explore It is therefore important to establish whether the results
the consequences of changing coastal fishery patterns obtained appear to be realistic. Thus, each of the main
and management regimes on aquaculture opportunities, findings is discussed in the light of current knowledge
given other employment opportunities or drift to unem- of the interactions between fisheries, aquaculture and
ployment, and to evaluate prospects for expansion of the environment.
either of the above industries.
Modelling has been used as an approach to exam-
ine nitrogen dynamics in aquacultural systems by dif- 2. Methods
ferent authors (Paulson, 1980; Kochba et al., 1994;
Hargreaves, 1997; Lorenzen et al., 1997; Nielsen et al., 2.1. Model description
1999; Montoya et al., 1999a,b; Jimenez-Montealegre
et al., 2002). Henderson et al. (2001) reviewed the use 2.1.1. The biological interactions concerning
of hydrodynamic and benthic models for managing traditional fishing, aquaculture and the
environmental impacts. Mathematical modelling has environment
also been used to assess environmental carrying capac- 2.1.1.1. Traditional fishing. The model (Fig. 2) con-
ity for multi-species culture in coastal waters (Duarte siders fished stocks as a single unit undergoing constant
et al., 2003). The dynamics of fished populations are natural regeneration. Clearly the real situation involves
routinely modelled as part of the stock assessment many fished species, which interact in various ways
process (Hilborn and Walters, 1992). Although bioeco- (e.g. competition, predation) with other fished and
nomic models have been applied to a range of fisheries unexploited species in the marine habitat. Furthermore,
questions (e.g. Agar and Sutinen, 2004; Westra et al., recruitment of young fish to wild populations is gener-
2005; Ye et al., 2005), to the knowledge of the authors ally a stochastic process, the strength of which is linked
the present study represents the first attempt to combine only weakly to the size of the breeding populations, and
biological and socio-economic aspects of aquaculture is likely to be influenced by both environmental condi-
and fisheries within a common framework. The model tions and the abundance of other species. Nevertheless,
in this paper is a new simulation model of aquaculture data on annual stock sizes and recruitment levels are
development that takes account of economic and social available for the main resource species, such as had-
driving forces in a biologically realistic environment. dock, whiting and cod (e.g. Anon, 2002) and crude
The aim of this paper is to identify and describe empirical relationships between abundance and recruit-
interactions between capture fisheries and aquaculture. ment can be extracted from such data. While recent
276 W.D. McCausland et al. / Ecological Modelling 193 (2006) 271–294

Fig. 2. Schematic structure of the bio-socio-economic model.

research on recruitment variability (e.g. Marshall et al., on the productivity of benthic animals (benthos, B) at
2000) has moved well beyond such simplistic repre- a local level, as mediated by a sensitivity parameter
sentations, for the present model this was considered (upsilon, υ). For example, since nutrient releases from
adequate. fish culture installations are related to the production
Additions and damages to the fish stock biomass, x of these installations (Black, 2001). Aquaculture instal-
are given by the formula lations generate outputs of nutrients (e.g. from waste
food and fish faeces) and, potentially, chemicals used
Dx = rx − υB − (h/0.6) (1)
to treat disease outbreaks). In the immediate vicinity
The first term represents additions in the form of natural of cages holding salmon, benthic animals may be neg-
regeneration, taken to be a fixed proportion,1 r, of the atively affected, while at a slightly larger spatial scale
biomass, x. The second two terms represent damages the input of nutrients could support increased benthic
to the biomass (e.g. due to effects of pollution on the production, potentially contributing positively to food
food chain) and traditional fishing activity. In terms of availability to wild fish populations. At a larger scale
the present model, the main impact of environmental again the effects may well be negligible, certainly in
threats (e.g. pollution) is assumed to be on the regula- terms of total nitrogen inputs into a sea loch system
tory regime, i.e. the response of managers to perceived and the surrounding coast.
environmental threats, rather than acting directly on Fishing is now one of the major factors controlling
the fished or cultured organisms. Nevertheless, envi- the size of fished populations. An approximate indica-
ronmental effects are notionally represented as effects tion of the amount (and hence number) of fish removed
by fishing can be obtained by reference to published
1 This is taken to be a weighted average of regeneration rates for data on landings (e.g. Anon, 2002). However, a substan-
the main fished species, weighted by value of catch. The figures tial proportion of the catch – around 40% – (Tidwell and
are based on the published figures for annual SSB and recruitment, Allan, 2001) is discarded. Due to poor sampling of the
converting the format to numbers of fish based on market sample
data. Although there is likely to be some variation in this parameter
UK fleet’s activity and the complexity of fishers’ deci-
due to the very high variability in recruitment, we find our estimates sions about when to discard fish, published estimates
are robust to such variations. of amounts of fish discarded tend to be very imprecise
W.D. McCausland et al. / Ecological Modelling 193 (2006) 271–294 277

(Stratoudakis et al., 1998, 1999). Although amounts of Unit costs, C, are total costs, which depend on the qual-
discards will vary between species, areas and seasons, ity of feed input as measured by the feed composition
for simplicity we use a simple overall ratio. of gross feed input, FC, scaled by cost parameter w,
Traditional fishing activity is represented by the and divided by total output, F:
catch, h, which is determined in Section 3.1. Since
approximately 0.6 of catch is retained (West of Scot- C = wFC/F (6)
land, ASFM 2002) damage to biomass is h/0.6. This
A typical gross feed input, FC comprises (BioMar,
reflects the discarding of fish below the minimum land-
2000): protein 50%, p; phosphorus, 1.2% Q; lipid 16%,
ing size, dumping of “over-quota” fish, and “high grad-
l; fibre 1.3%, f; ash 9.3%, a; carbohydrate 15%, c. Some
ing” (the dumping of less valuable fish).2
of these inputs have polluting impacts on the benthos,
detailed in the next section.
2.1.1.2. Aquaculture. Aquaculture installations gen-
erate outputs of nutrients (e.g. from waste food and fish FC = 0.5 p + 0.012 Q + 0.16 l + 0.013
faeces), and potentially, chemicals used to treat disease
outbreaks). f + 0.093 a + 0.15 c (7)
Aquaculture production, F, is given by a stan-
Feed composition is scaled by a feed quality parameter,
dard Cobb–Douglas production function, which relates
V. Actual sales of the final product, S, are determined
inputs (on the right hand side) to output (on the left hand
by demand for the final product, income, y, and the
side), as used by Karagiannis and Katranidis (2000) and
price of substitute products, M, where θ represents the
Nerrie et al. (1990) (although the latter usage shows
sensitivity of sales of aquaculture products to prices of
decreasing returns to labour).
imported products:
F = RA GFχ LAλ Kκ (2)
S = d + y − θM (8)
where GF is gross feed input (which is analysed fur-
ther below), LA is labour input, and K capital input. 2.1.1.3. Environmental interactions. Aquaculture
The parameters chi, χ, lambda, λ, and kappa, κ, rep- production causes damage to the benthos, or pollution,
resent the elasticity (or sensitivity) of production to P. This is represented by the formula:
changes in their respective inputs. RA is a shift param-
eter reflecting the effect of regulation in aquaculture, P = −0.00048 Q − 0.055 N − 0.00005 SS
and is described in Section 3.3.
−0.00005 BOD − 0.00002 A (9)
Gross feed input, GF, is positively related (with coef-
ficient nu, ν) to demand for the final good, d: where the principal pollutants are phosphorus, Q ,
GF = νd (3) nitrogen (total minus dissolved nitrogen3 ), N, total sus-
pended solids, SS (all measured in kg/T of F), biochem-
Demand for the final good, d, is inversely related to the ical oxidation demand, BOD (see footnote 5) (mea-
market price, π sured in kg O2 /T of F), antibiotics, A (measured in kg/T
of F). The sensitivity coefficients are those of Enell
d = d̄ − zπ (4)
(1995), Pillay (1992), and ICES (2002). The effects
where d̄ is a constant reflecting non-price determinants of nutrients and organic loadings can be classified as
of demand, such as advertising, and z is the price elas- having:
ticity of demand. The market price is taken to be a
mark-up (Gordon, 1976), m, over unit costs, C: (a) Local impact: organic content and sediment par-
ticle size in relation to the benthos can possible
π = (1 + m)C (5) lead to oxygen depletion, etc. However, through

2 Another source of error concerns the amount of fish landed that


3 This is expressed as: N = N
does not enter official statistics (i.e. “black fish”). By definition the total − Ndissolved = [(0.16p ×
importance of this source of error is difficult to determine. 10 FCR) − 30] − [(0.16pδ × 10 FCR) − 30].
278 W.D. McCausland et al. / Ecological Modelling 193 (2006) 271–294

fallowing, it is possible to increase recovery min- (see footnote 5) in waste arising from salmon farming
eralisation turn-over by bacteria (the same strains (BioMar, 2000).
used in bacterial filtration) (ICES, 2002).
(b) Larger regional scale impact: eutrophication due Q = (10Q FCR) − 5 (10)
to nutrient release (ammonia, phosphate, CO2 ), the N = (1.66p FCR)(1 − δ) (11)
response of plankton, the response of wild fish pop-
ulations, etc. (Davies and Rae, 2003). Quantities SS = 398 − 919 FCR + 650 FCR2 − 83 FCR3 (12)
of each pollutant are directly related to produc-
tion in the following ways (Eqs. (10)–(14), see BOD = 686 − 1671 FCR + 1544 FCR2 − 354 FCR3
BioMar, 2000). The formula for phosphorus dis-
(13)
charge from a Scottish salmon farm assumes that
of the phosphorus ingested, 5 kg are incorporated
into flesh protein per tonne of production, whereas,
for nitrogen discharge the formula assumes that of A = 0.0002F (14)
nitrogen ingested in the feed 30 kg are incorpo- where FCR is the feed conversion ratio, defined as
rated into flesh protein per tonne of production (De FCR ≡ GF/F, and δ is the digestibility coefficient (see
Silva and Anderson, 1995). The formula for total footnote 5). The pollution index is multiplied produc-
suspended solids (SS) gives an estimate of the SS tion, F/j, where j is a scaling parameter.
in waste arising from salmon farming (kg SS/tonne Additionally, escapes6 from the aquaculture instal-
of production) (BioMar, 2000). lations are given by
The biochemical oxidation demand (BOD) mea- X = εF (15)
sures the biodegradable material in waste, found by
measuring the oxygen consumed by aerobic micro- The occurrence of farmed salmon in fisheries can
organisms acting on the waste. GESAMP (1996) lists vary widely between years (Butler, 2002). The model
BOD among suitable environmental metrics for land- assumes 20% escapes.
based fish tanks but, in general, BOD is not strictly
appropriate for assessing effects of fish farming on the 2.1.2. Social and economic interaction between
marine environment.4 However, in the present model coastal labour markets in traditional fishing and
BOD is used as a proxy for farm discharge per unit aquaculture and the regulatory environment
time derived from information on the FCR and the for- 2.1.2.1. Traditional fishing. The model considers the
mulae for the discharge parameters given in Eq. (9), fished “stock” as comprising all fished species. Inter-
for SS, N and P. The discharge budget is calculated in actions between species are not taken into account.
terms of BOD, N, P, SS. Eq. (9) outlines the sources of Following Skjold et al. (1996), catch, h, is given by the
environmental impact and emphasises the importance Schaefer (1957) production function which assumes
of the feed conversion ratio in salmon farming in terms a Cobb–Douglas relationship between two production
of its influence on discharge parameters. It also clearly factors, fishing effort, E, and stock biomass, x, and two
shows that, in environmental policy terms, particular technology parameters, the catchability quotient, q, and
attention should be paid in selecting feeds and feeding technological improvement, e:
strategies to minimise impact whilst optimising salmon h = RE qeγ Eα xβ (16)
growth and farm. The standard test for BOD measures
the consumption of oxygen over 5 days at 20 ◦ C giving where α and β are the effort-output and stock-output
the BOD.5 Formula 13 gives an estimate of the BOD elasticities and γ is the marginal change of efficiency
due to technological improvement. RE is a shift param-
eter capturing the effect of regulation of traditional
4 The authors are grateful to an anonymous referee of this journal
fishing and is described in Section 3.3.
for this point.
5 The Eqs. (10)–(14) determine feed composition, which feed into

the rest of the model through costs (Eq. (6)). 6 This has no further feedback within the model.
W.D. McCausland et al. / Ecological Modelling 193 (2006) 271–294 279

2.1.2.2. The labour market in the coastal community. production, F, and catch, h, but also indirectly on other
The labour force, LF, in the coastal community is taken factors that affect production, as given by Eq. (21).
to comprise of four components. These are traditional
fishing,7 assumed to be proxied by fishing effort, E, DLA = φ1 F ξ1 − φ2 hξ2 (21)
labour employed by aquaculture, LA, other employ- The phi terms, φ, represent external shocks to employ-
ment, LO (which may include tourism and other eco- ment in aquaculture (subscript 1) and the traditional
nomic activities), and unemployed labour, LU. fishing sector (subscript 2). The xi terms, ξ, repre-
LF = E + LA + LO + LU (17) sent the sensitivity of employment in aquaculture to
production in that sector (subscript 1) and production
A search theory approach is adopted that implies all in the principal competing sector, traditional fishing
flows of labour between the three-employment sectors (subscript 2). Similarly, the flow into employment in
take place via unemployment. Changes to the size of traditional fishing depends primarily on production as
the labour force, represented by net immigration, also measured by the catch, h, competing production in
take place via unemployment. Thus the change to the aquaculture, F, and again also indirectly on other fac-
stock of unemployment comprises the inflow from net tors that affect production, as given by Eq. (16).
immigration, DLF, and the outflows of workers newly
employed in the traditional fishing, aquaculture and DLE = η1 hι1 − η2 F ι2 (22)
other sectors: DE, DLA and DLO respectively. The eta terms, η, represent external shocks to employ-
DLU = DLF − DE − DLA − DLO (18) ment in traditional fishing (subscript 1) and aquaculture
(subscript 2). The iota terms, ι, represent the sensitivity
Each of these flows is now described in turn. Migra- of employment in traditional fishing to production in
tion is positively related to general economic activity that sector (subscript 1) and production in the principal
as measured by gross domestic product (GDP), Y. competing sector, aquaculture (subscript 2).
2.1.2.2.1. Policy and regulation. Regulation of
DLF = −τ + µY ψ (19) aquaculture is given by
The term tau, τ, represents natural out-migration, mu, RA = R2 (ρP /R3 ) (23)
µ, represents external shocks to migration and the term
psi, ψ, represents the sensitivity of net immigration to where ρ > 1 is the regulation parameter (set initially to
GDP. A similar expression captures the flow into other 2), and P the pollution index defined in Eq. (9) and R
employment, which also depends positively on GDP, are scaling parameters (set to 1 and 3000, respectively).
and negatively on output of the two competing sectors. Regulation is expressed as an index, 0 ≤ RA ≤ 1. As
pollution rises, regulation becomes exponentially more
DLO = o1 Y ζ1 − o2 hζ2 − o3 F ζ3 (20) severe (Engle and Valderrama, 2002).
The omega terms, o, represent shocks to non-marine Regulation of traditional fishing is given by
sector employment arising from general economic RE = σx−R5 (24)
activity (subscript 1), the traditional fishing sector (sub-
script 2), and the aquaculture sector (subscript 3). The where σ > 0 is the regulation parameter (set initially
zeta terms, ζ, represent the sensitivity of non-marine to 1), and x the biomass and R is a scaling parame-
sector employment to GDP (subscript 1), catch (sub- ter (set initially to 0.45). Regulation is expressed as
script 2) and aquaculture (subscript 3). The flow into an index, 0 ≤ RE ≤ 1. As the biomass declines, reg-
aquaculture-related employment depends primarily on ulation becomes exponentially more severe. This is
essentially a mathematical interpretation of a common
sense view of how fishing should be regulated and
7 Since 1998, official statistics on fishing effort in Scotland are
the departure from linearity could have various expla-
regarded as highly unreliable. In checks carried out by FRS Marine
Laboratory, for some statistical rectangles, as little as 10% of real
nations, e.g. reflecting an initially slow management
fishing effort by the Scottish fleet entered official records (A. Shanks, response to declining stocks or, alternatively, express-
Personnel communication). ing a risk averse management strategy in which bigger
280 W.D. McCausland et al. / Ecological Modelling 193 (2006) 271–294

declines require increasingly drastic action to avoid a Table 2


risk of stock collapse (see, e.g. Hilborn and Walters, Nomenclature
1992). In practice, quotas often operate as to produce a Parameter Value
step function; what we have here is a smoothed approx- A: Antibiotics 0.02%
imation. a: Ash 9.3%
The model is formulated as a deterministic sec- B: Benthos 100
BOD: Biochemical oxidation demand Eq. (9)
toral model based on difference equations programmed C: Total costs of aquaculture production
using STELLA Research v 5.1 High Performance Sys- c: Carbohydrate 15%
tems Inc. The STELLA software has previously been D: Change operator
used for biological models simulating nitrogen dynam- d: Demand for aquaculture final product
ics in shrimp aquaculture (Montoya et al., 1999a,b; d̄: Autonomous demand for aquaculture final product 3300
GF: Gross feed input 100000
Montoya et al., 2002). E: Fishing effort 500
e: Technological change parameter 1
2.2. Model evaluation F: Production (aquaculture) 772
f: Fibre 1.3%
In order to run the simulation a set of values was h: Catch
j: Pollution scaling parameter 1000
assumed. Specifically, a systematic analysis was con- LA: Labour employed in aquaculture 300
ducted of the effect of extreme values (as opposed LF: Total labour force 1750
to marginal changes) of parameters and input val- LO: Labour employed in other, non-marine, sectors 900
ues (“factors”) upon simulation responses. Identifica- LU: Unemployed 50
tion of factors that are “important” was informed by K: Capital input (aquaculture) 1
l: Lipid 16%
the relevant economic and biological theories detailed M: Price of Imports 1000
throughout the paper and in particular in Section m: Mark-up parameter 0.05
2. As further simulation runs were conducted, fac- N: Nitrogen settleable Eq. (9)
tors that were revealed to be “unimportant” could be P: Pollution index
sequentially eliminated, and considered to be con- p: Protein (%in feed ration) 50%
Q: Phosphorus 1.2%
stants. Known signs were then verified. The model Q : Phosphorus discharge settable Eq. (9)
was run assuming an equilibrium of 772 tonnes of pro- q: Catchability quotient 1
duction of farmed fish (Table 2). Fishing effort was R1 : Regulation scaling parameter 80
initially set to 500 (days) with a catchability quotient R2 : Regulation scaling parameter 22
normalized to 1 and with an equilibrium catch of 4000 R3 : Regulation scaling parameter 5000
R4 : Regulation scaling parameter 0.02
(tonnes). A feed quality of 1 was assumed and with R5 : Regulation scaling parameter 0.45
capital input being the numeraire (1). Technology was r: Regeneration rate of wild population 0.02
also normalized to 1 and gross feed input was taken S: Aquaculture sales function
to be 1,00,000 (tonnes). Autonomous demand for the SS: Total suspended solids Eq. (9)
final product was 3300 in equilibrium. This was based V: Feed Quality 1
w: Cost scaling parameter 1200
on an input price of 1000 a mark up parameter of 5% X: Escapes Eq. (15)
and a cost scaling parameter of 1200. GDP was nor- x: Biomass 100000
malized to 1. The total labour force was assumed to be Y: GDP 1
1750 of which 300 were employed in aquaculture and z: Transform of price elasticity of demand (−)1000
900 were employed in other non-marine sectors and 50 α: Effort-output elasticity 1.232
β: Stock output elasticity 0.424
were unemployed. The balance of the remaining 500 χ: Output-gross feed elasticity 0.330
was employed in the traditional fishing. The sensitiv- δ: Protein digestibility for the feed ration 90%
ity of the model to variations in the forcing parameters ε: Proportion of aquaculture stock escaping 0.2
was explored. The model tested the following scenar- φ1 : Aquaculture employment shock wrt production 0.01
ios: Regulation of traditional fishing and regulation of φ2 : Aquaculture employment shock wrt catch 0.001
γ: Technology-output elasticity 0.021
aquaculture, improvements in feed quality, changes in
economic conditions and changes in technology.
W.D. McCausland et al. / Ecological Modelling 193 (2006) 271–294 281

Table 2 (Continued ) (2001). His analysis showed that optimal harvest levels
Parameter Value vary over time and labour dynamics can depend sig-
η1 : Fishing effort shock wrt catch 0.01 nificantly on the constraints placed on fishing effort.
η2 : Fishing effort shock wrt aquaculture 0.01 The effect of increased regulation on the fished stock
ι1 : Catch to employment shock elasticity 0.5 biomass in the model is positive. However, if the stock
ι2 : Aquaculture to employment shock elasticity 0.5 has already been severely depleted, as in the North-
κ: Capital-output elasticity 0.267
λ: Labour-output elasticity 0.128
west Atlantic cod fishery (Swain and Sinclair, 2000),
µ: Immigration shock 0.01 increased regulation may not lead to recovery, certainly
ν: Sensitivity of gross feed input to demand 0.7 not within a short time-scale.
о1 : Other employment shock wrt GDP 0.001 The impact on aquaculture production of insti-
о2 : Other employment shock wrt catch 0.001 tutional and environmental changes depends on the
о3 : Other employment shock wrt aquaculture 0.001
π: Market price of aquaculture production
nature of these changes. Incentives for producers to
θ: Sensitivity of aquaculture sales to import prices 0.08 supply more to the market increase with grants, infras-
ρ: Regulation parameter aquaculture 1.5 tructure development and availability of credit. Nev-
σ: Regulation parameter traditional fishing 1 ertheless, government regulations may also impact on
τ: Natural out migration parameter −0.05 the supply of salmon in that they may limit the areas
υ: Pollution sensitivity of benthos 1
ξ 1 : Aquaculture output to employment shock elasticity 0.5
in which farming can occur, the size of farms and the
ξ 2 : Catch to employment shock elasticity 0.5 operation of those farms, which affects their produc-
ψ: GDP-immigration elasticity 0.5 tion (Kaiser and Stead, 2002). Regulations pertaining to
ζ: Non-marine output to employment shock elasticity 0.5 aquaculture activity were developed in Europe and are
ζ 2 : Catch to employment shock elasticity 0.5 widely regarded as severe when compared to the rate
ζ 3 : Aquaculture output to employment shock elasticity 0.5
y: Income
of introduction and nature of similar regulations in the
agriculture industry (Kaiser and Stead, 2002). In 1995,
Howarth observed that “the task of the policy maker and
The aim of the sensitivity analysis was to vary the legislator is to reconcile the needs of the environment
parameters over a certain range and compare their rela- with the facilitation of an efficient aquaculture industry
tive influence on the end result. This exercise resulted in which functions in the common interest of all”.
the identification of coefficients with important effects The model showed that an increase in regulation
on the model simulations. Validation of the data (that is, of aquaculture by 50% causes a one-off fall in farmed
choice of initial values of factors) was conducted pri- fish production, but does not stem the growth rate in the
marily through econometric estimation of biological sector as a whole (Fig. 4). Hence, employment in aqua-
and economic relationships obtained from the perti- culture continues to rise. The government can restrict
nent literature. The references are detailed in Section 2 the production level in an effort to reduce pollution or to
for each relationship as appropriate. Within each sub- ensure that production is dispersed among coastal areas
system some normalisation also was conducted. A full where employment opportunities are needed. Model
description of the calibration data and definition of vari- output indicates that pollution falls in response to the
ables is contained in Table 2. one-off fall in production, but then rises again in tan-
dem with the growth of fish production. However, if the
level of pollution is considered to have exceeded a pre-
3. Results and discussion determined level, the regulatory authority may require
a further reduction in waste output by requiring fur-
3.1. Regulation of traditional fishing and ther reduction in fish production (SEPA, 1998). The
regulation of aquaculture regulatory authorities undertake an initial site evalu-
ation to determine the potential impact, they estab-
The model showed that an increase in regulation of lish a level of production which does not result in
traditional fishing by 50% causes a fall in catch and enrichment exceeding a predetermined level and ini-
a fall in employment in the traditional fishing sector tiate a monitoring programme to ensure that the level
(Fig. 3). This is in line with the finding of Charles of impact remains below the predetermined acceptable
282
W.D. McCausland et al. / Ecological Modelling 193 (2006) 271–294
Fig. 3. Effect of regulation of traditional fishing on (a) labour in fishing, (b) labour in aquaculture, (c) unemployment, (d) catch, fish production, (e) demand of aquaculture, and (f)
biomass.
W.D. McCausland et al. / Ecological Modelling 193 (2006) 271–294
Fig. 4. Effect of regulation of aquaculture on (a) labour in fishing, (b) labour in aquaculture, (c) unemployment, (d) catch, (e) fish production, (f) demand of aquaculture, and (g)
biomass.

283
284
W.D. McCausland et al. / Ecological Modelling 193 (2006) 271–294
Fig. 5. Effect of parameter feed quality on (a) labour in fishing, (b) labour in aquaculture, (c) unemployment, (d) catch, (e) fish production, (f) demand of aquaculture, and (g)
biomass.
W.D. McCausland et al. / Ecological Modelling 193 (2006) 271–294 285

level (SEPA, 1998). The costs incurred to minimise land 1998/1999). Advertising, negative or positive (i.e.
environmental impacts will constrain the supply of fish fish is good for people’s health) is largely designed
and the prices. to influence buyers’ preferences. Trends in the human
population size and habits also affect the total demand
3.2. Improvements in feed quality as well as imports and exports. In the UK, imports
are particularly important for white fish (cod and had-
Improvements in husbandry factors such as temper- dock), whereas, exports seem to be more confined to
ature, feeding frequency and feed technology are likely the pelagic species (SEAFISH, 2002). Other factors
to reduce the rate of waste production and increase the like bad weather, jellyfish losses, industrial agricultural
production of fish. The model showed that an improve- and domestic sewage outfalls, and oil spills, affect the
ment in feed quality of 10% generates a rise in fish supply and the market of the [farmed fish] product.
production and a consequent rise in employment in that
sector (Fig. 5). Regulation of aquaculture also responds 3.4. Changes in technology
to the increase in production by increasing regula-
tion. This generates [damped] cyclical behaviour of Fishing efficiency has been improved as technol-
fish production leading to the new equilibrium, which ogy has developed with modern fishing gears (changes
in turn yields cyclical behaviour of costs and hence in regulation about minimum mesh sizes) and tech-
prices in the sector. Digestibility values of feed are cur- niques. The model suggests that an increase in the
rently around 90% and FCR values (currently 1.17 for catchability quotient by 10% does little to stem the
salmon) have improved since the early 1980s. If the decline in traditional fishing, but, as might be expected,
FCR can be reduced to 1.0, feed wastage to 1% and increases the rate of decline of the biomass (Fig. 8).
indigestibility to 5% the release rate of dissolved nitro- Fishers are highly innovative and will always strive
gen would be approximately 33 kg/tonne of production to improve their catching efficiency (Jennings et al.,
(Davies, 2000). Overfeeding is likely when the value 2001). However, there is an increasing interest in the
of the product is high and the cost of the feed is low, development of highly selective gears that allow non-
with greater care being taken of an expensive feed prod- target species and by-catches to escape. The 1990’s
uct. Although in the early years of the Atlantic salmon have seen a considerable increase in the use of technol-
farming industry, feed losses were up to 20% it is now ogy on fish farms and increased mechanisation of farm
generally accepted that feed losses have been reduced operations drawing on a well-developed research sup-
to less than 5% in well-run farms (Davenport et al., port base and targeted research programmes. A consid-
2003). erable improvement to the production process in order
to improve efficiency by using technological develop-
3.3. Changes in economic conditions ment has been achieved by (ICES, 2002). Most salmon
farms now operate sophisticated computer programs
The consumption of salmon in the UK grew signifi- for recording and forecasting fish numbers and weights
cantly during the 1990s as supplies increased and prices cage by cage as well as costs and sales (Sutherland and
dropped (Stead and Laird, 2002). The model showed Calyton, 2002). Better feeds and improved husbandry
that a rise in autonomous demand of 3% increases fish are examples of such a technological advance.
production at first, followed by cyclical adjustment to
a new equilibrium only just higher than the original 3.5. Policy/regulations
(Fig. 6). This is due to the effect of regulation of aqua-
culture increasing in response to the rise in production. There are concerns that coastal fisheries are not sus-
A doubling of mark-up to 10% generates a much more tainable at present levels, and that aquaculture may
long lasting effect on fish production, again with over- be adversely affecting fisheries (Naylor et al., 2000).
shooting (Fig. 7). A significant impact on the demand of Bardach (1997) observed that the employment and wel-
farmed fish can be caused by the negative publicity that fare of local and non-local people need to be considered
aquaculture pollutes the environment and spreads dis- in the conflicting social environment that has devel-
eases outbreaks (Infectious Salmon Anaemia in Scot- oped in Scotland, and that natural resources should be
286
W.D. McCausland et al. / Ecological Modelling 193 (2006) 271–294
Fig. 6. Effect of parameter auto demand on (a) labour in fishing, (b) labour in aquaculture, (c) unemployment, (d) catch, (e) fish production, (f) demand of aquaculture, and (g)
biomass.
W.D. McCausland et al. / Ecological Modelling 193 (2006) 271–294
Fig. 7. Effect of regulation of parameter mark up aqua on (a) labour in fishing, (b) labour in aquaculture, (c) unemployment, (d) catch, (e) fish production, (f) demand of aquaculture,
and (g) biomass.

287
288
W.D. McCausland et al. / Ecological Modelling 193 (2006) 271–294
Fig. 8. Effect of regulation of parameter technology on (a) labour in fishing, (b) labour in aquaculture, (c) unemployment, (d) catch, (e) fish production, (f) demand of aquaculture,
and (g) biomass.
W.D. McCausland et al. / Ecological Modelling 193 (2006) 271–294 289

shared with all potential users in a way that will benefit on the environment, these potential effects are sys-
the society while not harming the ecosystem. tematically addressed in a formal environmental state-
In addition, there are perceived to be environmen- ment. Economic incentives and constraints (pollution
tal problems with aquaculture that may be threatening charges; access charges, tradable permits for resource
capture fisheries. In recent years, the harvest of fish use) to promote environmentally and socially friendly
from natural waters in many European fishing grounds aquaculture require legislation and implementation at
apparently has reached its upper limit, but the demand provincial or national government levels (GESAMP,
for fishery products is still high (FAO, 2002). Thus 2001). Financial incentives for sustainable produc-
policies must be devised to conserve existing natural tion could be granted to aquaculture projects where
environmental resource stocks. Such policies need not, investments are directed towards the implementation
however, result in the cessation of aquaculture devel- techniques that significantly decrease environmental
opment (Bardach, 1997). As noted by Cromey et al. impacts as well as participating on monitoring schemes
(2000) and Henderson et al. (2001), it is important (AQCESS, 2000).
to base the debate on verifiable and updated scientific
facts, testable hypothesis and transparent modelling of 3.6. Changes in economic conditions
the interactions between production, environment and
economic welfare. Overcapitalisation and overfishing, brought about
The model suggests contrasting outcomes from by a market failure, have adverse effects on the envi-
increased regulation in fisheries and aquaculture. ronment (e.g. reduction in stock sizes of target and non-
Although an increase in regulation of aquaculture target species, damage to the sea bed). In aquaculture
causes a short-term fall in farmed fish production, there are no comparable problems but overcapitalisa-
employment in aquaculture continues to rise pro- tion exists where there has been extensive government
vided that the demand for the aquaculture products support or subsidy.
remains strong. This reflects the ability of the aqua- Although activity in a wild fishery may be con-
culture facilities to satisfy the regulation requirements strained by costs of capital equipment in the long run,
through improving provisions for environmental pro- in the short run this is not so because the capital equip-
tection without the need to limit employment. In con- ment has already been purchased and written-off in
trast, increased regulation in the fishery sector tends to the enterprises’ accounts. If stocks are in decline, there
reduce employment in the sector as regulation directly will be an excess of capital. Aside from regulatory
targets the economic activity though limits imposed on restrictions, pressure on the fished stocks depends not
landings and days at sea, as well as decommissioning only on the condition of the stocks and capital costs,
schemes. but also on the level of demand, which remains high
It is important that local government should under- and rising. However, an examination of past invest-
stand the economic values and social benefits of aqua- ment, profit level and incomes shows that they are
culture, including its potential role in providing work vulnerable to the natural variability of stocks, which
for unemployed fishermen. Failure to address aquacul- can change the situation significantly in the short
ture development issues at the local level could result run.
in socio-economic complications and instability in the The markets for fish and fish products are in a state
rural areas. of upheaval caused by two rather separate develop-
In Europe, an integral part of the process of deter- ments. The first is a global increase in the demand
mining applications for marine fish farms, renewal for fish; the second one involves a rise in high-income
of existing leases or extensions to existing develop- demand and changes in consumer behaviour, especially
ments is the environmental impact assessment (EIA) in wealthy countries. The model showed that a rise in
(Fernandes et al., 2000, 2001). EIA can be a pow- demand increases farmed fish production at first fol-
erful tool, which can ensure that decisions are made lowed by cyclical adjustment to a new equilibrium only
on the basis of the best information. The process of just higher than the original. The market is the driv-
completing and evaluating EIAs seek to ensure that, ing force of aquaculture development; production and
where a development is likely to have significant effects demand are finely balanced and any increase in pro-
290 W.D. McCausland et al. / Ecological Modelling 193 (2006) 271–294

duction in excess of the likely evolution in demand levels. However, events in 1998–1999 have shown how
may result in steep decrease in price and profitability. volatile this market can be and further disruptions are
Possible solutions to maintain prices include enlarg- likely. If the growing aquaculture industry is to sustain
ing the range of products must be enlarged and bet- its contribution to world fish supplies, it must reduce
ter marketing strategies. Although private investors wild fish inputs in feed (Naylor et al., 2000). Alterna-
are the leading force, the state can play a key role tives protein source to replace fishmeal (e.g. soya) in
in ensuring that economic viability will be achieved an objectively serious manner with solid scientific sup-
in parallel with respect of the environment and good port and methods of reducing the discharge of feed from
quality of the products. To secure employment and farms are currently investigated. Carbohydrates can be
socio-economic well being, aquaculture needs to be used as an alternative to fishmeal. Inclusion rates of
an economically viable and self-sufficient industry. In fishmeal in aquafeeds vary widely according to species,
contrast to capture fisheries, aquaculture allows conti- the life cycle stage for which the feed is intended and
nuity of supply, size and quality assurance of fish. These the composition of the fishmeal available. It would be a
features are particularly attractive to the food process- mistake to ignore the significance of fish oils as a com-
ing industries (MacAlister Elliott and Partners Ltd., ponent of the food. There is a risk that quality fish oils
1999). could prove to be the more finite commodity in the next
decade as aquaculture is projected to use 87% of world
3.7. Improvements in feed quality supply in 2010. This has obvious implications for the
salmon sector and others where much of the dietary
Improved feed quality and usage in aquaculture energy is provided as oil at present. Furthermore, more
results in better growth and survival of the farmed research on fish physiology to better understand the
fish, feed cost savings, less usage of dietary protein metabolic requirements of fish and on feed ingredients
(sparing proteins), less wastage of feed resources, min- and health management will help aquaculture produc-
imizes nutrient discharges from aquaculture to the tion to expand.
environment and ensures the sustainability of aquacul-
ture (Dosdat, 2001). The results of this study showed 3.8. Technology
that improvement in feed quality generates improve-
ment in fish production and employment. The use of Fish farming involves the use of a variety of organic
fishmeal in fish feeds is determined by an economic chemicals and pharmaceuticals. In Norway 6 g of
rationale; when fishmeal prices increase, feed formu- antibiotics was required for each tonne of produc-
lators use alternative protein sources from plants (soy, tion in 1996 versus 900 g/tonne of production in 1987
corn, wheat) to replace them in land animal feeds. (Noakes et al., 2000). This is a good example of how the
Fishmeal is produced almost exclusively from small technological progress (development of vaccines) and
pelagic fish (living in the surface waters or middle the improvement in stock management had a positive
depths of the sea), for which there is little or no demand effect on production within one decade. The develop-
for human consumption although harvesting for such ment of vaccines, the better husbandry and hygiene
species is not free from ecological costs. World pro- and fallowing in the case of Atlantic salmon farming
duction of fishmeal has remained static over the last have reduced the use of antibiotics in marine aqua-
decade at 6–7 million tonnes and is likely to remain culture (Costello et al., 2001). The best management
so over the next decade, provided that El Niño events option at corporate level is to take advantage of tech-
do not cause dramatic changes. In 2000, no more than nological advances to reduce production costs and to
34% of world fishmeal production went into fish feed develop more environmentally friendly (or acceptable)
(European Commission, 19/9/2002). The estimate for practices, coupled with research on species diversifica-
2010 has recently been revised upwards to 2.83 million tion and product differentiation. Recently technologi-
tonnes or some 44% of likely supply. It seems likely cal changes have been directed towards the quality of
that the underlying trend will be for fishmeal prices the final product, addressing “ecological” (i.e.. “envi-
to drift, rather than accelerate, upwards over the next ronmentally friendly”) labelling and animal welfare,
decade from a realistic starting point at pre-El Niño which have been of concern.
W.D. McCausland et al. / Ecological Modelling 193 (2006) 271–294 291

3.9. The labour market in the coastal community profitability need not necessarily be achieved by intro-
ducing ITQs, but this could be an effective mechanism
Aquaculture not only contributes substantially to to reduce fleet capacity, and it is noticeable that the
fish supplies but also provides alternative employment Icelandic and Dutch harvesting sectors, which use this
in many fisheries-dependent regions. approach, achieve significantly better relative earnings
The arrival of aquaculture in rural communities than other countries.
appears to have a positive impact on employment Employment prospects in fisheries are not encourag-
within these areas. In the west coast of Scotland, aqua- ing over the short term. Present policies (grants for ves-
culture provides an important source of employment sels and infrastructure, despite restricted entry through
for local people in areas where there are very few alter- licensing, and constraints on inputs of “effort”), have
native job opportunities. The main reason why individ- almost certainly led to excessive investment in capi-
uals began working in fish farming was the lack of alter- tal relative to the use of labour. This may be corrected
native employment in the local area (just under 60% by an improved management regime, but only in the
of fish farmers said there was no other employment context of a further reduction of capacity. Technical
opportunities available to them), and lack of alternative advances combined with limited or depleted stock pro-
employment is also the main reason why aquaculture duction can be expected progressively to reduce the use
workers stay in the industry (just under a half of fish of labour.
farmers stay in aquaculture because of the lack of other The European fleet may be more capital-intensive
jobs in their community) (AQCESS, 2000). than it should be, and there are also almost certainly
In recent years, aquaculture has been the only seg- more vessels than needed, given local fishing opportu-
ment of the fisheries industry in the European Com- nities. Despite marginal returns, incentives to remain
munity to experience a rise in employment, and it in the fishery mean that these vessels are employing
accounts for approximately 60,000 full-time equiva- crew, thus offsetting somewhat the impact of excessive
lent jobs mostly in coastal and rural areas. In 1998, fish capitalisation on total employment, but at the risk of
processing provided employment for a further 89,468 delaying stock recovery.
individuals (Green Paper). In 1998, aquaculture in the It should not be expected that fish stock recovery will
EU employed at least 80,000 full or part-time work- lead to significantly increased landings and employ-
ers (European Commission, 19/9/2002). Employment ment in European capture fisheries over a short time
has remained steady or has declined in aquaculture in horizon. In addition to other factors, climatic change
Greece and Norway although a rise in production was has not been favourable to high production, and eco-
achieved from 1993 and onwards. The primary cause logical changes have been noted (Parsons and Lear,
to his rationalisation of labour or shedding was a fall 2001). The currently accepted precautionary approach
in prices. Small-scale producers are finding it increas- will encourage lower levels of access in order to sup-
ingly difficult to survive. However, there are no data port a balanced ecosystem, and will likely limit TACs
series available on employment of 3 years or more in available to fishing enterprises over at least a decadal
most of the European countries. time scale.
Aquaculture is of growing importance socio- Prospects for the promotion and development of
economically within the European Union. It may pro- alternative employment and earnings opportunities
vide part-time additional revenue for fishermen or such as aquaculture or tourism in order to absorb excess
other workers displaced from the fisheries sector. The supply labour due to contraction of the fisheries sector
depleted stock conditions of groundfish in northern and enhance individuals’ socio-economic welfare are
European seas suggest that maintaining income even important for the labour market in the coastal commu-
at the present depressed levels will be difficult, and nities. The model predicts that aquaculture provides
marginal enterprises are likely to leave the indus- an alternative employment in the coastal communi-
try; possibly encouraged by active fleet downsizing ties especially when there is an increased regulation
measures. Although more precautionary management to preserve the wild stock. Fishing and aquaculture
could reverse current declines in landings and stocks, is the dominant occupation in mainly rural commu-
this is unlikely to occur over the short term. Improved nities where the activity (or inactivity) in the sector
292 W.D. McCausland et al. / Ecological Modelling 193 (2006) 271–294

determines the pace of economic development. Mobil- Bardach, J.E., 1997. Sustainable Aquaculture. John Wiley and Sons
ity of labour is an attribute of the versatility of the Inc., Canada, 251 pp.
human resource and its rationalisation is an essential Beveridge, M.C.M., 1996. Cage Aquaculture. Fishing News Books
Ltd., Oxford, 352 pp.
ingredient for efficient functioning of the fishing and BioMar, 2000. BioMar’s Complete Feeding Quide for Salmon. Copy
aquaculture industry and effective environmental pol- number 478. Grangemouth, Scotland, 110 pp.
icy relating to reversing the process of inshore stock Black, K.D., 2001. Environmental Impacts of Aquaculture. Sheffield,
depletion. In addition, “sticky” or immobile labour may Academic Press and CRC Press, Sheffield, UK, 214 pp.
render a well-articulated management policy ineffec- Butler, J.R.A., 2002. Wild salmonids and sea louse infestations on
the west coast of Scotland: sources of infection and implications
tual thus increasing the problems of redundant labour in for the management of marine salmon farms. Pest Manage. Sci.
fisheries and inshore stock depletion. In Scotland, there 58, 595–608.
is considerable potential mobility between the fishing Charles, A., 2001. Sustainable Fishery Systems. Fish Biology and
and aquaculture occupations: just under a third of fish Aquatic Resources Series. Blackwell Science, Oxford, UK, 350
farmers would be prepared to work in aquaculture and pp.
Costello, M.J., Grant, A., Davies, I.M., Cecchini, S., Papoutsoglou,
just under a third of fish farmers would be willing to S., Quigley, D., Saroglia, M., 2001. The control of chemicals
be fishermen (AQCESS, 2000). used in aquaculture in Europe. J. Appl. Ichthyol. 17, 173–180.
Another important issue, and one that will influ- Cromey, C.J., Nickell, T.D., Black, K.D., 2000. DEPOMOD. A
ence the level of labour mobility between the sectors model for predicting the effects of solids deposition from mari-
in coastal economies, is fishermen’s and aquaculture culture to the benthos. Oban Scotland, ISBN 0-9529089-1-3, 120
pp.
workers’ attitudes towards their jobs and why they Davenport, J., Black, K., Burnell, G., Cross, T., Culloty, S., Ekarathe,
choose to stay working in these occupations. In Scot- S., Furness, B., Mulcahy, M., Thetmeyer, H., 2003. Aquaculture
land around 60% of aquaculture workers began work- the Ecological Issues. Blackwell, Oxford, UK, 90 pp.
ing in aquaculture because there were no other employ- Davies, I.M., 2000. Waste production by farmed Atlantic salmon
ment opportunities available to them (AQCESS, 2000). Salmo salar in Scotland. ICES, CM 2000/0:01.
Davies, I.M., Rae, G., 2003. Study for Research into Aquaculture
This indicates the usefulness of the aquaculture indus- Fish Carrying Capacity of GB Coastal Waters. FRS, Aberdeen,
try in enhancing employment in coastal communi- 25 pp.
ties, especially if employment in the fishing industry De Silva, S.S., Anderson, T.A., 1995. Fish Nutrition in Aquaculture.
declines. Chapman and Hall, London, 309 pp.
DG Fisheries, 17.01.03. http://europa.eu.int/comm/fisheries/reform/
index en.htm. Reforming the Common Fisheries Policy.
Dosdat, A., 2001. Environmental impact of aquaculture in the
Acknowledgements Mediterranean: nutritional and feeding aspects. In: Proceedings
of the Seminar of the CIHEAM Network on Technology of Aqu-
This research was funded by the European Union, culture in the Mediterranean, vol. 55, Zaragossa, 17–21 January
project “Aquaculture and coastal economic and social 2000. Cahiers Options Mediterraneennes, pp. 23–36.
sustainability” (AQCESS), Contract No. Q5RS-2000- Duarte, P., Meneses, R., Hawkins, A.J.S., Zhu, M., Fang, J., Grant,
J., 2003. Mathematical modelling to assess the carrying capacity
31151. The authors wish to express thanks to all the for multi-species culture within coastal waters. Ecol. Model. 168,
members of the AQCESS team for valuable comments. 109–143.
Enell, M., 1995. Environmental impact of nutrients from Nordic fish
farming. Water Sci. Technol. 3110, 61–71.
References Engle, C.R., Valderrama, D., 2002. The economics of environmen-
tal impacts of aquaculture in the United States. In: Tomasso,
J.R. (Ed.), Aquaculture and the Environment in the United
Agar, J.J., Sutinen, J.G., 2004. Rebuilding strategies for multispecies
States, vol. 247–270. U.S. Aquaculture Society, A Chapter of
fisheries: A stylized bioeconomic model. Environ. Res. Econ. 28,
the World Aquaculture Society, Baton Rouge, Louisianan, USA,
1–29.
p. 279.
Anon, 2002. Report of the ICES Advisory Committee on Fisheries
European Commission 19/9/2002. A strategy for the Sustainable
Management. ICES Cooperative Research Report No 255, Inter-
Development of European Aquaculture. Communication from
national Council for the Exploration of the Sea, Copenhagen,
the Commission to the Council and the European Parliament,
Denmark.
24 pp.
AQCESS (Aquaculture and coastal economic and social sustainabil-
European Commission 2000. Regional Socio-Economic Studies on
ity), 2000. Fifth Framework Project. Contract No. Q5RS-2000-
Employment and the Level of Dependency on Fishing. Lot. No.
31151. http://www.abdn.ac.uk/aqcess/.
W.D. McCausland et al. / Ecological Modelling 193 (2006) 271–294 293

23 Coordination and Consolidation Study. Fisheries Sub-Sector Henderson, A., Gamito, S., Karakassis, I., Pederson, P., Smaal, A.,
Strategy Paper, 53 pp. 2001. Use of hydrodynamic and benthic models for managing
European Commission 2002. Financial Instrument for Fisheries environmental impacts of marine aquaculture. J. Appl. Ichthyol.
Guidance—Instructions for Use. ISBN 92-894-1647-5, 47 17, 163–172.
pp. http://europa.eu.int/comm/fisheries/doc et publ/liste publi/ Henderson, A.R., Davies, I.M., 2000. Review of aquaculture, its
facts/ifop en.pdf. regulation and monitoring in Scotland. J. Appl. Ichthyol. 16,
European Commission, 2001. Facts and Figures on the CFP-Basic 200–208.
Data on the Common Fisheries Policy. ISBN 92-894-1842-7, 28 Hilborn, R., Walters, C.J., 1992. Quantitative Fish Stock Assessment:
pp. http://europa.eu.int/comm/fisheries/doc et publ/liste publi/ Choice Dynamics and Uncertainty. Chapman and Hall, London,
facts/pcp en.pdf. 570 pp.
FAO, 2002. The State of World Fisheries and Aquaculture. FAO Holby, O., Hall, P.O.J., 1991. Chemical fluxes and mass balances
Fisheries Department, Rome, ISBN 92-5-104842-8. in a marine fish cage farm. II. Phosphorus. Marine Ecol. Progr.
Fernandes, T.F., Eleftheriou, A., Ackefors, H., Eleftheriou, M., Ervik, Series 70, 263–272.
A., Sanchez-Mata, A., Scanlon, T., White, P., Cochrane, S., Pear- Holmer, M., 1992. Impacts of aquaculture on surrounding sediments:
son, T.H., Read, P.A., 2001. The scientific principles underlying generation of organic-rich sediments. In: De Pauw, N., Joyce, J.
the monitoring of the environmental impacts of aquaculture. J. (Eds.), Aquaculture and the Environment, Special Publication
Appl. Ichthyol. 17, 181–193. No. 16. European Aquaculture Society, pp. 155–175.
Fernandes, T.F., Miller, K.L., Read, P.A., 2000. Monitoring and reg- ICES, 2002. Report of the Working Group on Environmental Inter-
ulation of marine aquaculture in Europe. J. Appl. Ichthyol. 16, actions of Mariculture, ICES headquarters, 8–12 April, 50 pp.
138–143. Jennings, S., Kaiser, M.J., Reynolds, J.D., 2001. Marine Fisheries
GESAMP, IMO/FAO/UNESCO-IOC/WMO/WHO/IAEA/UN/ Ecology. Blackwell Science, Oxford.
UNEP Joint Group of Experts on the Scientific Aspects of Jimenez-Montealegre, R., Verdegem, M.C.J., van Dam, A., Ver-
Marine Environemtal Protection, 1996.The contributions of reth, J.A.J., 2002. Conceptualization and validation of a dynamic
science to coastal zone management. Rep. Stud. GESAMP 61, model for the simulation of nitrogen transformations and fluxes
66 pp. in fish ponds. Ecol. Model. 147 (2), 123–152.
GESAMP, IMO/FAO/UNESCO-IOC/WMO/WHO/IAEA/UN/ Kaiser, M., Stead, S.M., 2002. Uncertainties and values in European
UNEP Joint Group of Experts on the Scientific Aspects of aquaculture: communication, management and policy issues
Marine Environemtal Protection, 2001. Planning and manage- in time of “changing public perceptions”. Aquacult. Int. 10,
ment for sustainable coastal aquaculture development. Rep. 469–490.
Stud. GESAMP 68, ISBN 92-5-104634-4, 90 pp. Karagiannis, G., Katranidis, S.D., 2000. A production function anal-
Gordon, R.G., 1976. Recent developments in the theory of inflation ysis of seabass and seabeam production in Greece. J. World
and unemployment. J. Monetary Econ. 2, 185–219. Aquacult. Soc. 313, 297–305.
Goulding, I., Hallam, D., Harrison-Mayfield, L., Mackenzie-Hill, Karakassis, I., Tsapakis, M., Hatziyanni, E., 1998. Seasonal variabil-
V., Helder DaSilva, 2000. Regional Socio-economics Studies on ity in sediment profiles beneath fish farm cages in the Mediter-
Employment and the Level of dependency on fishing. Lot No 23. ranean. Marine Ecol. Progr. Series 162, 243–252.
Coordiantion and Consolidation Study. European Commission Karakassis, I., Hatziyanni, E., Tsapakis, M., Plaiti, W., 1999. Benthic
DG Fisheries. Fisheries sub-sector Strategy Paper, 50 pp. recovery following cessation of fish farming: a series of suc-
Green Paper: The Future of the Common Fisheries Policy on the cesses and catastrophes. Marine Ecol. Progr. Series 184, 205–
EU Online website: http://europa.eu.int/comm/fisheries/doc et 218.
publ/green/volume1 en.pdf. Kochba, M., Diab, S., Avnimelech, Y., 1994. Modeling of nitro-
Hall, P.O.J., Anderson, L.G., Holby, O., Kollberg, S., Samuelsson, gen transformation in intensively aerated fish ponds. Aquaculture
M.-O., 1990. Chemical fluxes and mass balances in a marine fish 120, 95–104.
cage farm. I. Carbon. Marine Ecol. Progr. Series 61, 61–73. Lorenzen, K., Struve, J., Cowan, V.J., 1997. Impact of farming inten-
Hall, P.O.J., Holby, O., Kollberg, S., Samuelsson, M.O., 1992. Chem- sity and water management on nitrogen dynamics in intensive
ical fluxes and mass balances in a marine fish cage farm. IV. pond culture: a mathematical model applied to Thai commercial
Nitrogen. Marine Ecol. Progr. Series 89, 81–91. shrimp farms. Aquacult. Res. 28, 493–507.
Hargrave, B.T., Duplisea, D.E., Pdeiffer, E., Wildish, D.J., 1993. MacAlister Elliott and Partners Ltd., 1999. Forward Study of
Seasonal changes in benthic fluxes of dissolved oxygen and Community Aquaculture: Summary Report. Brussels: European
ammonium associated with marine cultured Atlantic salmon. Commission Fisheries Directorate General, 60 pp.
Marine Ecol. Prog. Series 96, 157–249. Marshall, C.T., Yaragina, N.A., Adlandsvik, B., Dolgov, A.V., 2000.
Hargreaves, J.A., 1997. A simulation model of ammonia dynamics Reconstructing the stock-recruit relationship for Northeast Arctic
in commercial catfish ponds in the southeastern United States. cod using a bioenergetic index of reproductive potential. Can. J.
Aquacult. Eng. 16, 27–43. Fish. Aquat. Sci. 57, 2433–2442.
Henderson, A., Davies, I.M., 2001. Review of the Regulation Montoya, R.A., Lawrence, A.R., Grant, W.E., Velaso, M., 1999a.
and Monitoring of Aquaculture in Scotland, with Emphasis Simulation of nitrogen dynamics and shrimp growth in an inten-
on Environment and Consumer Protection. Marine Laboratory sive shrimp culture: effects of feed and feeding parameters. Ecol.
Aberdeen, Report No 01/01, 30 pp. Model. 122, 81–95.
294 W.D. McCausland et al. / Ecological Modelling 193 (2006) 271–294

Montoya, R.A., Lawrence, A.L., Grant, W.E., Velasco, M., 1999b. Laubier, L., Reish, D.J. (Eds.), Actes de la 4ème Conference
Simulation of nitrogen dynamics and shrimp growth in an inten- internationale des Polychètes. Mém. Mus. natn. History Nature,
sive shrimp culture system: effects of feed and feeding parame- no 162, Paris, pp. 511–520.
ters. Ecol. Model. 122, 81–95. SEAFISH, 2002. UK Seafood Market: An Overview.
Montoya, R.A., Lawrence, A.L., Grant, W.E., Velasco, M., 2002. http://www.seafish.org.
Simulation of inorganic nitrogen dynamics and shrimp survival SEPA, 1998. A Manual of Regulation and Monitoring for Cage Fish
in an intensive shrimp culture system. Aquacult. Res. 33, 81–94. Farming in Scotland. Scottish Environment Protection Agency,
Naylor, R.L., Goldburg, R.J., Primavera, J.H., Kautsky, N., Bev- Stirling, Scotland, 120 pp.
eridge, M.C.M., Clay, J., Folkes, C., Lubchenco, J., Mooney, H., Schaefer, M.B., 1957. A study of the dynamics of the fishery for
Troell, M., 2000. Effect of aquaculture on world fish supplies. yellowfin tuna in the eastern tropical Pacific Ocean. Bull. Int.
Nature 405, 1017–1024. Am. Trop. Tuna Commis. 2, 245–285.
Nerrie, B.L., Hatch, L.U., Engel, C.R., Smitherman, R.O., 1990. Skjold, F., Eide, A., Flaaten, O., 1996. Production functions of the
The economics of intensifying catfish production: a production Norwegian bottom fisheries of cod in the Barents Sea. ICES J.
function analysis. J. World Aquacult. Soc. 21, 350–356. Marine Sci. Int. Council Explor. Seas, Mimeo CM1996/P3.
Nielsen, S.N., Anastacio, P.M., Frias, A.F., Marques, A.F.J.G., 1999. Stead, S.M., Laird, L., 2002. Handbook of Salmon Farming. Springer
CRISP—crayfish rice integrated system of production. 5. Simu- Praxis, Chichester, UK, 497 pp.
lation of nitrogen dynamics. Ecol. Model. 123, 41–52. Stratoudakis, Y., Fryer, R.J., Cook, R.M., 1998. Discarding practices
Noakes, D.J., Beamish, R.J., Kent, M., 2000. On the decline of for commercial gadoids in the North Sea. Can. J. Fish. Aquat.
Pacific salmon and speculative links to salmon farming in British Sci. 55, 1632–1644.
Columbia. Aquaculture 183, 363–386. Stratoudakis, Y., Fryer, R., Cook, R.M., Pierce, G.J., 1999. Fish
O’Connor, B.D.S., Costelloe, J., Keegan, B.F., Rhoads, D.C., discarded from Scottish demersal vessels: estimators of total dis-
1989. The use of REMOTS technology in monitoring coastal cards and annual estimates for targeted gadoids. ICES J. Marine
enrichment resulting from mariculture. Marine Pollut. Bull. 20, Sci. 56, 592–605.
384–390. Swain, D.P., Sinclair, A.F., 2000. Pelagic fishes and the cod recruit-
Parsons, L.S., Lear, W.H., 2001. Climate variability and marine ment dilemma in the Northwest Atlantic. Can. J. Fish. Aquat.
ecosystem impacts: a North Atlantic perspective. Progr. Sci. 57, 1321–1325.
Oceanogr. 49, 167–188. Sutherland, R., Calyton, P., 2002. Economic and business issues.
Paulson, L.J., 1980. Models of ammonia excretion for brook trout In: Stead, S., Laird, L. (Eds.), Handbook of Salmon Farming.
(Salelinus fontinalis) and rainbow trout (Salmo gairdneri). Can. Springer Praxis, Chichester, UK, pp. 235–276.
J. Fish. Aquat. Sci. 37, 1421–1425. Tidwell, J.H., Allan, G.L., 2001. Fish as food:aquaculture’s contribu-
Pearson, T.H., Rosenberg, R., 1978. Macrobenthic succession in tion. Ecological and economic impacts and contributions of fish
relation to organic enrichment and pollution of the marine envi- farming and capture fisheries. EMBO Reports 211, 958–963.
ronment. Oceanogr. Marine Biol. Annual Rev. 16, 229–311. Weston, D.P., 1990. Quantitative examination of macrobenthic com-
Phillips, M., Boyd, C., Edwards, E., 2001. Systems approach to aqua- munity changes along an organic enrichment gradient. Marine
culture management. In: Subasinghe, R.P., Bueno, P., Phillips, Ecol. Progr. Series 61, 233–244.
M.J., Hough, C., McGladdery, S.E., Arthur, J.R. (Eds.), Aqua- Westra, J.V., Zimmerman, J.K.H., Vondracek, B., 2005. Bioeco-
culture in the third millennium. Technical Proceedings on the nomic analysis of selected conservation practices on soil erosion
Conference on Aquaculture in the Third Millenium. Bangkok, and freshwater fisheries. J. Am. Water Resour. Assoc. 41, 309–
Thailand, 20–25 February 2000, pp. 239–247. 322.
Pillay, T.V.R., 1992. Aquaculture and the Environment. Fishing New Ye, Y.M., Loneragan, N., Die, D., Watson, R., Harch, B., 2005. Bioe-
Books, Oxford, 185 pp. conomic modelling and risk assessment of tiger prawn (Penaeus
Pocklington, P., Scott, D.B., Schaffer, C.T., 1994. Polychaete esculentus) stock enhancement in Exmouth Gulf. Aust. Fish. Res.
response to different aquaculture activities. In: Dauvin, J.C., 73, 231–249.

Вам также может понравиться