Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 19

American Economic Association

7KH&KRLFHEHWZHHQ0DUNHW)DLOXUHVDQG&RUUXSWLRQ
$XWKRU V 'DURQ$FHPRJOXDQG7KLHUU\9HUGLHU
6RXUFH7KH$PHULFDQ(FRQRPLF5HYLHZ9RO1R 0DU SS
3XEOLVKHGE\American Economic Association
6WDEOH85/http://www.jstor.org/stable/117287
$FFHVVHG

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless
you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you
may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.

Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at
http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=aea.

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed
page of such transmission.

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The
American Economic Review.

http://www.jstor.org
The Choice Between Market Failures and Corruption

By DARON ACEMOGLUAND THIERRYVERDIER*

Because governmentinterventiontransfers resourcesfrom one party to another, it


creates room for corruption.As corruption often underminesthe purpose of the
intervention,governmentswill try to prevent it. They may create rentsfor bureau-
crats, induce a misallocationof resources, and increase the size of the bureaucracy.
Since preventing all corruptionis excessively costly, second-best interventionmay
involve a certain fraction of bureaucrats accepting bribes. When corruption is
harder to prevent, there may be both more bureaucrats and higher public-sector
wages. Also, the optimal degree of governmentinterventionmay be nonmonotonic
in the level of income. (JEL D23, 1140)

Inefficiencies associatedwith governmentin- theory of "governmentfailure," we are often


terventions in many developing and even ad- unable to determine whether a certain govern-
vanced economies are well known (see for ment interventionis justified when the distor-
example, Deepak Lal [1985] on misallocation tions it brings are taken into account.
of resources; Ledivina V. Carino [1986] and This paper develops a simple frameworkto
Hernando De Soto [1989] on corruption; or analyze the links between governmentinterven-
JohnD. Donahue [1989] on rentsto government tions and governmentfailures.We startwith the
employees). Taking the problems of govern- textbook model of governmentas a benevolent
ment involvement seriously, many social scien- social plannerinterveningto correctmarketfail-
tists prefer to live with market failures rather ures. To this, we add three basic assumptions:
than risk widespreadgovernmentfailures (e.g.,
Edward S. Mills, 1986). Others interpret the 1. Governmentinterventionrequiresthe use of
presence of governmentcorruptionas evidence agents ("bureaucrats"for short) to collect
that most politicians are intervening to further information,make decisions, and implement
their careeror wealth ratherthan correctmarket policies.2
failures (e.g., William A. Niskanen, 1971; An- 2. These bureaucratsare self-interested,and by
drei Shleifer and Robert W. Vishny, 1994). In virtue of their superiorinformation,hard to
contrast,anotherview points to a trade-off be- monitor perfectly.
tween governmentfailures and marketfailures. 3. There is some heterogeneityamong bureau-
This view is seldom formalized or developed, crats.
however, and we lack an understandingas to
why government interventiondesigned to cor- These three assumptionsimply that when the
rect marketfailures also leads to corruptionand marketfailure in question is important,the op-
inefficiencies.' As a consequence, without a

* Acemoglu: Departmentof Economics, Massachusetts the optimalmixtureof marketfailure and corruption,which


Institute of Technology, 50 Memorial Drive, Cambridge, is the focus of our paper.
MA; Verdier:DELTA-ENS, 48, Boulevard Jourdan,Paris 2 See Maurice Crozier (1964), Guy B. Peters (1989), or
75405, France, and CERAS. We thank two anonymous James Q. Wilson (1989) on the role and duties of bureau-
referees, and James Robinson, Jaume Ventura,and various cracies. These studies substantiateour assumptionthat it is
seminarparticipantsfor useful comments. not possible to have government intervention without a
' Susan Rose-Ackerman(1978 p. 9) also motivates her sizable bureaucracyand that bureaucratswill have an infor-
inquiry into corruption with a similar observation. She mational advantage over their "principal."For example,
writes: "... corruptincentives are the nearly inevitable con- Peters (1989 p. 196) writes: "The first and perhaps most
sequence of all government attempts to control market importantresource of the bureaucracyis informationand
forces ...." However, she does not pursuethis line to discuss expertise."
194
VOL.90 NO. I ACEMOGLUAND VERDIER:MARKETFAILURESAND CORRUPTION 195

timal allocation of resources will involve a tion. As a result, governmentinterventionleads


certain degree of government intervention,ac- both to a certain amount of corruptionand to
companiedby a large governmentbureaucracy, rents for governmentemployees.
rents for public employees, misallocationof re- Our analysis yields a numberof comparative
sources, and possibly, corruption. Paradoxi- static results which may be useful in assessing
cally, we also find that when bureaucratsare the trade-off between market failures and gov-
corruptible,the optimal size of the government ernmentfailures. We find that when monitoring
is greater than in the case where corruptionis bureaucratsbecomes more difficult,they should
not possible. These government failures, how- receive higher wages, and governmentinterven-
ever, are not proof thatgovernmentintervention tion should become relatively rare. But if gov-
is socially harmful. Instead, they may indicate ernment intervention continues to be required
the unavoidable price of dealing with rnarket despite the increased difficulty of monitoring,
failures. the number of bureaucrats and their wages
To illustratethe main idea of the paper,con- should increase, very much as if the bureau-
sider what is perhapsthe most standardexample cracy were expanding to seek additionalrents.
of governmentintervention:taxing pollution (or The intuitionfor this result-is informativeabout
any other negative externality). A benevolent the workings of our model. Governmentinter-
governmentwould ideally tax pollution and en- vention has two instruments: the number of
sure that all firms pollute less. But it is often bureaucratsand their wages. When there are
costly to observe how much pollution a partic- many bureaucrats,each firm is likely to be
ular firm is causing and whetherthey took pre- inspected, and a small fine on polluters is suf-
cautions. So the government employs ficient to discouragepollution. Because the fine
bureaucratsto collect information and imple- is small, there is only a small bribe that the
ment policies. The fact that the government bureaucratcan extract. In contrast, with few
needs to employ agents, who would otherwise bureaucrats,the fines need to be large and there
be productive, increases the cost of interven- is more room for corruption.When bureaucrats
tion. More interestingly, it also introduces a become harderto monitor, the optimal govern-
principal-agent relation whereby bureaucrats ment intervention will use both instruments
transferresources on the basis of information more intensively. That is, the government will
they have and the government (the principal) hire more bureaucratsand pay higher wages.
does not. This reasoning leads to our first basic Furthermore,the optimal degree of govern-
result: because government intervention de- ment interventionmay be nonmonotonicin the
signed to correct market failures requires the per capita income level of the economy. An
use of bureaucratsto make decisions, it will increase in output in a poor economy tends to
create opportunitiesfor these employees to be increase the desirability of government inter-
corruptand demandbribes. vention, but has the opposite effect in a rich
Corruption,by misdirecting subsidies or re- country.The reason for the predicteddecline in
ducing tax revenues, underminesthe purposeof governmentinterventionin rich countriesis that
government intervention.We therefore expect the opportunitycost of governmentintervention
the governmentto institutemechanismsto pre- is the withdrawalof agents from the productive
vent corruption.An importantinstrumentin this sector. In richer economies, the productivityin
effort is incentive payments (e.g., Gary S. the private sector is higher, so, the opportunity
Becker, 1968; Becker and George J. Stigler, cost of governmentinterventionis also greater.
1974; Rose-Ackerman, 1978). Furthermore, Unless the extent of market failures increases
when bureaucratsare credit constrained,these relatively rapidly with per capita income, the
incentive payments will take the form of "effi- optimal size of government declines at some
ciency wages." Public employees will receive point. The nonmonotonic relation between in-
monetary and nonpecuniaryrents, which they come and governmentinterventionin our model
will lose if caught taking bribes. Nevertheless, contrasts with some existing theories, such as
given some degree of heterogeneityamong bu- the so called "Wagner's Law," which predict
reaucrats, it is often optimal not to pay the increasing government intervention over time.
excessive rents requiredto prevent all corrup- Although our model is extremely simple, this
196 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW MARCH2000

comparativestatic result may help us in analyz- bribes they can extract.However, in all of these
ing the variationsin the degree of government papers, the approachis partialequilibrium,and
involvement across countries and over time. the costs and benefits of government interven-
Another result is that corruption should be tion are not analyzed together. In contrast,our
observed as part of an optimal allocation when general-equilibriumapproach is importantfor
the marketfailure in question is important,and many of our key results, including the finding
the fraction of "dishonest"bureaucrats(those that the numberof bureaucratsand their wages
who are harderto detect when taking bribes) is should be higher when they are harderto mon-
relatively low. This result may suggest that sit- itor, and the nonmonotonic relation between per
uations where the majority of bureaucratsare capita income and governmentintervention.
corrupt, as in some less developed countries The plan of the paper is as follows. The next
(LDCs) are harder to rationalize as "optimal" section outlines the basic environmentand char-
governmentinterventionthan instances of more acterizes the optimal allocation in the absence
occasional corruptionin the OECD. of corruptionconstraints.Section II character-
Many other studies emphasize the costs of izes the optimal allocationwhen bureaucratsare
corruption(e.g., Robert Klitgaard, 1989; Shle- corruptible. This section obtains most of the
ifer and Vishny, 1993; Paulo Mauro, 1995). We importantresults of this paper but because all
depart from these papers by emphasizing the bureaucratsare homogenous, there is no equi-
unavoidability of corruption (see also Rose- libriumcorruption.Section III extends the anal-
Ackerman, 1978). We argue instead that in ysis to the case of heterogenousbureaucratsand
many instances, markets malfunction and gov- determinesthe conditions under which the op-
ernment intervention is necessary. Corruption timal allocation will involve some of these bu-
associated with such interventions may there- reaucratsacceptingbribes. Section IV considers
fore be the lesser of two evils. This is relatedto some extensions, and Section IV concludes.
an argument made by Nathaniel Leff (1964),
but there is a crucial difference. According to I. The Basic Model
Leff (1964), and more recently DeSoto (1989),
corruptionis often unavoidablebecause govern- We consider a static economy consisting of a
ments distort the allocation of resources, and continuum of risk-neutralagents with mass l.
corruptionis the way that the marketbypasses For now all agents are homogeneous. They can
the regulations. The optimal policy, in Leff's choose between two activities:they can become
view, is therefore to eliminate government in- entrepreneurs,or if there is a government,they
tervention. In our story, the market, not the can become government employees (bureau-
government,is the culprit. The governmentin- crats). Entrepreneursalso have two choices.
tervenes to redress marketfailures, and corrup- They can choose one of two technologies: "bad"
tion emerges as an unpleasant side effect of or "good." Both technologies generate output
necessary intervention.Our work is also closely equal to y. However, their costs differ. The bad
related to the principal-agent approachto law technology costs 0, whereas the good technol-
enforcement (e.g., Becker, 1968; Becker and ogy costs e where 0 < e < y.
Stigler, 1974; Rose-Ackerman, 1978; Dilip We choose the terminology "bad" and
Mookherjee and I. P. L. Png, 1992, 1995; Ab- "good"because good technologies create a pos-
hijit Banerjee, 1997) and to the literature on itive externality.Let n be the mass (fraction)of
optimal regulation under asymmetric informa- entrepreneursin this economy and x c n be the
tion and regulatory capture (see Jean Jacques mass of entrepreneurschoosing the good tech-
Laffont and Jean Tirole, 1993). In a related nology. We assume that there is a positive non-
contribution,Banerjee(1997) considersa model pecuniary effect on the payoff of all agents
where bureaucratshave superior information equal to O3x.Moreover, we have f3 > e so that
relative to the governmentwishing to allocate a this externalityis strongenough to outweigh the
limited set of goods to agents who are not the private costs. We also assume that the cost of
ones with the highest willingness to pay. Bu- choosing the good technology, e, is nonpecuni-
reaucratsare corrupt and may even introduce ary. These assumptionssimplify the analysis by
red tape in order to increase the amount of making maximum taxes independent of tech-
VOL.90 NO. 1 ACEMOGLUAND VERDIER:MARKETFAILURESAND CORRUPTION 197

nology choices, but do not affect our basic In this section, we ignore the corruptionprob-
results. lem, and assume that bureaucratsalways report
truthfully.In the absence of furtherconstraints,
A. The Laissez-Faire Equilibrium the optimal strategy for the governmentwould
and the First Best be to have a trivialproportionof agents become
bureaucrats, randomly inspect entrepreneurs,
In the decentralizedequilibrium,there is no and impose infinite taxes/subsidies. This strat-
government, so all agents become entrepre- egy would minimize the withdrawalof agents
neurs, hence n = 1. The payoffs to the two from the productive sector. However, in prac-
activities are: tice, there will be limited liability constraints
limiting taxes, and a government budget con-
(1) Trg= y + 3 x-e, straintdeterminingthe amountthatcan be given
away in subsidies. This is the first important
7Tb= y + f3 x. role of the limited liability constraints in this
economy.
Therefore, 7Tb > lTg for all x, and the unique We denote the tax that an entrepreneurwith
equilibriumhas n = 1 and x - 0. the bad technology has to pay by T, and denote
Since , > e, the firstbest is given by n - 1 the subsidy that an entrepreneurwith the good
andx = 1: all agents become entrepreneursand technology receives by s (both of these are
choose the good technology. However, this out- imposed only if the entrepreneuris inspected).
come is not sustainableas a decentralizedequi- Note that we do not assume s ? 0, so entre-
librium because, as in a standard prisoner's preneurs with good technology may be taxed
dilemma, each individual has a dominantstrat- too. We denote the wage of a bureaucratby w.
egy, which is to choose the bad technology. Since before inspection,it is not known who has
Essentially, entrepreneursdo not take into ac- chosen bad technologies, inspection is random.
count the externalities they create on other Therefore, the probabilitythat an entrepreneur
agents. is inspected is p(n) max{(1 -- n)In, 11,
which is the fraction of bureaucratsdivided by
B. OptimalRegulation WithoutCorruption the fraction of entrepreneurs,unless there are
more bureaucratsthan entrepreneurs.4
We now consider governmentinterventionto
regulate technology choice. Throughoutthe pa-
per, we assume that the governmentintervenes anothermeasureof the efficacy of governmentintervention.
to maximize social surplus. So there are no In particular,as 0 -- 0o, government intervention is ex-
distributionalconcerns or rent seeking by the tremelyeffective, and all marketfailurescan be preventedat
government itself. If technology choices of minimal cost.
4 Notice that in this environment, it is not possible to
agents were publicly observable, the first best collects taxes withoutinspection.We discuss the case where
could be achieved. It is realistic, however, to the governmentcan impose "poll taxes" without inspecting
assume thattechnology choices are not publicly technology choices in AppendixC (availableupon request).
observed. The government needs to employ In this case, without corruption,the government raises a
large tax revenue via poll taxes, and then sets a large
some agents as bureaucratsto inspect entrepre- subsidy, a large public-sector wage, and employs a very
neurs, and find out what technology is being small fractionof agents to inspect technology choices. How-
used. We assume that one bureaucratcan in- ever, when bureaucratsare corruptible, similar results to
spect only one entrepreneur.This assumptionis those in the text apply. A high subsidy to good technology
of no major importance,but the fact that regu- creates strong incentives for corruption,so only moderate
subsidies can be set, and a sizable bureaucracyis necessary
lation requiresthe employmentof bureaucratsis to inspect technology choices. In any case, we view the
crucial for our analysis. assumptions in the text, that taxation is costly, and that
taxation and inspection can be carried out together, as
plausible. Suppose, for example, that the bad technology in
our model correspondsto misleadingshareholdersand cred-
3Appendix B (availableupon request)gives the analysis itors, and/or taking excessive financial risks. Then, inspec-
for the case in which each bureaucratinspects 0 entrepre- tors who collect taxes can also determine whether a
neurs. The qualitative results are identical, and 0 gives company has chosen the "bad"technology.
198 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW MARCH2000

The exact timing of events is as follows: see thatthe optimalallocationwould never have
n < 1/2. Hence, we use p(n) (1 - n)ln as
1. The governmentannouncesthe public wage, the probability of getting inspected for an en-
w, the tax T, the subsidys, and the maximum trepreneur,and then check whethern ? 1/2. As
numberof bureaucratsit will hire (1 - n). a result,the second constraint,which we referto
2. Agents choose their profession. If there are as the technology choice constraint, 7rg?
9 Xb,
more applicants to the government sector takes the form
than 1 - n, then 1 - n of them are chosen
n
randomlyand the remainderenterthe private (4) T + s 1n - e.
sector. l-- n
3. Those who enter the private sector choose a
technology. Their technology choice is not This constraintensures that all agents prefer to
observed by any other agent at this stage. choose the good technology.
4. Each bureaucratrandomly inspects one en- The government cannot force its citizens to
trepreneur5and discovers whether he has become bureaucrats. The third condition, the
chosen the good or the bad technology. allocation of talent constraint, therefore en-
5. Each bureaucratthen reportson the technol- sures that agents are willing to become bu-
ogy choice of the entrepreneurhe has in- reaucrats rather than entrepreneurs. This
spected. If his report is "good," the requires w +? f x? -ag, that is, the payoff
entrepreneurreceives the subsidy s. If the to bureaucracy must be as large as the return
report is "bad,"then the entrepreneurpays to entrepreneurship.Or:
the tax T.
1-n
As noted above, for now, all bureaucratsal- (5) w?y-e + - s.
n
ways reporttruthfully,hence there is no corrup-
tion. The government is utilitarian, and
maximizes total net surplus: Finally, we need the revenues of the govern-
ment not to fall shortof its expenses.The govern-
(2) SS= ny + (f-e) x ment will have a wage bill equal to (1 - n) - W9
and as long as n /2, it will pay subsidiesequal
to (1 - n) xln s (since there will be 1 - n
e

by choosing n, x, w, T, and s, subject to four entrepreneursinspectedin total and a proportion


constraints,where recall that x is the mass of xln of them will have chosen the good technolo-
agents choosing the good technology. gy). It will also collect taxes equal to (1 - n)
First, there is a limited liability constraint (I - xln) * T. The government budget constraint is
which dictates that the government cannot tax therefore:
more than the revenue of an entrepreneur:
x x
(3) T cy. (6) 1_ _ r
X w + - S.
n n

Second, choosing the good technology must It is straightforwardto see that the limited
yield a payoff as high as the bad technology. liability constraint(3) has to hold as an equality:
The expected payoff to the two technologies otherwise, T and n could be increased without
are: -g y + x-e
x + p(n) * s and 7Tb= violating (4), (5), or (6). The technology choice
y + f3 x - p(n) * T. It is straightforward to constraint, (4), also has to hold as an equality
for the same reason. Then, from (3) and (4) we
have T - y and s = nl(1 - n) - e - y.
5There is no coordinationissue here so an entrepreneur Substitutingthese into (5) now gives us a sim-
never gets inspectedby two bureaucrats,and as long as n >
1/2, each bureaucratinspects one entrepreneur.Introducing
plified form of the allocation of talent con-
coordinationproblems does not change our results, though straint: w ?> y - (1 -- n)ln - y, for n ?> 1/2. If
it complicates the expressions. this inequality did not hold, the public-sector
VOL.90 NO. 1 ACEMOGLUAND VERDIER:MARKETFAILURESAND CORRUPTION 199

wage rate would be too low to attractagents,


and we would have n - 1. Also, rearranging I v X-- ---

(6) and using (4), we obtain a more compact


form of the government budget constraint as x=(l- n)2y/ne

w + x/(1 - n) * e ' y. Combining these two


inequalities, and noting that x, the mass of en-
trepreneurschoosing the good technology, can- n 8 U = ny +(P-e)x
not exceed n, we obtainthe constraintset of the
governmentas: 11

-
(7) i (I ~ n)' y} n}
x -<min1 SSng sSg
\

n 1 x

The characterizationof the optimal allocationis FIGURE 1. OPTIMAL GOVERNMENT INTERVENTION WITHOUT
THE POTENTIAL OF CORRUPTION
thereforegiven by the maximizationof (2) sub-
ject to (7) and n - 1/2. This problem is repre-
sented diagrammatically in Figure 1. Only
combinations of x and n in the triangulararea Government regulation is costly as it with-
are permissible. The objective function to be draws agents from productionto employ them
maximized, (2), is linear in n and x, thus the in monitoring activities. It is therefore only
contours are straightlines. Since the constraint worthwhileif the externalityin question is suf-
set is nonconvex, it is clear that an optimum ficiently pronounced. In particular, since the
must be either at n =1 (with x = 0), or at x = cost of governmentinterventionis the diversion
n, i.e., at point E in the figure. Which of these of agents from production, the benefit of the
will be preferreddepends on the slope of the intervention,f, needs to be sufficiently large as
contours of (2). comparedto y.
If n = 1 and x = 0, then social surplus is
SSng y. Insteadwith x = n in (7), we obtain II. Optimal Regulation With Corruption
a unique solution:
A. Analysis

(8) n =- We now combine two of our three basic


~y+ ~e ingredients:(i) the need to employ bureaucrats
to make autonomousdecisions or collect infor-
ni lies between 1/2and 1 as requiredsince y > e. mation, and (ii) corruptibility(while the third
Substituting(8) and n = x into (2), we obtain ingredient,heterogeneity,is left to the next sec-
the social surpluswith optimalgovernmentreg- tion). A bureaucratcan exploit the informa-
ulation as: SSg = (y + 3 - e) * (V/(V + tional advantagehe has over his principal, the
\e')). The comparisonof SSg with SSng leads government.This can take either of two forms.
to our first result (proof omitted). First, upon meeting an entrepreneurwho has
chosen the good technology, a bureaucratcan
PROPOSITION1: Suppose there is no corrup- threatenthat unless he is bribed he will report
tion opportunity.Then if the technology to be bad. Second, when he
meets an entrepreneurwith the bad technology,
(9) 3> ye+e he can demanda bribeto reportthe projectto be
good. In both cases the maximum"surplus"that
a bureaucratcan extract is s + T. We assume
is satisfied, the optimal allocation of resources that in both cases the bureaucratcan get a pro-
has n = x = n given by (8). Otherwise, the portion a of this amount as bribe.
optimal allocation is laissez-faire (n 1 and A corrupt bureaucratwill get caught with
x 0). probabilityq. In this case, he suffers the most
200 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW MARCH2000

serious punishmentsubject to limited liability; are extremely difficult to administer, suffer


he loses all his income.6 Note that 1 - q is a from multiple equilibria,and are highly unreal-
measure of the informationaladvantageof bu- istic. Hence, in this paper we ignore these im-
reaucrats.When q = 0, then corruptbureau- plementation mechanisms. We also do not
crats are never caught. In contrast, if q 1, allow complaints by entrepreneurs.Such com-
corruption will be immediately detected. We plaints could change the bargaining game be-
can also observe the second importantrole of tween bureaucrats and entrepreneurs in the
the limited liability constraint (recall its first corruptionstage, and would imply that bureau-
role was to limit taxation): because all agents crats would be able to extract less from entre-
are risk neutral,a large punishmentimposed on preneurs with the good technology without
bureaucratscaughttakingbribes would discour- changingthe essence of our results.8Finally, we
age corruptionat no cost, and the allocation of allow bureaucratsto reportthat the technology
Proposition 1 could be achieved. The limited is bad even when n - x. This can be justified
liability constraintprevents this. by assuming that there is a small set of entre-
The timing of events of the previous section preneurs who would always choose the bad
is now modified.In stage 5, each bureaucratfirst technology, say, because they lack access to the
decides whether to make a "collusion"offer to good one.
the entrepreneurwith whom he is matched.If he Because all agents, in particularall bureau-
decides not to demandbribes, he makes a truth- crats, are homogenous, there will be a unique
ful report,and the game ends as in the previous condition determining whether it pays to be
section. In case the bureaucratdemandsa bribe, corrupt. If honest, a bureaucratobtains w. If
then his report depends on the entrepreneur's corrupt,he loses everything with probabilityq,
response. If the entrepreneuraccepts this offer and with probability1 - q, he receives both the
and pays the bribe, then, exactly at the same wage and a bribe b =- o ( + s). Hence, if the
time, the bureaucratmakes the agreed report.If "corruptionconstraint,"'the inequality
the entrepreneurrejects the collusion offer, the
bureaucratreportsthe projectto be bad. Finally, 1 q
W Co o (T + s)
there is a stage 6 in which bureaucrats'reports (10)
q
are inspected and those who made a false report
are caught with probability q. All revenues 1-q n
from a bureaucrat who made a false report - ff e,
o-
q 1-n
and from the corresponding entrepreneurare
confiscated.7
Observe that we are not allowing compli- is violated, all bureaucratswould be corrupt
cated implementationschemes. Since the entre- [where the second term is obtained by substi-
preneurand the bureaucratwho have inspected tuting for T + s using (4)]. In this case, all
him share a piece of informationnot observed entrepreneursreceive ffo (T + s) irrespective
by any other agent, they may both be asked to of their technology choice, and the government
reportit. Then, there will exist a Nash equilib- interventionis unambiguouslywasteful. So for
rium in which there is truthfulrevelation.These governmentinterventionto be desirable condi-
kinds of implementationschemes would always tion (10) has to hold. This observation also
solve corruptionor collusion problems,but they explains why corruptionis harmfulin this econ-

6 8 In particular,suppose that when dealing with an entre-


We treat q as exogenous though it is possible to endo-
genize it, or even model the hierarchyof bureaucracyalong preneurwith a good technology, a bureaucratcan extract a
the lines of GuillermoCalvo and StanislawWellisz's (1979) fraction of crgof the surplus, whereas the same fraction is
analysis of hierarchiesin efficiency wage models (see also I, > a,, when negotiating with an entrepreneurwith the
JuanD. Carrillo, 1995; Rose-Ackerman,1978). Since these bad technology. In the first two cases considered in Propo-
extensions are not essential for our purpose, we will not sition 2, all entrepreneurschoose the good technology, so
pursue them here. only o'g would matter, but in the third case, where some
7 Although a bureaucrat can falsify the technology entrepreneurschoose the bad technology, both ab and oyg
choice of the entrepreneur,he can never falsify having met appearin the expressions, which makes the analysis more
an entrepreneur. complicated, without affecting the main results.
VOL.90 NO. I ACEMOGLUAND VERDIER:MARKETFAILURESAND CORRUPTION 201

11
---
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - line would be reached at point E, ratherthan at
1
E as in Figure 1. We also need to check thatn '
1/2, since all these equations are written assum-
x -1- n)2y/ne U =ny +(P-x
ing this condition to hold. Even though this
Sg9c constraint was never binding in the previous
section, it may bind when bureaucrats are
corruptible.
n -- - Ec Optimal governmentinterventionwill there-
nc : fore take one of the following three forms:9

(i) (11) is less restrictivethan (7), so n = x =


SSg nf > 1/2 as given by (8);
0 nc y/e x
(ii) (7) is less restrictivethan(11), and n = x =
nc > 1/2 where nc is given by imposing n =
FIGURE2. OPTIMALGOVERNMENT
INTERVENTION
WITH x in (7):
POTENTIAL
CORRUPTION

y
(12) nc- 1-q
omy. The role of governmentinterventionis to y +e+e*- (J e
make ex post transfersconditional on technol- q
ogy choice so that ex ante decisions are af-
fected. When bureaucratsare corrupt,transfers (iii) n = 1/2 andx is chosen so as to balance the
are unconditionaland governmentintervention governmentbudget constraint,thus
no longer affects ex ante choices.
In contrast, when (10) holds, no bureaucrat
will demand bribes. Hence, we simply need to (13) x = max{( - 1q );
make sure that the corruptionconstraint,(10),
and the other constraintson governmentpolicy,
summarized by (7), are satisfied. Combining In this last case, governmentrevenues fall short
(10) with the simplifiedform of the government of supportingan allocation in which all entre-
budget constraint,w + x/(l - n) = y, gives preneurschoose the good technology, and the
the corruptionconstraintin the (x, n) space as: only way of increasingrevenuesis to have some
of the entrepreneurschoose the bad technology
and pay the tax T = y. We have the following
(11) x 'e (e + q ) proposition (proof in the Appendix).

PROPOSITION 2: Suppose that bureaucrats


Diagrammatically,we add a line representing are corruptible. The optimal allocation is:
(11) to Figure 1 as an additionalconstraintand
repeatthe analysis. If ( 11) is less restrictivethan 1. If y/e - [1 + of - (1 - q)/q]2 and f3 >
(7), the public wage, set to attractagents into Ve (VjW + \e), thenthereis government
bureaucracy,would be high enough that no bu- interventionwith n = x = n'as given by (8).
reaucratwould want to accept bribes and the 2. If yle E (1 + o (1 - q)lq; [1 + o- (1 -
solution of the previous section applies. q)/q]2) and f3 > 2e + e * o- (1 -q)lq,
The more interesting case, drawn in Figure then the optimal allocation has government
2, is when (11) is a more restrictiveconstraint
than (7). In this case, to preventcorruptionit is
necessary to pay bureaucratsa wage above the 9 Another possibility is to have a certain fraction of the
minimum level that would attractthem to the bureaucratscorrupt, and reduce the required revenue by
catching a fractionq of those. A by-productof our analysis
governmentsector, i.e., a rent. In Figure 2, this in the next section will be to show that this is never pre-
implies thatthe constraintset is now the smaller ferredto the allocation derived here (see the proof of Prop-
shaded triangle and the highest social surplus osition 3 in the Appendix).
202 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW MARCH2000

interventionwith n = x = nc as given by induce entrepreneursto choose the good tech-


(12). nology, and this translates into an opportunity
3. If yle < 1 + o- (1 - q)lq and 1B> e + for large bribes. To prevent corruption now
yl[yle - (1 - q)lq], then there is requires a high w. This trade-off implies that
government interventionwith n = 1/2,x it is cheaper to satisfy the technology con-
1/2 [yle - u (1 - q)lq]. straint of the entrepreneurs, (4), not only by
4. Otherwise, the optimal allocation is laissez- increasing w, but also by having more bureau-
faire. crats (lower n) so as to reduce T + s and the
level of equilibrium bribes. In fact, it trivially
B. Discussion follows from (4) that in this case T + s is
smaller than in Section I, subsection B. The
There are a numberof results summarizedin second and related reason is that the corrup-
Proposition2. First, if q is large enough or a- is tion constraint forces public-sector wages to
sufficiently small, then corruption is easy to increase, and this requires higher government
prevent,and the corruptibilityof the bureaucrats revenues, and more bureaucratsare needed to
is not important.This is because the wage used raise revenues.
to attractagents to bureaucracycan also be used Because ni > n, the social surplus with
to discipline them, and the same trade-off as in intervention,SS,, is lower than SSg, so govern-
the previous section applies. In contrast,if q is ment intervention is less desirable. Therefore,
small or u is large, then corruptionis tempting some marketfailures, which should have been
for governmentemployees. To prevent corrup- corrected when bureaucratswere not corrupt-
tion, bureaucratshave to be paid a rent. As long ible, do not justify government intervention
as the market failure in question is serious when bureaucratic corruption is taken into
enough (i.e., A3high), it is worthwhile for the account.
society to withdraw a large number of agents Furthermore, n,. is decreasing in the bar-
from the productive sector and pay them the gaining power of bureaucrats, o-, and their
required rent in order to correct the market informational advantage, 1 - q. An increase
failure (cases 2 and 3). An immediate implica- in cr or a reduction in q will reduce the
tion is thereforethatthe potentialfor dishonesty desirability of government intervention.
among bureaucratsdoes not necessarily make Nevertheless, if the optimal allocation of
governmentinterventioncounterproductive.In- resources still requires government interven-
stead, it introduces equilibriumrents for these tion, we will observe higher wages for bu-
employees as part of the constrained optimal reaucrats (w 'I ) and a larger government
allocation. (tic , ). At first, these patterns may look like
Paradoxically, nc as given by (12) is less a government sector diverting resources
than n as in (8). This implies that the intro- (rents) to itself by paying higher wages and
duction of the corruption constraint increases hiring more people, very much as in the the-
the optimal size of the bureaucracy. Intu- ories of "bureaucratic tyranny" (e.g., Nis-
itively, a larger bureaucracy is useful for two kanen, 1971). But, in our economy, it is also
reasons. First and most importantis the trade- exactly the pattern that emerges when bureau-
off between the number of bureaucrats and crats become harder to control (which could
their wages in preventing corruption. With be because of changes in technology, bribe
many bureaucrats, corruption can be pre- opportunities, or cultural reasons), and gov-
vented with a low wage. This is because when ernment intervention continues to be socially
entrepreneurs are sure to be inspected (e.g., beneficial.
n = '/2), a low level of T + s is sufficient to Finally, if y is sufficiently small, the govern-
induce them to choose the good technology. ment will have difficulty in raising enough tax
When T + s is small, there is only a small revenue to pay the subsidies and the wages of
bribe that bureaucrats can extract, and so a bureaucrats.In this case, optimal government
low level of w is sufficient to prevent corrup- intervention has even more bureaucrats,n =
tion. In contrast, when there are a few bureau- 1/2, in an attempt to minimize bureaucratic
crats, a large level of T + s is needed to wages by reducing bribes and maximize reve-
VOL.90 NO. I ACEMOGLUAND VERDIER:MARKETFAILURESAND CORRUPTION 203

nues. Moreover, if all entrepreneurschoose the


good technology, tax revenues will again fall
p Optimal goverment intervention
short,so the optimalallocationrequiressome of
the entrepreneursto choose the bad technology
and act as a "tax base."l0 Therefore, govern-
ment interventionis now less successful in two poor intermediate rich
dimensions (as comparedto the solution of the
previous section): fewer agents are becoming I I
entrepreneurs,and not all of them are choosing
Nq government interveition
the good technology. Even though government
interventionis now much less desirable, with a _ ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~I
~ I

sufficiently serious market failure, it may still l I+(l-q)o/q [l+(l-q)a/q] 2 y/C


be preferredto laissez-faire.
Comparativestatics with respect to y (or to FIGURE 3. THE RELATION BETWEEN THE LEVEL OF INCOME
yle) are also interesting. Since y is the output AND GOVERNMENT INTERVENTION

producedby an entrepreneur,it naturallycorre-


sponds to per capita income in the economy: a
higher level of y implies a richer economy. f = go + PI* y2, so that the importance of
Figure 3 gives the cutoff level of ,Babove which the externalityalso increases with income. It is
government interventionis optimal as a func- straightforwardto verify using the expressions
tion of yle (curve ,3,3). The three different re- in Proposition2 that there will once again exist
gimes of Proposition 2 can be seen in this a cutoff /3*(y) such that if Bo > I3*(y), gov-
diagram and a U shape emerges for the cutoff ernmentinterventionis justified.If 032 - 1/2 in
level. This cutoff level, /3/3,is decreasing in y the above formula, then the extent of market
for poor economies, then constant, and finally failures increase sufficiently rapidly with in-
increasing. The intuitive reason for the down- come that /3*(y) is always decreasing in y. In
ward-sloping part is that in poor economies, this case, therefore, there should always be
resources are limited, and the governmentbud- more interventionin richersocieties, as claimed
get constraint can only be satisfied by having by the "Wagner'sLaw." In contrast,if /82 < ?/2,
some entrepreneursuse the bad technology (i.e., then the comparative static results of Figure
x < n) while being taxed heavily. Since the 3 continue to hold: the higher opportunitycost
point of the intervention is to increase x, it of withdrawingagents from the productivesec-
becomes less desirable. In contrast, for rich tor dominates at high levels of income, and the
economies the governmentbudget constraintis relation between income and optimal govern-
not as restrictive, and the key factor is the ment intervention is nonmonotonic. Although
opportunitycost of diverting productive indi- growth of income may bring new areas for
viduals to bureaucracy. As y increases, this government intervention,for example, nuclear
opportunitycost rises and governmentinterven- research or increased demand for government
tion becomes less desirable. Even though our interventionin social problemsrelatedto demo-
model is simple and abstractsfrom many rele- graphicand sociological changes, it is plausible
vant considerations,this comparativestatic re- that the extent of many "externalities"increase
sult emphasizes an effect that has not been less than proportionallywith income. So our
pointed out in the previous literature. analysis suggests that in a numberof areas, the
The comparative static results in Figure higher opportunitycost of governmentinterven-
3, however, assume that the extent of the exter- tion in rich economies may discourage govern-
nality, /3,remainsconstantas income increases. ment intervention.
A more flexible formulationis to assume that Overall, therefore, our model suggests that
an inverse U-shaped relation between per cap-
ita income and government intervention is
10 Since entrepreneursare indifferent between the two possible. Such a nonmonotonic relation is
technologies, i.e., '1b = 7Tg = Ox, this is simply a mixed- consistent with some broad patterns in the
strategyequilibrium. data. Government intervention increased
204 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW MARCH2000

starting from the nineteenth century (see, for solutions. Either there is no government reg-
example, Peter H. Lindert, 1989, 1994). An ulation, thus n = 1 and x = 0. Or there is no
important aspect of government involvement corruption and Proposition 2 from the previ
was indeed an attempt to correct certain mar- ous section applies with q replacing q (and
ket failures. For example, investment in edu- n X
>x 1/2 or n I/2 and x < 1/2, in this
cation for the masses, which stood at a very case, w ? (1 -q) * a e (T + s)lq, so neither
low levels, increased substantially after the "honest" nor "dishonest" bureaucrats accept
intervention (see Franz Ringer, 1979). In bribes). For future reference, let us refer to
contrast, the 1980's experienced a shift in the social surplus of this allocation as S,1, (see
political attitudes with politicians such as Proposition 2). What we will show in this
Thatcher, Reagan, and Mulroney, emphasiz- section is that there is a third possible solution
ing costs of government and attempting to re- which will feature equilibrium corruption:in-
duce the scope of government involvement. tervention with partial corruption.
Observethatso far the optimalallocationdoes Let us first characterizethe optimal govern-
not feature"equilibrium" corruption;eitherthere ment regulationwith partialcorruption.This is
is laissez-faireor all bureaucratsare honest.This an allocation in which there are sufficient bu-
is because bureaucratsare homogenous,and all reaucraticrents so that "honest"bureaucratsdo
corruptionopportunitiesare the same. We will not take bribes, but the remaining fraction m,
generalizethis aspectin the next section. the "dishonest,"do. Equation (4), the technol-
ogy choice constraint, becomes:
III. Heterogeneity and Equilibrium Corruption
ni 1
A. Analysis (14) T+ -2 n e.
I m

We assume that once an agent becomes a


bureaucrat,he discovers whether he is good at As before, an entrepreneur who chooses the
taking bribes or not." Those who are good at good technology incurs the cost e, and re-
taking bribes (the "dishonest")get caught with ceives the benefit when he obtains the sub-
probability q ? 0, while those who are not sidy. In Sections I and II, the probability of
proficient at corruption (the "honest") get this even was (1 n)ln. Now, with proba-
caught with probabilityq > q. The probability bility is (1 - n) (1 - m)ln, the entrepre-
that an agent is good at taking bribes is m. In neur is inspected and receives the subsidy.
terms of the timing of events in Sections I and With probability (1 - n) -n/ln, there is
II, between stages 3 and 4, each bureaucrat inspection, but the bureaucrat is corrupt and
discovers whetherhe is good at taking bribes or extracts a bribe equal to or (T + s), and
not, and then decides whether to demand a irrespective of his technology choice, the en-
bribe. Exactly the same result would hold if trepreneur obtains the remaining (1 - a-) -
bureaucratshad different "moral costs" of ac- (T + s), which gives (14) as the relevant
cepting bribes (as argued by Klitgaard, 1988), technology choice constraint. As in the pre-
or alternatively,if some situations were more vious section, if a bureaucratand an entrepre-
conducive to the detection of corruption.All we neur are caught exchanging bribes, the
need is some heterogeneityin the "propensity" entrepreneur's revenue is confiscated irre
to accept (pay) bribes across bureaucrats spective of the technology choice. 12 Also
(projects). again we have imposed n ? 1/2 which will be
There are now three different candidate checked later.
We also need to ensure that "honest"bureau-
crats do not accept bribes, which, with a similar
It is possible to assume that agents know whether or
not they are good at corruptionbefore they choose their
12
profession. This would introduce some adverse selection Without this assumptionthe governmentbudget con-
featureswithout affecting the generalinsights. See Timothy straint below and the technology choice constraint, (14),
Besley andJohnMcLaren(1993) for an analysis of this type would have to be slightly modified without affecting the
of adverse selection. results.
VOL.90 NO. 1 ACEMOGLUAND VERDIER:MARKETFAILURESAND CORRUPTION 205

reasoning to above, we obtain the new partial- This differs from (5) for two reasons. First,
corruptionconstraint: agents recognize that if they enter bureaucracy,
with probabilitym, they will be good at taking
1 q bribes, and thus make more than w. And they
(15) w *(T + s) also realize that by becoming an entrepreneur
q
they will have to deal with corruptbureaucrats,
lq n uf thus the third term is added to the right-hand
e. side.
q 1-n 1-m The characterizationof optimal government
The budget constraintwith partialcorruption interventionis more involved than before, and
is differentas well, because some of the corrupt in orderto simplify the algebrafrom now on we
bureaucratsare caughtand theirreturnsare con- assume oa= 1; so entrepreneursget taxed fully
fiscated: when they meet a corrupt bureaucrat.Then,
combining the partial-corruptionconstraint,the
x budget constraint and the allocation of talent
(16) (1-n) w+ -n) (1-m) -* s
n condition yields the constraint set for govern-
ment interventionwith partial corruptionas:
+ (1n) *m * q *s
-q)
(18) x min{n;(1-n) *e
<(1I n)- m q (w + T)

L,m
+ (1n) * (1m) * I1-- *T.

The governmentstill pays w to all bureaucrats, -- ' m '


then"honest"bureaucrats, fraction1 - m, pay out 1-q 1- m41
a subsidywith probabilityxln, and dishonestbu- q 1-mJ'
reaucrats,exceptthe proportionq who get caught,
pay a subsidywithprobability1 (if the technology (1-n)2 y
is bad,they claim it is good andtakethe subsidy). n eJ
As for the revenues,a proportionq of the m (1 -
n) dishonestbureaucratsare caught,their wages and n ? 1/2. There are three terms in (18). The
are not paid out, and full taxes are collectedfrom firstone requiresx to be less thann. 'Thesecond
all the entrepreneurs who conspiredwith the cor- ensures that the 1 - m proportionof the bu-
ruptbureaucrats.Finally,the (1 - n) (1 - m) reaucratswho are "honest"do not accept bribes
honestbureaucrats findentrepreneurs withthe bad [cf., (15)]. The thirdone ensures that agents are
technology with probability1 -- xln, and this willing to apply to bureaucracy[cf., (17)].
gives the last term. Let A -A(q, m, q) mI( -m) (1 - q) +
Finally, the allocation of talent constraintbe- (1 -- q)lq *1/(1 - m) (1 - m * q). Then
comes: Proposition3 follows (proofin the Appendix).

PROPOSITION 3: Suppose that bureaucrats


(17) (1 -m) *w are corruptibleand that a proportion1 - m get
caughtwithprobabilityq, and a proportionm get
+m. (1-q^) [w+ 07 (T+ S)] caught with probabilityq E (0, q). Then there
exists a uniqueQ(m, q) E (0, q) such that:
1-n
n 1. When q < Q(m, q), government interven-
tion, wheneveroptimal,involves afraction m
1-n of bureaucratsaccepting bribes (i.e., partial
n corruption),and:
206 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW MARCH2000

(a) If y/e ? (1 + A)2 and j > e-(y x =(I-n)2y/ne 1


+ \/e), then the optimal allocation has
government intervention with n = x =n
as given by (8). on
partial-corrupt -)on UIn- --- U c---
OOSIr -7
(b) If yle E (1 + A; (1 + A)2) and B>
2e + A - e, then the optimal allocation
has government intervention with n =
contr t c,I
x = npC as given by n = (yle)l[(yl
e) + 1 + A].
(c) If yle < 1 + A and ,3 > e + [yl(yle) -
A], then the optimal allocation has gov-
ernment intervention with n = 1/2, x = npc y/e
1/2 (yle - A).
FIGURE4. EQuILIBRIUM WITH
CORRUPTION
(d) Otherwise the optimal allocation is lais-
HETEROGENEOUS BUREAUCRATS
sez-faire.
2. When q- Q(m, q), government interven-
tion, whenever optimal, involves no corrup- Puc
tion and the optimalallocation is as given in
Proposition 2 with q substituted by q and Governimot
oT = 1. Interventn"
\ GovernmentIntervention
Corrupti
B. Discussion No corruption

Proposition3 gives a characterizationof op-


timal intervention with heterogeneity among
bureaucrats.It formalizes one of our claims in
the introduction:for certainparametervalues, it No Govemment

is optimal to have government interventionto Intervention


deal with the market failure, but at the same
q
time allow some of the governmentemployees Q(m,q)
to be corrupt.Clearly, heterogeneityamong bu- FIGURE 5. PATFERNS OF GOVERNMENT INTERVENTION
reaucratsis crucial for equilibriumcorruption.
In the previous section, where bureaucratswere
homogenous, optimal governmentpolicy never
involved corruption.13Intuitively, the market crats," each getting caught with probabilityq.
failure is serious enough and requiresinterven- Since a fraction m of bureaucratscan only be
tion. Nevertheless, preventing all corruptionis caughtwith probability4'< q, points along this
excessively costly, so intervention with some line cannot be achieved. Instead, all corruption
corruptionis the best option. could be prevented by offering a high-enough
The technical intuition of this result can be wage to ensure that even bureaucratswith q4do
easily seen in Figure 4. As the propositionsug- not accept bribes, and this gives the smaller
gests, the comparison between partial corrup- triangle. Altenatively, the government could
tion and no corruptionboils down to whether allow partial corruption, which gives the shaded
the constraint set under one regime is larger triangle as the relevant constraint set. Since this
than the other. In this figure HH is the curve shaded triangle is larger than the no-corruption
that would apply with "homogenous bureau- triangle,partialcorruptionyields a largerchoice
set, and is thereforepreferredto no corruption
in this case.
13 In other examples of corruptionin the literature,het-
Figure 5 illustrates the optimal patter of
erogeneity is also important.For example, in Mookherjee
and Png (1995) corruptionmay be optimal because elimi- government intervention-in the space (p, 4u).
nating all corruptionwould induce excessive enforcement The critical level for 4, Q(m, q), separatesthe
effort from some law enforcers. two regimes of government intervention(with
VOL.90 NO. 1 ACEMOGLUAND VERDIER:MARKETFAILURESAND CORRUPTION 207

and without partialcorruption).The cutoff lev- tween governmentpay and corruptiondepends


els of f3 in both regimes (I,3 and n,) are on which parametersdiffer across countries (or
decreasing functions of q, because a less cor- time periods). For example, suppose q in-
ruptible bureaucracymakes government inter- creases. Then the partial-corruptionregime be-
vention more desirable. The thick lower comes more desirablerelative to no corruption.
envelope of these two lines separates the re- Also, since honest bureaucrats are easier to
gions of governmentinterventionand no inter- monitor, government wages can be reduced.
vention, and is also decreasing. Therefore,if the main differencebetween coun-
Figure 5 also gives us a sense of when an tries is due to differences in monitoringpossi-
optimal allocation with corruption is more bilities, we expect a negative relation between
likely to arise. The cutoff level in the corruption government pay and corruption. In contrast,
regime, 0, is an increasingfunction of m and a supposem increases:this will make government
decreasingfunction of q. This reflects again the interventionwith partial corruptionless desir-
fact that governmentinterventionis more likely able, but as long as we stay in the regime where
to be optimal when corruptionis less of a prob- it is optimalto have governmentintervention,w
lem. On the other hand, the cutoff line in the will increase, the fraction of agents who are
no-corruption regime, f3,, depends only on q. corruptwill increase, and the size of the bureau-
A reductionin m (or an increase in q) therefore cracy (1 - n) will also grow. Therefore,when
only shifts down the cutoff line I,3. A down- countries differ with respect to the fraction of
ward shift of the curve /,3 increases Q and "dishonest"bureaucrats,we expect a positive
enlargesthe region where governmentinterven- relationbetween wages and corruption.
tion with partialcorruptionis optimal.Hence, a Finally, the comparative static results with
low m (i.e., relatively few "dishonest"bureau- respect to y are similar to those in the previous
crats) and a high value of q (i.e., "honest" section. When q ? Q(m, q), Proposition 2
bureaucratsbeing relatively easy to monitor) applies and we have the same results as before.
make partial corruptionmore desirable. These When q < Q(m, q), there is equilibriumcor-
observations fit many instances of government ruption,but the extent of governmentinterven-
interventionin the developed world where cor- tion once again depends on how high yle is
ruptionexists, but is not the norm.For example, relative to f3 and q. If y is small, the constraint
national defense is an important public good on governmentinterventionis governmentrev-
and there are instances of corruptionin defense enues, and an increase in y makes intervention
procurementsin the OECD countries, but they more desirable.When y is high, the opportunity
appear to be relatively rare. In contrast, the cost of withdrawing agenits from the private
corruptionexperiences of many LDCs may be sector becomes more important,and furtherin-
at odds with this picture. In particular, it is creases in y make interventionless desirable(as
difficult to make an argument that licensing long as ,Bdoes not increase rapidly with y).
private businesses in Lima as in the cases dis-
cussed by DeSoto (1989) or the widespread IV. Extensions
corruptionin the Philippinesduringthe reign of
Marcos were designed to correct major market A. Misallocation of Talent
failures. In fact, the proportionof corruptbu-
reaucratsin many LDCs appearsto be very high Anothercriticism of governmentintervention
to fit our case of optimal partial corruption, is that it distorts the allocation of other re-
which requires a low value of m. The model sources, for example talent. Our model implies
therefore suggests that it is easier to justify the that this may also be a feature of optimal gov-
instances of corruptionin the advanced econo- ernmentintervention.In the presence of rents in
mies as costs of optimal governmentinterven- one sector, talent will be naturallymisallocated
tion, but much harderto do so for the LDCs. (see Acemoglu and Verdier 119981for a more
Another interesting comparativestatic exer- detailed discussion of misallocation of talent).
cise would be to uncover the link between cor- To formalizethis, considerthe model of Section
ruptionand (relative) wages in the government II where all bureaucratsface the same probabil-
sector (w). In our model, the correlation be- ity of getting caught, q. However, assume that
208 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW MARCH2000

each agent has a cost c of enteringentrepreneur-


ship. c is the private informationof an agent,
and cannotbe verified.Those with low c have a
comparativeadvantagefor entrepreneurship rel-
ative to bureaucracy.We assume that c has a
distributionF(c) in the populationwith support Ei U=n'~ +~x~ex
[0, c]. We also assume that c < y - e so that ll I /

the first best would still involve all agents


choosing entrepreneurship.Now consider the
configurationof parameterssuch that (7) is less
restrictivethan (1 1). We know from our previ-
ous analysis that in the absence of the costs, all
agentswantedto enterbureaucracy.This will be
truea fortioriwhen enteringthe privatesector is
costly. In other words, we will have:
x* y/e 1
1-n (a/e) I x
w>y-c- *.T
n FIGURE6. INTERIOR
SOLUTIONS

for all c. Since the governmentcannotcondition diagrammaticform of the maximization prob-


its hiring on c (it is not observed), a random lem with the corruptionconstraintand homog-
selection of applicants will be chosen for bu- enous bureaucratsas in Section II. The diagram
reaucracy. Therefore, as long as some agents shows that if the objective function is suffi-
have a comparative advantage for private sec- ciently concave (a low enough), then an interior
tor, the corruption constraint, whenever it is solution is possible. This interiorsolution would
binding, will lead to some degree of misalloca- have the same features as the cases we dis-
tion of talent. cussed earlier. In particular,there will be rents
for governmentemployees, and this allocation
B. Interior Solutions would be preferredto no governmentregulation
if the market failure it is trying to correct is
The optimal allocations in our analysis so far sufficientlyimportant(i.e., 13high enough). It is
were corner solutions, n = x, n = 1/2, or n = straightforwardto check that an increase in (3
1 (and x = 0). This implies that changes in ,3 would now lead to an increase in x, thus the
never led to changes in x (unless they switched more importantis the externality, the larger is
the economy from no interventionto the regime the fraction of people induced to choose the
with governmentintervention). good technology. Moreover, the comparative
To illustrate how some degree decreasing static results of Section II continue to hold. For
returnschanges our results, we modify the ex- example, for given ,B, an increase in y at first
ternality from (3 * x to ,3 * xa with a < 1. makes governmentinterventionmore desirable
Therefore, the externality from entrepreneurs as governmentrevenues increase, but as further
using the good technology is always positive increases in y raises the opportunity cost of
but exhibits decreasing returns.The analysis of intervention, government regulation becomes
the previous sections would carry over un- less desirable.
changed and the same constraintsets as in Fig-
ures 1, 2, and 4 will apply in the three cases we V. Conclusion
analyzed (respectively, without corruptioncon-
straint,with corruptionconstraintand homoge- Textbooks on public finance emphasize the
nous bureaucrat,and with corruptionconstraint role of the government in correcting market
and heterogeneous constraints). However, in- failures. In reality, we observe many govern-
stead of maximizing a linear function, we now ment failures which may be hard to reconcile
have a concave function. Figure 6 draws the with the textbook view. We argue in this
VOL.90 NO. ] ACEMOGLUAND VERDIER:MARKETFAILURESAND CORRUPTION 209

paper that as long as three plausible condi- of the distinction between bureaucratic cor-
tions are satisfied, optimal government inter- ruption and corruption in the private sector.
vention aimed at correcting important market The conventional wisdom is that the former is
failures will be associated precisely with much more harmful, but we are not aware of
these observed government failures. These any formal analysis of this issue. This paper
three conditions are: emphasized the role of government policy in
modifying ex post returns and thus affecting
1. Government intervention requires "bureau- ex ante behavior. Corruption prevents this
crats" to gather informationand implement useful role of government intervention. If pri-
policies. vate corruption has less scope for influencing
2. At least some of the agents who enter bu- ex ante behavior, it will be less harmful.
reaucracy are corruptible,in the sense that Nevertheless, in many situations, corruption
they are willing to misrepresenttheir infor- in the private sector may hinder contracting
mation at the right price. between agents and lead to similar inefficien-
3. There is some amount of heterogeneity cies. The analysis of these issues is also an
among bureaucrats. obvious area for future research.

These three features imply that government


intervention will create corruption opportuni- APPENDIX
ties, rents for public employees, and misalloca-
tion of resources. The possibility of corruption PROOF OF PROPOSITION2:
is likely to increase the size of governmentand Suppose bureaucratsare corruptibleand the
public-sector wages, as compared to the case governmentintervenes.We can characterizethe
where corruption was not possible. And yet, total surplus as:
these many faces of governmentfailure do not
necessarily imply that governmentintervention 1. If y/e ? [1 + o- (1 -- q)/q]2, (11) is less
is harmful.They may arise because the govern- restrictivethan (7), thus the solution is then
ment is trying to tax some activities while sub- n-x-n > 1/2 and SS - (y - , -
e)
sidizing others in order to deal with market Vy7(Vy+ Ve).
failures. 2. If yle C (1 + o- (1 - q)Iq; [1 r- oS (1 -
Not all instances of governmentintervention q)/q]2), then (11) is more restrictivethan (7)
are in line with this story. Our model predicts and y is sufficiently high that all entrepre-
that government intervention with partial cor- neurs choose the good technology: n = x =
ruptionis likely to be optimal only when cor- nc > 1/2, nc < n and SS, [(y + -
e)
ruptionis relatively rare and the marketfailure y]l[y + e + e * 0 (1 - q)lq].
it is trying to correct is relatively important. 3. If yle < 1 + o-I (1 - q)lq, then (10) is
Many cases of corruption from developing more restrictivethan (7) but y is low so that
countries do not fit this pattern.This suggests if all entrepreneurschoose the good technol-
that even though corruptionin LDCs may be ogy, there will not be enough government
"equilibrium,"it is unlikely to be "optimal." revenue to pay the bureaucrats.Thus, we
Our analysis is clearly special because we as- have n = 1/2,x = max{ 1/2 (yle -oI (1 -
sumed governmentpolicies to be optimally de- q)/q), O} and SSc = 1/2 y + 1/2 (-e)
termined. Nevertheless, a simple theoretical [yle - or (1 - q)/q].
frameworkof optimal governmentintervention
may be the place to start in assessing the pros If there is no intervention, total surplus is
and cons of governmentinterventionin differ- SSng
= y. ComparingSCin the three cases with
ent environments.Furtherresearch to analyze y, we obtain Proposition2.
how "equilibrium"governmentpolicies and op-
timal government intervention interact would PROOF OF PROPOSITION3:
be useful. Suppose the government intervenes and
Finally, an interesting and important issue wishes to allow partialcorruptionwith the frac-
that we have not discussed is the foundations tion m of bureaucratswho are "dishonest"and
210 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW MARCH2000

are accepting bribes. The optimal allocation is while the feasible set (DP, for interventionwith
given as: corruptionis:
(A3)
1. If yle < I + A, thenn = 1/2. In this case,
the partial-corruptionconstraint is binding (x, n) suchthatn : 1/2; and
and the allocation of talent constraint is FI)c{x?minjn(1 n) -A(q,m,q)-n;
slack. The numberof entrepreneurschoosing
the good technology is: x = max{ 1/2 [yle -
A]; 01. Social surplus is SS, V/2y + '/2

(13- e) [yle - A].


2. If yle E (1 + A, (I + A)2), then the ---
y
}

partial-corruptionconstraint is binding, the n e '


(1-n)2
size of the private sector is:
Comparing(A2) to (A3), it follows that (n C
y
(Dpc (and therefore SSP, is larger than SSnC) if
e and only if: A(q, m, q) ? (1 - q)lq. This
(A1) n,= condition is equivalent to:
- + I + A
e
(m + 1 --m9) ' (1-m)(1 -4).
and x = nP. We have social surplus:
Ssp, = [(yle) * (y + C - e)l(yle + I +
A)]. The left-hand side of this inequalityis continu-
3. If yle > (1 + A)2, then the allocation con- ously decreasing in q E (0, q), from a maxi-
straintis binding and we have n x = n as mum of 1 - m to (1 - m)(1 - q). The
given by (8). SS . = SSg as in Section II, right-handside is a quadraticfunction, B(q),
subsection B. and is increasing for q C (0, min(q, ql2 +
(1 - q/2m))). Moreover, B(O) = 0, and
Now that we have the surplus from govern- B(min(q, q/2 + (1 - q)/2m)) ' B(q) = 1-
ment intervention with partial corruption q. It thereforefollows that there exists a unique
(SSp,), we can compare this surplus to that Q(nm, q) E (0, min(q, (q/2) + (1 -q)/2m))
from government interventionwith no corrup- such that, B(q) ' (1 - m) (1 - q) if and
tion (SS,,,), and to output with laissez-faire only if q ?, Q(m, q). Hence, when q is smaller
(SSng) . than this threshold, we have A(q, m, q) ' (1 -
First, note that irrespectiveof parameterval- q)lq, and governmentinterventionwith partial
ues, the social surplus of no intervention is corruptionwill be preferredto government in-
always SS,,g = y. Second, comparing govern- tervention with no corruptionwhile when q is
ment intervention with no corruption (SS,1.) to larger than Q(m, q), no corruption is pre-
intervention with partial corruption (SSPL) is ferred.14
equivalent to comparingthe constraintssets of
these regimes in the space of (x, n). The fea- REFERENCES
sible set of points (x, n), for interventionwith-
out corruption,(Dn,, is given by: Acemoglu, Daron and Verdier, Thierry. "Proper-
ty Rights, Corruptionand the Allocation of
(x,n) suchthatnz? V2 ; and Talent: A General Equilibrium Approach."
(A2) '1' l x I< in{(]-n) -q t; Economic Journal, September 1998, 108
-
(450), pp. 1381-403.

ne q) 14 This result also establishes our earlierclaim that when


_'1n)2 *y }|
all bureaucratsare homogenous, it is optimal not to allow
tn e any corruptioni.
VOL.90 NO. I ACEMOGLUAND VERDIER:MARKETFAILURESAND CORRUPTION 211

Banerjee, Abhijit. "A Theory of Misgover- BureaucraticCorruption,"American Behav-


nance." Mimeo, Massachusetts Institute of ioral Scientist,November 1964, (1), pp. 8-14.
Technology, 1997. Lindert,PeterH. "ModemFqiscalRedistribution:
Becker, Gary S. "Crime and Punishment: An A PreliminaryEssay." University of Califor-
Economic Approach." Journal of Political nia-Davis, Agricultural History Center,
Economy, March-April 1968, 76(2), pp. Working Paper No. 55, 1989.
167-217. ___ ."The Rise in Social Spending, 1880-
Becker, Gary S. and Stigler, George J. "Law En- 1930." Explorations in Economic History,
forcement, Malfeasance and the Compensa- January1994, 31(1), pp. 1-37.
tion of Enforcers."Journal of Legal Studies, Mauro, Paolo. "Corruptionand Growth."Quar-
January1974, 3(1), pp. 1-19. terly Journal of Economics, August 1995,
Besley, Timothy and McLaren, John. "Taxes and 110(3), pp. 681-712.
Bribery:The Role of Wage Incentives."Eco- Mills, Edward S. The burden of government.
nomic Journal, January 1993, 103(416), pp. Stanford, CA: Hoover Institution Press,
119-41. 1986.
Calvo, Guillermo and Wellisz, Stanislaw. "Hier- Mookherjee, Dilip and Png, I. P. L. "Monitoring
archy, Ability, and Income Distribution." vis-a-vis Investigation in Enforcement of
Journal of Political Economy,October 1979, Law." American Economic Review, June
87(5), pp. 991-1010. 1992, 82(3), pp. 556-65.
Carino, Ledivina V. Bureaucraticcorruptionin _ . "Corruptible Law Enforcers: How
Asia: Causes, consequences and controls. Should They Be Compensated?"Economic
Manila: JMC Press, 1986. Journal, January 1995, 105(428), pp. 145-
Carrillo, Juan D. "Corruption in Hierarchies." 59.
Mimeo, University of Toulouse, France, Niskanen, William A. Bureaucracy and repre-
1995. sentative government. Chicago: Aldine/
Crozier, Maurice. Bureaucratic phenomenon. Atherton, 1971.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1964. Peters, Guy B. Thepolitics of bureaucracy.New
De Soto, Hernando. Theotherpath: The invisible York: Longman, 1989.
revolution in the third world. New York: Ringer, Franz. Educationand society in modern
Harper,1989. Europe.Bloomington, IN: Indiana University
Donahue, John D. The privatization decision. Press, 1979.
New York: Basic Books, 1989. Rose-Ackerman, Susan. Corruption:A study in
Klitgaard, Robert. Controllingcorruption.Berke- political economy. New York: Academic
ley, CA: Universityof CaliforniaPress, 1988. Press, 1978.
. "Incentive Myopia." World Develop- Shleifer, Andrei and Vishny, Robert W. "Corrup-
ment, April 1989, 17(4), pp. 447-59. tion." QuarterlyJournal of Economics, Au-
Laffont, Jean Jacques and Tirole, Jean. A theory gust 1993, 108(3), pp. 599-618.
of incentives in procurementand regulation. _ . "Politicians and Firms." Quarterly
Cambridge,MA: MIT Press, 1993. Journal of Economics, November 1994, 109
Lal, Deepak. The poverty of development eco- (4), pp. 995-1026.
nomics. Cambridge,MA: HarvardUniversity Wilson, James Q. Bureaucracy: What govern-
Press, 1985. ment agencies do and why they do it. New
Leff, Nathaniel. "Economic Development Through York: Basic Books, 1989.

Вам также может понравиться