Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 18

World Development, Vol. 23, No. 8, pp.

1421-1438, 1995
Copyright 0 1995 Elsevier Science Ltd
Pergamon Printed in Great Britain. All rights reserved
0305-750x/95 $9.50 + 0.00

0305-750x(95)00043-7

The Developmental State, Government, and


Singapore’s Economic Development Since 1960

W. G. HUFF*
University of Glasgow, U.K. and Australian National University, Australia

Summary. - Government interventionism is widely acknowledged to characterize less-developed


countries, but consensus is lacking as to whether it promotes economic development, and if so, how. The
present article analyzes the nature of government involvement m the Singapore model of economic devel-
opment, and emergence of a developmental state closely associated with this model. It compares
Singapore’s experience with South Korea’s and Taiwan’s, where government also contributed to
development success, and with other Asian countries where government failed to play a strong develop-
mental role.

1. INTRODUCTION from Britain, the People’s Action Party (PAP) has


held power, for much of the period winning all the
Singapore has been described as “the world’s most seats in regular parliamentary elections. Lee Kuan
successful economy” (Lim, 1983) and regarded as Yew led the government until his retirement in 1990,
“the most successful of East Asia’s ‘four dragons’,” by then as the world’s longest-serving Prime Minister.
which also comprise South Korea, Hong Kong and One aim of the present article is to draw together
Taiwan (Giordano and Kato, 1993). In 1992, the major features of government interventionalism in
Singapore’s Gross National Product (GNP) per capita the Singapore model of economic development. This
reached US$1.5,750, with further growth of 9.9% in provides a framework for the article’s other, and main,
1993 and 10.5% during the first half of 1994. Per purpose, which is to focus on a wider issue, and one
capita income is the 16th highest in the world, and hitherto given little systematic consideration: what
over two-thirds of the US level, compared to one- factors made government interventionism successful
seventh in 1965 (World Bank, 1967 and 1994). An in promoting economic development in Singapore.
island of 3.1 million people, Singapore is the world’s After all, government involves itself in the economy
eighth largest exporter of machinery and transport and “is powerful in nearly evev developing country”
equipment and ranks 12th in exports of services (Sen, 1983, p. 752). but often with poor results, or
(GATT. 1993). By any measure, social welfare has worse. Indeed, by the 197Os, the frequency of a nega-
improved markedly, and absolute poverty has all but tive outcome had given rise to a development eco-
disappeared. nomics literature which had at its core “the rejection
Since the 197Os, such economic development has of intervention. Government was the problem rather
drawn a stream of delegations from Africa and Asia than the solution” (Fishlow, 1991, p. 1730).
(Financial Times, 1978; Lee, 1993) to find out “how More recently, however, not least in the light of
Singapore did it.” A seminal article by L. Lim (1983) Singapore’s interventionism, but also South Korea’s
which exploded the myth of Singapore as a luissez-
faire economy opened the way to an increasing recog-
nition that a “heavily interventionist” state guided * This paper has benefited from the comments of R. B.
DuBoff, J. F Ermisch, J. C. B. Chau, two anonymous refer-
Singapore. Most observers now recognize that
ees, seminar participants at the Australian National
Singapore’s government was on the whole “very
University and the Umversity’s ECHOSEA Group led by A.
intrusive in both the economy and the society” J. S. Reid. Work was carried out with the aid of grants from
(Krause, 1988, p. S62), and that “The state has played the Scottish Economic Society. John Robertson Bequrst and
a central role in the development of Singapore” generous help from the Nuffield Foundation which financed
(Findlay and Wellisz, 1993, p. 7). Interventionism has an indispensable research tnp lo Singapore. The help of ail
been accompanied by remarkable political continuity: these bodies is gratefully acknowledged. Final revision
since 1959, when Singapore gained independence accepted: January 26, 1995.
1422 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

and Taiwan’s, the emphasis has shifted from “govem- (a) Foundations for rapid economic development
ment failure” - a lapse into inept economic policies and peculiarities of the Singapore model
- to include the possibility of the “developmental
state” which plays an integral part in promoting eco- The first, 1956, estimates of national income for
nomic development. East Asian experience showed Singapore showed that per capita income had
that “government intervention can work well if done increased “fairly steadily and rapidly since 1948” and,
properly” (Collins, 1987, p. 446) and the “sometimes at probably over a third of the United Kingdom’s, was
policy-driven nature of dynamic comparative advan- very much greater than almost anywhere else in Asia
tage” (Bardhan, 1993, p. 133). The “key question” (Benham, 1959, pp. l-2). Prosperity had spread, so
became “not whether there is government action in the that Singapore was “almost certainly the only place in
Far Eastern economies, but rather how these success- Asia where there is a really substantial middle class”
ful economies managed their intervention and strate- (Silcock, 1959, pp. 43, 158). After the island’s union
gic decisions-making in ways that dominate those of with Malaya to form Malaysia in 1963, the August
the unsuccessful ones” (Bhagwati, 1987, p. 285). 1965 separation from Malaysia and British military
The development economics agenda again features withdrawal beginning in 1966 were macroeconomic
state and market - indeed, as “perhaps the central shocks to the new Republic of Singapore, creating sig-
issue of today’s development debate” (Lipton, 1992, nificant unemployment. But neither negated earlier
p. 426). developmental advantages. During 1960-66, includ-
The article is structured in three further sections. ing a period of import substitution as part of the
The next identifies where state intervention was cru- Malaysian experiment, Singapore’s economy grew at
cial in the Singapore development model. Section 3 an annual average rate of 5.7% (Table 1).
attempts to answer the question of what allowed a Upon becoming a Republic in 1965, Singapore,
developmental state to emerge in Singapore, and sets alone among developing countries, existed as a city
out five main features which combined to create it. A state able to close its borders and regulate labor flows
final section draws some lessons of government inter- to prevent the erosion of rising per capita incomes
ventionism in Singapore and assesses how relevant through immigration from the surrounding region
its experience may be to less developed countries quicker than labor could be absorbed. By contrast,
(LDCs). Hong Kong was subject to massive labor inflows dur-
ing 1945-55, causing population increase of about
400%, with continued rapid growth into the mid-
2. THE SINGAPORE DEVELOPMENT MODEL 1960s (Szczepanik, 1958; Chow and Papanek, 1981).
A second highly unusual aspect of Singapore is loca-
This section focuses on major constituents con- tion. Its geographical situation, astride the world’s
tributing to the Singapore development model, and main east-west communications routes and bridging
analyzes them in turn. Subsection (a) draws attention the time zone gap between the New York/London and
to Singapore’s favorable 1959 starting point, indi- Hong Kong/Tokyo financial markets, can be thought
cates recent economic performance and considers of as a useful national resource. Location has been
two highly unusual features which differentiated exploited to further economic development in manu-
Singapore from nearly all other developing countries facturing and services - the two main pillars of
- its strong locational advantages and city state sta- Singapore’s economy (Table 2).
tus. What might be regarded as the Singapore model The breakup of Malaysia left Singapore with little
proper, as opposed to the setting in which it was option but to turn decisively outward to export domes-
embedded, is dealt with in subsection (b). tically made manufactures. Initially, development

Table 1. Singapore macroeconomic indicators, 1960-92 (%)

1960-66 1960-69 1967-79 1970-79 1980-92

Annual real GDP growth rate 5.7 8.0 9.7 8.3 6.7
Annual inflation rate* 1.1 1.1 5.4 5.8 2.4
Savings ratio+ 6.7 11.5 27.5 28.8 42.7
Investment ratiot 17.5 20.7 38.5 40.5 41.3
*GDP deflator.
t’fbe savings ratio and investment ratio are defined respectively as Gross National Savings and Gross
Capital Formation divided by Gross Domestic Product, All variables are in real terms deflated by the GDP
deflator.
Sources: Singapore, Department of Statistics, Singapore National Accounrs 1987 (Singapore, 1988);
Singapore, Ministry of Trade and Industry, Economic Survey of Singapore 1993 (Singapore, 1994).
SINGAPORE’S ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 1423

Table 2. Singapore GDP and employment by industrial sector, 1960-92 ($m at 1985 marketprices,
persons and %)

1960 1969 1979 1992


(a) GDP*
Total $m 5.0585 10,730.o 26.284.7 64,771 .O
Agriculture & quarrying 3.8 2.1 1.5 0.4
Manufacturing 16.6 23.2 29.4 27.6
Construction & utilities 7.0 10.7 9.1 8.9
Commerce 24.6 22.9 19.4 18.2
Transport & communications 8.8 7.2 11.6 14.7
Financial &business services 14.0 16.5 18.9 26.1
Other services 19.6 15.7 12.2 10.2

(b) Employment+
Persons 000 471.9 650.9 1.021.0 1592.0
Agriculture & quarrying 7.3 3.8 1.6 0.2
Manufacturing 15.7 22.0 28.9 27.0
Construction & utilities 6.1 7.8 6.3 6.9
Commerce 24.2 23.5 23.3 22.9
Transport & communications 10.7 12.1 11.6 10.5
Financial &business services 4.6 3.5 7.1 10.9
Other services 31.4 27.3 21.2
*For GDP, the percentage shares may not add to 1002, since imputed bank service charges are deducted
and import duties added to arrive at total GDP, but account is not taken of these for individual industries.
+Employment figures for 1960 are from the 1957 Census and for 1969 from the 1970 Census. Employment
figures for 1992 refer to June 1993.
Sources: Singapore, Census of Population 1957 (Singapore, 1964); Singapore, Department of Statistics,
Economic and Social Statistics, 19604982 (Singapore, 1982); Singapore, Department of Statistics,
Singapore National Accounts 1987 (Singapore, 1988); Singapore, Department of Statistics, Yearbook of
Statistics (various years); Singapore, Ministry of Trade and Industry, Economic Survey of Singapore 1993
(Singapore, 1994).

relied largely on manufacturing as the “engine of Republic an attractive manufacturing location by


growth,” with a particular emphasis on electronic and keeping down the “distance costs” of exporting to the
electrical products. During 1967-79, manufacturing West (Helleiner, 1973). Location was even more
employment increased over fourfold, and the share of important in Singapore’s development of services
manufacturing in GDP rose from 20.5% to 29.4% exports (internationally traded services sold to non-
(Singapore, Department of Statistics or Economic Singapore residents). These included air traffic,
Development Board, 1990; Singapore, Department of telecommunications, shipping, and cargo handling
Statistics, 1988). Manufacturing production was activities, but above all international financial and
highly export-oriented, as measured by the increase in business services. Government systematically built on
direct manufactured exports (excluding petroleum) Singapore’s location and time zone advantages to pro-
from 13.6% of GDP in 1967 to 47.1% by 1979 mote the Republic as a regional and international
(Table 3). financial center. After 1979 financial and business ser-
Singapore’s geographical position and excellent vices replaced manufacturing as the engine of growth
international transport links helped to make the and between 1979 and 1992 grew at an annual average

Table 3. Singapore direct manufactured exports, 1960-92 (at 1985 marketprices)

1960 1966 1967 1969 1979 1992

Sm 542.5 933.3 1,127.5 1.827.4 12,368.O 37.950.5


% of GDP* 10.7 12.7 13.6 17.0 47.1 58.6
*Data are deflated by the GDP deflator for manufacturing.
Statistics refer to firms with 10 or more workers, and exclude petroleum, rubber processing and granite
quarrying.
Sources: Singapore, Department of Statistics or Economic Development Board, Report on rhe Census of
bldrrstrial Production (various years); Singapore, Department of Statistics, Singapore National Accounts
1987: Singapore. Ministry of Trade and Industry, Economic Survey of Singapore (various years).
1424 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

rate of 9.9%, to make up 26.1% of GDP by the later 1986, p. 1 i), rapidly dealt with this problem. By 1969,
date (Table 2). By 1993, Singapore was the world’s for comparable job classifications in key electrical and
fourth largest foreign exchange market, after London, electronics assembly industries, hourly compensation
New York and Tokyo, the center of the Asian dollar costs in Singapore were less than one-eleventh of the
market, and host to 115 foreign banks and 78 mer- US level, and below those in South Korea, Taiwan and
chant banks. Hong Kong. Productivity levels were as high as in the
other newly industrialized countries (NICs) and
higher than the United States (US Tariff Commission,
(b) The role of government in the Singapore 1970). At the beginning of the 197Os, Singapore had
development model the lion’s share of offshore assembly activities of
the US and European semiconductor industries
Initial advantages can always be dissipated and (Chang, 1971).
existing strengths ignored: this subsection, which Although Singapore’s ability after the split with
shows how government played a central role in shap- Malaysia to close its borders and regulate labor flows
ing the Singapore development model, also carries the obviated the typical developing country difficulty of
message that policy choices matter. Government workers being drawn into urban areas faster than
intervention in Singapore’s economy concentrated in modem sector jobs can be created, this was quickly
three areas - the labor market, taxation and fiscal replaced by the potentially even more serious problem
incentives, and state-owned enterprises. Although of how to prevent wages being bid up above inter-
Singapore’s was a strongly private enterprise econ- nationally competitive levels in a small, rapidly
omy, it is important to note, as will be stressed later, industrializing country nearing full employment. In
that interventionism in these three strategic areas 1972, the government responded by establishing
allowed a substantial measure of government direc- the National Wages Council as a tripartite body with
tion of the entire economy. All three areas in which the equal representation from the government, the
government intervened could be controlled through People’s Action Parry (PAP) controlled National
the domestic sector of Singapore’s economy as Trades Union Congress and employers. Thus, “the
opposed to attempting to influence the international or Singapore Government has not felt inhibited from get-
world economy on which Singapore, as a small coun- ting directly involved in labour-management negotia-
try, could have no effect. tions” and at least until 198 1 was “the central focus of
power because it performs the dual functions of defm-
(i) Labor market regulation ing national objectives and inter-relating parochial
The most distinctive feature of the Singapore interests through the executive authority of the state”
development model was government control over (Kim, 1981, p. 67). After 1981 the government’s role
wages and labor. Historically, Singapore was a high- is said to have altered from a “dominant partner” to
cost manufacturing producer, with wage costs one whose “influence on wage changes remains
“20-30% too high for world markets” (United strong” (Pang, 1988, p. 214). By any account, as
Nations, 1961, p. 115). In 1967 and 1968, labor legis- Manning and Pang (1990, p. 71) conclude the
lation framed by the PAP, which “de-politicised the National Wages Council “has had a powerful influ-
labour movement, established de facto government ence on wage determination.” The National Wages
control over unions [and] transferred bargaining Council could successfully establish itself as a body
power from workers to employers” (Lim and Pang, which achieved “consensus” in line with government

Table 4. Singapore. United States, Japan and Asian countries hourly compensation costs for producrion
workers in manufacturing, 1975-92 (current VS$ and index, United Stares = 100)

1975 1980 1992

S Index $ Index $ Index

United States 6.36 100 9.87 100 16.17 100


Japan 3.00 47 5.52 56 16.28 101
Singapore 0.84 13 I .49 15 4.95 31
South Korea 0.32 5 0.96 10 4.93 30
Taiwan 0.40 6 1.oo 10 5.13 32
Hong Kong 0.76 12 1.51 15 3.92 24
Asian NICs* 0.52 8 1.17 12 4.84 30

*Asian NICs refers to a US trade-weighted average level for Singapore, South Korea, Taiwan and
Hong Kong.
Sources: US Department of Labor (1994).
SINGAPORE’S ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 1425

Table 5. Singapore real average monthly earnings for all market” (Fields and Wan, 1989, p. 1475) produced the
workers, 1978-92 (1988 = 100) internationally competitive wages and the absence of
strikes attractive to multinational enterprises (MNEs)
1978 57.9 1986 91.4 manufacturing for export as part of vertically inte-
1979 60.5 1987 93.8
grated international operations. As important for
1980 63.3 1988 100.0
political stability, which must underpin longer
1981 63.5 1989 107.3
1982 70.8 1990 113.3
term economic development in the host country,
1983 77.1 1991 119.6 Singapore’s real wages doubled during 1978-90, and
1984 83.2 1992 126.5 continue to grow strongly (Table 5). Furthermore, the
1985 89.4 1993 131.3 Singapore government promoted skill acquisition and
human capital development to the benefit of workers.
Sources: Singapore, Ministry of Labour, Yearbook of
L.abour Starisrics (various years).
(ii) Direct foreign invesfmenr
objectives because by the 1970s two of its constituents A small economy like Singapore’s can be usefully
were the government, because no significant non- thought of as able to tap a perfectly elastic supply of
government trade unions existed in Singapore, and capital at a given world rate of profitability. Labor
because employers apparently did not feel strong market regulation by government which pegged wage
enough to break the cartel and bid up wage rates, rises at or below productivity gains was essential in
despite incentives to do so due to Singapore’s labor safeguarding this required rate of profit, and allowed
scarcity and desirability as a production base (Lim, two further features of the Singapore model to
1987, p. 51). emerge: high foreign investment and an associated
While not mandatory, throughout the period since reliance on foreign enterprise. Fundamental to the
1972 National Wages Council recommendations have Singapore model was that capital came largely not as
been closely observed. A measure of the National portfolio investment but as direct foreign investment
Wages Council’s effectiveness is that, as Table 4 which gave rise to almost complete foreign MNE
shows, during 1975-92, compensation levels for dominance of the manufacturing export sector. After
production workers in Singapore manufacturing 1967-69, direct foreign investment made a growing
increased more slowly than in the other Asian NICs - contribution to domestic capital formation in
the benchmark against which the government mea- Singapore (Table 6). By the 1970s capital account
sured success in containing labor costs. Although ris- inflows in excess of Singapore’s balance-of-payments
ing female labor force participation rates and the current account deficits, reflected in Table 1, allowed
presence of at least 200,000 guest workers helped to the Republic to begin its accumulation of large foreign
dampen wage pressure, a growing chorus of com- reserves (Wong, 1986). During 1980-90, Singapore
plaints about widespread “job-hopping” in Singapore received more direct foreign investment in absolute
was indicative of wage rates held below free market terms than any other LDC. On a per capita basis, and
levels. At the same time, the government all but elim- using 1990 population, the figures were US$767 for
inated work stoppages. Singapore’s “regulated labor Singapore compared to US31.50 for China, the fourth-

Table 6. Singapore measures of the contribution of directforeign invesrmenr to cupirul uccumulutiorl,


1967-92 (1985 marker prices, annual uverqes)’

Gross fixed Foreign investment in IMF figures for direct


capital formation manufacturing sector gross foreign investment in
(GFCF) fixed assets Singapore
Q of ‘h of
$m $m GFCF $m GFCF

1967-69 2.382.2 261.4 11.0 219.0 9.2


197&79 6,648.6 896.7 135 1.471.3 22.1
198c92 17.498.2 2.1 12.3 12.1 4.609.3 26.3

*For 1980-91, the figures for “Foreign investment in manufacturing sector gross fixed assets” refer to
1980-90.
Sources: Singapore, Department of Statistics, Singapore Nurionul Accorrn~s 1987; Singapore, Mimstry of
Trade and Industry, Economic Survey r$ Singupore (various years); Singapore Economic Development
Board, Annual Report or Yeurbook (V&OUS years); International Monetary Fund, Btrkmce o( Ptr~~rerrf.r
Sturistfcs Yearbook. Vol. 27. 1967-74, p. I of Singapore section, Vol. 29, 197X, p. 532 and part I of the fol-
lowing years: 1985, p. 559, 1986, p. 581, 1987, p. 597, 1992, p. 617, 1993, p. 613: InternatIonal Monetary
Fund, btferntrtionul Finuncinl Srutisrics Yeurbook 1990, pp. 634-635, Aprrl 1994, p. 480.
1426 WORLDDEVELOPMENT

Table 7. Singapore manufacturing value added as a percentage of output, 1973-92*

1973 1978 1984 1992 % of total


1992
manufacturing
value added
All industries 32.0 26.3 27.0 34.6 100.0
Electronic products
and components 32.2 29.9 27.9 38.5
Electrical machinery
and apparatus 39.0t 33.7 37.6 38.7 4.4
Transport equipment 46.8 47.4 51.7 45.2 8.6
Machineryexcept electrical
and electronic 39.9 49.1 45.7 38.5 6.4
Fabricated metal oroducts 36.8 34.5 38.7 37.8 7.1
*Figures include petroleum refineriesand products.
tlncludes electronicproducts.
Sources: Sineanore. Deoartment of Statistics or Economic Development Board, Report on the Census of
Industrial Prkhctih (kious years).

largest LDC foreign investment recipient (United level of domestic saving. Its achievement and corre-
Nations, 1992). In 1975, wholly- and majority-owned spondingly high investment was long regarded as a
foreign companies accounted for 71.3% of the output key to rapid growth by Singapore planners and policy
and 84.1% of the direct exports of Singapore’s manu- makers. As early in 1963, Singapore’s Minister of
facturing sector. By 1992, this dominance had Finance, Goh Keng Swee, pointed to a high invest-
increased even further, to 74.2% of output and 845% ment ratio as “the paramount need.. .in an economy
of direct exports (Singapore, Department of Statistics which wants to expand its basic wealth at a fast rate,
or Economic Development Board, 1975, 1992). a target like 20% or more should be aimed at”
According to Lee Kuan Yew (1990), in 1990 of “the (Singapore Legislative Assembly, November 1963).
top 20% of key positions in our society...non- Goh concluded in 1968 that Singapore had achieved
Singaporeans would comprise at least 40% of the key “take-off,” and recalled telling Lee Kuan Yew that the
decision makers.. .at the moment we are using bor- higher savings rate which could thus be attained
rowed brainpower, that of the multinationals.” would sustain double-digit growth (Goh, 1989).
Singapore now hosts some 4,000 MNEs, and over From the late 196Os, jobs created by MNEs aug-
two-thirds of the Fortune 100 companies (Financial mented the savings base in three ways. One was to
Times, 1994; Lim, Pang and Findlay, 1993, p. 127). reduce unemployment, which fell from 8.9% in 1966
The value-added share of gross output at free trade to 4.5% in 1973, the latter effectively constituting full
prices measures technical development in manufac- employment. Second, the savings base widened as
turing, and although in Singapore this ratio rose some- more women joined the labor force. The female par-
what for the sector as a whole during 1978-91, in the ticipation rate, in 1957 just 21.6%, rose to 44.3% by
electronics industry it actually fell (Table 7). A manu- 1980 and to 53.0% in 1990. Third, the savings base
facturing sector run by multinationals which primarily depended as jobs created by MNEs encouraged labor
undertake research and development elsewhere, weak reallocation to higher paid jobs. This last was reflected
local inputs to technological progress, small indige- in a fall in the proportion of own-account, and unpaid
nous research and often repetitive, low-value added family, workers in Singapore’s labor force from
operations heavily dependent on relatively poorly paid 20.7% in 1970 to 13.3% in 1980 and 7.8% by 1990
female workers, are all consistent with Singapore’s (Singapore, 1973 and 1993).
remarkably high share of GDP going to foreigners Singapore fully realized its increased savings
(Lim and Pang, 1984; Lim, 1987)‘. During 1985-92, potential. Although under 10% for most of the 196Os,
fully 32% of Singapore’s GDP accrued to foreign the savings rate averaged 29% in the 1970s and over
firms and individuals (Singapore, Department of 40% from 1980-the world’s highest (Table 1). Little
Statistics, Yearbook, 1992, p. 79). was voluntary about the savings process. Public sec-
tor saving was the driving force, and increased from
(iii) Government-forced savings less than a quarter of national savings in 1974 to three-
Control of the labor market and massive direct for- fifths by 1984 (Table 8). Seven main statutory boards,
eign investment, which led to job creation by MNEs, with monopoly power, were central in determining
made it possible for the government to force a high public sector savings - the Housing and
SINGAPORE’S ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 1427

Table 8. Singapore sources of gross national savings, 1974-85

Gross national Public sector Private sector


savings* savings savings
Other
Central Provident (corporate +
Fund peisonal)
$m $m % GNS $m %GNS $m % GNS
1974 3,220 736 22.8 643 20.0 1,841 51.2
1975 3,985 1,362 34.2 821 20.6 1,802 45.2
1976 4,580 1,470 32.1 831 18.1 2,279 49.8
1977 5,079 2,021 39.8 888 17.5 2,170 42.7
1978 5,928 2,230 31.6 1,027 17.3 2,671 45.1
1979 7,300 2,801 38.4 1,534 21.0 2,965 40.6
1980 8,282 3,407 41.1 2,036 24.6 2,839 34.3
1981 10,483 4,261 40.6 2,599 24.8 3,623 34.6
1982 12,885 5,936 46.1 3,506 27.2 3,443 26.7
1983 16,306 8,649 53.0 3,849 23.6 3,808 23.4
1984 18,596 11,291 60.7 3,166 17.0 4,139 22.3
1985 16,543 11,052t 66.8 4,159 25.1 1,332 8.1
*Gross national savings equal public sector savings plus private sector savings. Public sector savings are
the current surplus in the consolidated accounts of the public sector, which consists of government plus
seven major statutory boards, namely the Housing and Development Board, Jurong Town Corporation,
Public Utilities Board, Port of Singapore Authority, Telecommunication Authority of Singapore, Urban
Redevelopment Authority and Sentosa Development Corporation. Central Provident Fund savings are the
net addition that year to the accumulated fund due to members. Because of members’ withdrawals of funds,
this figure was normally less than members’ contributions. Other private sector savings are gross national
savings minus public sector and Central Provident Fund savings. Figures which divide other
private sector savings into corporate and personal savings are not available.
*The 1985 figure for public sector savings is provisional. Comparable figures for public sector savings are
not available after 1985, due to changes in the official statistics.
Sources: Singapore, Department of Statistics, Singapore National Accounrs 1987; Singapore,
Parliamentary Debates. Vol. 36, No. 10 (February 28, 1977), ~01s.607-608, Vol. 37, No. 7 (February 27.
1978). ~01s. 485-486, Vol. 38, No. 7 (March 5, 1979). cols. 417-418; Singapore, Ministry of Trade and
Industry, Economic Survey of Singapore 1979, p. 30, 1980, p. 36, 1981, p. 40, 1982, p, 45, 1983, p. 49,
1984, p. 43, 1985. p. 34, 1986, p. 38, 1987, p. 46; Singapore, Department of Statistics, Yearbook of
Statistics 1982/83. p. 194, 19X5/86,p. 216.

Development Board, Jurong Town Corporation, sumers and effectively to subsidise public housing
Public Utilities Board, Port of Singapore Authority, provided through the Housing and Development
Urban Redevelopment Authority, Telecommuni- Board. Implicit taxation of consumers effectively
cation Authority of Singapore and Sentosa mobilized savings, since the government avoided the
Development Corporation. Singapore, almost alone in “Please effect” of increasing its own consumption in
Asia, allowed bank deposit and lending rates to reach line with taxes (Please, 1967). During 1966-92, pub-
market-clearing levels. But the government relied lic consumption as a proportion of GDP changed
heavily on price manipulation (McKinnon, 1993, p. little; virtually the whole of the dramatic fall in
12), since it used the monopoly power of statutory private consumption’s GDP share during this period
boards to extract an “economic surplus” from con- could be channelled into savings (Table 9). The

Table 9. Singapore expenditure on gross domesnc product, 1960-92 (%)

1960 1966 1970 1979 1992


Private consumption expenditure 89.4 76.7 67.5 55.0 43.0
Government consumption expenditure 7.5 10.6 11.9 9.9 9.4
Gross capital formation 11.4 21.9 38.7 41.8 40.4
Net exports of goods and services -14.0 -8.2 -20.3 -7.1 7.2
Sources: Singapore, Department of Statistics, Econonlic and Socia/ Statistics, 1960-1982, pp. 56, 63;
Singapore, Ministry of Trade and Industry, Economic Survey of Singapore 1993 (Singapore, 1994), pp.
106. 112.
1428 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

government typically realized budget surpluses, fur- maximized. In line with this analysis, recent govem-
ther adding to public savings. As Singapore shows, ment policy statements emphasize the objective of
however, such surpluses need not imply low govem- growth maximization (Straits Times Weekly,
ment spending on development. November 12, 1994). Since the incremental capital-
A substantial proportion of the private sector’s con- output ratio (AWAY) is the reciprocal of the output-
tribution to Singapore’s high savings rate was due to capital ratio, an economic growth maximum would
savings forced by the government through the Central help to explain a capital-output ratio in Singapore
Provident Fund, a social security scheme. The Central which during 198%89 was, at 7.1, the highest in Asia
Provident Fund could increase the domestic savings after the Philippines (Amdt, 1993, p. 244).
rate because (unusually among developing countries) Government control of savings nevertheless
it operated on the provident fund principle: on retire- contributed in two ways to the high direct foreign in-
ment, individuals were paid benefits determined by vestment which was a feature of the Singapore
total past contributions from themselves and their development model. One was that large savings
employers plus interest, rather than payments being removed the balance-of-payments current account
made to retirees from the contributions of those deficit as a constraint on capital inflows and so pro-
still working. According to one study, the Central moted macroeconomic stability. The other, more
Provident Fund’s effect was to raise Singapore’s over- important, contribution of high savings and govern-
all savings rate by 3.8% during 1967-89 (Monetary ment control of them was that public sector savings
Authority of Singapore, 1991). and those of the Central Provident Fund provided a
The recollection that savings and investment are cheap, noninflationary way to finance infrastructural
distinct acts is crucial in understanding why in development, further facilitated by government
Singapore, although government so largely controlled dominance of the land market. Singapore’s superb
savings, investment came chiefly from the private sec- infrastructure - including port, airport, roads,
tor. Beginning in the 1960s the public sector never telecommunications and a mass rapid transit system
accounted for as much as two-fifths of gross fixed cap- -together with fiscal incentives such as tax holidays
ital formation, and during 1980-92 its share was a and accelerated depreciation allowances, ready-to-
little over a quarter. Long before the late 1980s. move-into factory sites and a range of development
when Singapore’s own savings could have entirely expenditure including training and education effec-
financed the economy’s high investment ratio, the tively acted as subsidies to MNE investment. Through
government had begun to invest much of public sav- helping to assure MNEs’ required rate of profitability
ings abroad in equities, bonds, real estate and short- and attracting their investment, domestic savings
term assets. In effect, Singapore exchanged an outflow which financed this subsidy also drew in the MNE
of national savings for an inflow of private foreign entrepreneurship, technology and guaranteed access
capital. to world markets central to the Singapore develop-
It can be argued that by the 1980s government- ment model.
forced abstinence pushed the savings ratio to a level
that Singapore was “oversaving,” meaning the un- (iv) State-owned enterprise
warranted sacrifice of current consumption by State-owned enterprise - in 1983 estimated to
Singaporeans (Young, 1992; Lim, 1988; Koh, 1987; include some 490 wholly or partially government-
see Straits Times Weekly, August 29, 1992 for a owned companies - had two main roles in the Singa-
defence of government policy). In 1992 the share of pore economy. First, in combination with monopoly
private consumption expenditure in Singapore’s GDP power, statutory boards with significant commercial
was 43%. The insurmountable problem, however, of operations could mobilize savings because, like
discovering and aggregating individual Singaporeans’ Singapore’s state-owned enterprise as a whole, and
utilities to arrive at a social utility function makes it indeed the government itself, they remained notable
impossible to know whether Singapore oversaved. for efficient and effective management (Lim, 1983;
A separate issue is overinvestment, because invest- Low, 1984, 1988). In this Singapore had the advantage
ment came largely from the private sector, not the gov- that public enterprise began afresh rather than through
ernment which forced Singapore’s high savings rate. the nationalization of already loss-making lirms. But
Overinvestment is suggested by the work of Young efficiency in Singapore was bolstered by long tradi-
(1992), who calculated that during the 1980s the aver- tion dating back to British colonial rule, and, probably
age before-subsidy real rate of return on capital in more important, as discussed below, a policy of high
Singapore had been pushed to one of the lowest in the pay for public sector employees.
world. Taking I = investment, Y = income, and K = The other principal role of state-owned enterprise.
capital, Young’s finding would be consistent with a emphasized by L. Lim (1983), was to till strategic
Singapore policy to step up the investment ratio (I/Y) gaps in the economy. If a sector was not attractive to
to a point at which the incremental output-capital ratio international investment, or (like communications)
(AY/AK) equalled zero and economic growth was too much of a public good and/or too strategic to turn
SINGAPORE’S ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT I429

to foreign enterprise, the government did not hesitate and because Fund beneficiaries were permitted to
to step in. Accordingly, the Singapore government withdraw savings to spend on housing. Together with
began as nonstatutory undertakings a range of enter- a massive public housing program, this last meant that
prises, including Singapore Airlines, Neptune Orient by 1990, 88% of households owned the houses they
Line (an international shipping line) and International occupied, compared to less than one-third in 1970.
Trading Company (Intraco). Beginning in 1985, how- The rapid gains in real wages (Table 5) and home
ever, the onset of privatization and, more important, ownership for Singaporeans induced acceptance of
the continued rapid growth of private enterprise prob- government wage control and thereby completed a
ably reduced the contribution of state-owned enter- “virtuous circle” of macroeconomic policy: low infla-
prises to GDP. It is now perhaps no more than about tion with consequent real exchange rate competitive-
lo%, although the government retains a majority ness helped to ensure the continued foreign capital
holding in profitable and key undertakings like inflows with embodied MNE technology which made
Singapore Airlines and Singapore Telecom. real wage gains possible.

(v) Macroeconomic stability (vi) Infernationaljnancial services developrnenr


Macroeconomic stability, often stressed as basic to Singapore’s geographical location and pre- 1960
rapid growth in East Asia (World Bank, 1993), was growth as a center for financial activities were strong
secured in Singapore by government intervention in advantages in the Republic’s subsequent development
the economy. Indicative of this stability was as an international financial center. But financial
Singapore’s exceptionally low inflation (Table l), to development “has not been accidental.” It followed
which government control over wages was fundamen- “development strategy mapped out in the late 1960s”
tal. Macroeconomic management was unconven- (Fry, 1988, p. 354). Government contributed to tinan-
tional: a government’s ability to secure international cial services development in three main ways. One
competitiveness through limiting wage rises to pro- was the provision of public goods -the maintenance
ductivity gains is not typically among the range of of honest markets, an environment conducive to easy
policy instruments available. But in Singapore, the operation and the stability of the Singapore dollar.
substitution of institutional arrangements centered on This achievement of the PAP government should not
the National Wages Council for a conventional be underestimated, since such public goods were
macro-policy instrument - the exchange rate - dissipated in many parts of Asia.
freed the latter to become an instrument targeted The second aspect of the government’s contribu-
specifically on inflation. Because in an enrrepot econ- tion was more specific and had the direct effect of aug-
omy like Singapore’s import and export prices rose menting Singapore’s natural comparative advantage
about equally, domestic inflation was kept low by (i.e. when a free competitive market prevails) in pro-
allowing the nominal exchange rate to appreciate in viding financial services. The government “targeted”
line with foreign inflation (Corden, 1984; Lim, 1988). the development of specific activities which typically
Although exchange rate appreciation as an anti-infla- were then strongly encouraged with tax or other fiscal
tion device has proved effective in Latin America in incentives. In 1968, the Singapore government, in
the medium term, it has typically been undermined by consultation with international banks, immediately
government inability - unlike in Singapore - to reacted to the possibility of establishing an Asian
control domestic wage settlements, with consequent Dollar Market. It abolished a withholding tax of 45%
upward pressure on prices which wrecked interna- on interest paid to nonresidents, quickly followed by a
tional competitiveness. variety of other fiscal measures targeted at establish-
Government-forced savings in Singapore helped to ing the market (Hodjera, 1978). Government response
dampen inflation by draining purchasing power from to the opportunity available to Singapore paid divi-
the private sector and neutralizing the expansionary dends. As a result of government policy, it has been
effect of large inflows of foreign capital. Moreover, argued, Singapore “stole the march on Hong Kong,”
government borrowing from the Central Provident where the authorities lacked a similar development
Fund (the largest holder of government securities) commitment (Jao, 1985, p. 44. 1979). Strategic advan-
provided a ready source of finance, characteristically tage, once gained for Singapore, was not lost. and sub-
at below-market interest rates. Because in relying on sequently Hong Kong found it impossible to challenge
the Central Provident Fund the government borrowed the Republic as an Asian Dollar Market. After rcach-
already-existing private-sector savings, it could avoid ing US$54.4 billion in 19X0, Singapore’s Asian Dollar
inflationary financing of developmental expenditure Market grew to US$355.4 billion in 1992. annual
through money creation. At the same time, public average growth of 16.9% (Monetary Authority 01
willingness to comply with the Central Provident Singapore, 1993). Development of an Asian Dollar
Fund was strengthened by positive real interest rates, Bond Market - which the Singapore govcrnmcnt
the expectation of low inflation, tax concessions for itself took the lcad in starting by iloatinp US rlollar-
savers with sufficiently high income to be tax payers, denominated bonds - led to signiticant rnarkct
1430 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

specialization and complementarily in Singapore’s 3. ACHIEVEMENT OF A DEVELOPMENTAL


offshore banking system. STATE IN SINGAPORE
Throughout the 197Os, in line with planning strat-
egy to establish Singapore as a financial center (Hon, The emergence of a developmental state associated
1972) the government moved aggressively to attract with the Singapore model rested on five interrelated
international financial institutions and broaden the factors - government autonomy from interest
range of financial services available. Demonstrable groups; stability, perpetuated by a favorable sequenc-
success, indicated by the “engine of growth” role ing of events; material gains for the bulk of the popu-
which financial and business services had assumed by lation which promoted government control without
1980, led to a redoubling of government effort in the harsh repression; the ability of individuals in charge of
1980s to promote this sector. The establishment of the government; and a state which treated the market
Singapore as a “financial supermarket” (Singapore, with respect and established a creative relationship
Ministry of Trade and Industry, 1981, pp. 10-l 1) was with it. The interplay of these five considerations
central to the Economic Development Plan for the explains the success of government interventionism in
Eighties; during that decade, every budget statement Singapore. Two intertwined questions run throughout
contained fiscal incentives aimed at financial innova- the discussion of these factors. First, what prevents the
tion. Government initiative was instrumental in estab- government from acting in ways which inhibit devel-
lishing a new futures and options market, organized opment? Second, what pushes the state to follow poli-
through the Singapore International Monetary cies which actually promote development?
Exchange (SIMEX). As the government planned,
merchant banking has taken off, and Singapore is
increasingly a center for fund management. (a) Development commitment and exclusion of
The third aspect of the government’s contribution interest groups
to the development of financial services arose because
it had a leading role in promoting the accumulation of The first of the five factors -the autonomy of gov-
physical and human capital on which the augmenta- ernment - allows an all-out systematic commitment
tion of comparative advantage in financial services to economic development, which is a different, alto-
heavily depends. Singapore’s telecommunications gether rarer, thing than the proclaimed allegiance to
system is a good example of physical capital provi- the goal of development usual in LDCs during the
sion. In the early 197Os, the rapid expansion of the 1950s and 1960s. Government identification with, and
Asian Dollar Market created serious difficulties for capture by, particular interest groups - a lack of
banks in obtaining a London line through the autonomy - was typically the rock on which a deter-
Singapore telephone exchange. The temporary solu- mined, sustained drive to development foundered
tion of the government was to set aside for calls to (Bardhan, 1990). Singapore had such interest groups
London several operators with a secret number given in a local entrepreneurial class described in 1958 as
only to banks (Bryant, 1985). Subsequent government “both extensive in numbers and high in quality” (Goh,
investment in telecommunications obviated the prob- 1958, p. 1), which derived from its Chinese-educated,
lem, and by 1988 international calls made from China-oriented majority as well as a similarly oriented
Singapore numbered one-third as many as made from trade union movement. The size of Singapore’s
the whole of Japan (GATT, 1990). China-oriented majority can be gauged by the fact that
Singapore planners also showed flexibility in in 1957 over twice as many of the island’s Chinese
responding to the changing educational needs arising were literate in Chinese as in English (Singapore,
from development as an international financial center 1973, p. 103).
as well as from efforts to promote higher quality, The political achievement of Lee Kuan Yew’s PAP
higher value-added manufacturing. In 1967 the gov- in the 1959 colonial government-sponsored elections
ernment had determined that “We will cease making and afterward was simultaneously to stand on a
the mistakes which nearly all developing countries are strongly development-oriented economic platform
now making - over-producing unemployable num- (People’s Action Party, 1959) and to gain the backing
bers of educated white collar workers and not turning of the majority of the Chinese population. Chinese still
out the skilled artisans and technicians we need for often say that Lee won the support of the rickshaw
industrial growth” (Singapore, Ministry of Labour, pullers. But in 1961, Lee, in control of the levers of
1969, front cover, quoting Goh Keng Swee). But the state power, split with the leftist wing of the PAP and
government underwrote a strong expansion of tertiary subsequently neutralized his political opponents with
education as the need for this grew: enrollment in a carefully judged combination of repression and
higher education expanded at 3.7% per annum during achievement-oriented policies, which gained endorse-
1967-79, but at over twice that rate during the 1980s ment, if not a mass popular following.
(Singapore, Department of Statistics, Yearbook, 1976, The Lee Kuan Yew government saw its political
1985/86, 1991). future not as “a communist outpost of Peking” (Mills,
SINGAPORE’S ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 1431

1964, p. 268) but as an agent of rapid economic devel- from the decision-making process. Businessmen
opment. The English-educated, Chinese leadership, could not decide policy, “nor can they exert pressure
headed by Lee, feared the local Chinese business class on the government” (Lee, S. Y., 1978, p. 50). Neither
which backed China and Chinese-language rights, and was backing derived from the Chinese trade union
once in power was determined not to be beholden to movement which had flourished in Singapore. Rather,
it. Among the leaders of the Chinese business com- new unions and the National Trades Union Congress,
munity who strongly supported China and Chinese- which did not have roots in the older Chinese radical-
language education, Tan Kah Kee had been the ism, were created as part of the PAP’s overall eco-
foremost pre-WWII figure. After the war, he was “the nomic strategy.
real Chinese leader with a mass following” (Lee, In Singapore, the process through which the gov-
1988, p. 25), but in 1950 was forced by the British ernment achieved autonomy from interest groups also
colonial authorities to remain in China, where he pushed it to seek economic growth to legitimize itself
became an official of the Chinese Communist Party. and retain power. A fundamental check against the
Following Tan’s exile to China, his successor was Tan danger of government failure was the PAP’s need for
Lark Sye. rapid economic development to protect the party’s
In 1956 Tan Lark Sye was instrumental in the own interest in gaining reelection. Singapore’s 1965
establishment of the Chinese-language Nanyang split with Malaysia, creating what has been described
University as a bastion of Chinese culture, with the as “a state of siege” (Lim, Pang and Findlay, 1993, p.
support of a wide section of the Chinese business com- 104), gave further impetus to the PAP’s already strong
munity and Chinatown. In 1963, in the first business desire to achieve rapid economic growth as a condi-
session of the new Singapore Legislative Assembly, tion for political perpetuation. Perhaps more impor-
Lee Kuan Yew addressed head-on the threat of tant, however, the separation from Malaysia allowed
Nanyang University, and drew attention to its wider Singapore’s government to take firmer control of the
implications: economy, especially the labor movement, and pushed
government policy toward heavy reliance on MNEs to
The Nanyang University Council has hitherto spumed achieve quick results. The fact that most directly pro-
every Government grant to help it raise its standards and ductive activity in the economy was left to MNEs
put its organisation into shape, largely because the furnished an additional check against government fail-
Communists have been able to manipulate some leaders ure. In Singapore, a high degree of trust and close rela-
of the Chinese merchant community who have preten- tionship between government and the private sector,
sions to greatness, and perhaps to inherit the mantle of
often stressed as important to the developmental state
another Chinese patriot like the late Mr. Tan Kah Kee.. .a
situation is developing which, if left unchecked within (Rueschemeyer and Putterman, 1992), was basic to
five years, will make it more a University of Yenan than attracting multinationals.
of Nanyang with young pro-Communist graduates and
student leaders manipulating the entire governing
Council of Nanyang University (Singapore Legislative (b) Sequencing, stab&y and economic progress
Assembly, December 1963).
The second and third factors - a sequencing to
Tan Lark Sye had as trenchant views, expressed in product stability and material gains - which explain
his well-known observation that English education Singapore’s developmental state can be considered
resulted in “increasing taxes, laying traps, turning out together. In 1959, independent Singapore inherited,
fools and wasting public funds.” He warned that “If not just a successful economy, but, as Lee Kuan Yew
we do not take steps to preserve our culture now.. .in emphasized, “an administration that worked’ (1967,
40 or 50 years perhaps we shall no longer call our- p. 2). Singapore suffered “no xenophobic hangover
selves Chinese” (Far Eastern Economic Review,, from colonialism” (Lee, K. Y., 1978, p. 13). In a first
1980, p. 161). His views did not prevail: at the begin- phase, this acceptance of the past prevented any break
ning of the 198Os, Nanyang University was finally in government. This was also true of Hong Kong and,
subsumed under government direction into the like it, Singapore’s inheritance was solidly free trade.
English-language Singapore National University, The Singapore government assumed a leading role
Adaptation, frequently suggested in the mid-1960s. in the second phase of sequencing from independence
of a Hong Kong development model reliant on small until the early 197Os, a period in which the basis for
Chinese manufacturing enterprise and so local entre- development-oriented institutions was laid. In 1959,
preneurs appears never to have been seriously consid- the Economic Development Board was set up as “the
ered by the PAP (Singapore Legislative Assembly, spearhead for industrialization by direct participation
Debates, 1964; Singapore Parliamentary Debates, in industry” and building necessary infrastructure
1965). Its decision to rely for economic development (Singapore, Economic Planning Unit, 1964, p. 37).
on MNEs and state-owned enterprises allowed After 1966, the Economic Development Board and its
Singapore’s local business elite largely to be excluded offshoots - the Development Bank of Singapore and
1432 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Jurong Town Corporation - could be harnessed to ciary: “It is absolutely futile for people to talk about
export-oriented industrialization. The Monetary challenging executive decisions in court. If it is not
Authority of Singapore, established in 1971 as a quasi- legal, the government will make it legal, and it will
central bank, became a strong and responsive institu- make it legal retrospectively” (Srruits Times Weekly,
tion which, together with the Development Bank of 1991). At the end of 1994 the government went a step
Singapore, the government could use in its strategy to further in apparently trying to rule out significant
turn Singapore into the “Zurich of the East.” political critique by Singaporeans unless they were
In a third and final phase, as the government willing to risk standing openly against the PAP when
extended and consolidated its control - notably over Prime Minister Goh Chok Tong declared that anyone
the trade unions - management of the mass media who “wanted to comment regularly on politics and set
was a key part of the overall effort. A leading the political agenda should become politicians them-
Singapore economist emphasized how this was seen selves” (Straits Times Weekly, December 24, 1994).
as contributing to economic development: “The mass
media can be made to play a crucial role in an all-out
and all-round development effort.. .The deliberate (c) Caliber of lendership
omission of such a use by a government in a poor
country is unforgivable irresponsibility, whatever is The caliber and economic competence of
the view in some unrealistic circles in already affluent Singapore’s post-1959 political leadership cannot be
societies about press freedom” (Lim, 1983, p. 96; and doubted. An elite very much in the British, rather than
see New York Times, 1993). S. Rajaratnam, a former the populist US, tradition, the same, small group of
Foreign Minister, elaborated the last point: “How leaders dominated politics between independence in
many Singaporeans really want free speech anyway? 19.59 and Lee Kuan Yew’s 1990 retirement. The
They want orderliness, a decent living” (Buruma, observation of Silcock (1985, p. 293), among the most
1989, p. 143). Both of these were achieved. acute academic critics of Asian development, is
Corruption, endemic in many LDCs, was absent in telling:
Singapore. The Republic was -and remained in 1994
- among the few Asian exceptions to Myrdal’s “soft The number of those who made the difference and
state” characterized by a lack of social discipline, enabled Singapore to make so much of a not very obvi-
unwillingness of the people to accept obligations and ous opportunity was probably not above fifty. They have
weak (or no) enforcement of policies by the govern- meant far more to Singapore than any spreading of eco-
ment (Myrdal, 1968, pp. 891-900). nomic doctrine among the population in general or even
The Singapore government acted systematically to among the educated parts of the population.
break up potential political or special interests based
on racial or ethnic (Chinese dialect) groups. This pol- In Singapore, distinguishing features of its post-
icy could be applied virtually universally through an 1959 political and economic leaders were their per-
educational approach which made English the first sonal integrity, a high level of formal education and,
language in all schools, and through the government’s often, extensive training in economics. Although this
rehousing program, which allowed the PAP to manip- last did not extend to Lee Kuan Yew, his approach to
ulate electoral constituencies and disperse political economics was “that of a person recognising that he
opposition (Economist, 1979; Lim, Pang and Findlay, has some training in the subject [who] uses it to
1993, p. 125). Government upgrading of public hous- appraise the judgement of fully professional econo-
ing estates, including privately owned dwellings, mists and use their advice to check some of his own
involved a considerable subsidy; in 1992 the PAP ideas” (Silcock, 1985, p. 315). But there is a crucial
announced its intention to upgrade first in constituen- distinction, drawn by C. Johnson (1982, p. 25),
cies which voted most heavily for the party (Straits between an “economic bureaucracy” and a “bureau-
Times Weekly, 1992). cracy of economists.” Economic success, while
By a somewhat different route to Singapore’s, almost certainly uncorrelated with the number of eco-
South Korea and Taiwan experienced sequencing nomics graduates in a government bureaucracy (Hong
which yielded a similar combination of stabilization, Kong employs just 12 professional economists), does
followed by institutional development and growing require, as in Singapore, a political leadership and
government control accompanied by rising living associated economic bureaucracy willing and able to
standards with consequent incentives to political sta- think like economists to evaluate choices in hard eco-
bility (Sachs, 1987; Mason eral., 1980). Palpable eco- nomic terms.
nomic progress contributed to the PAP’s acceptance Comparison with other countries confirms the rele-
by voters and Singapore’s one-party elected parlia- vance of the premium placed on economic judgement
ment. But the government took no chances and toler- by the PAP. Stories of groups as small as those in
ated no more than mild criticism. A law lecturer at the Singapore, described as a “handful of heroes,” have
National University observed of the Singapore judi- been interestingly told for Latin America by
SINGAPORE’S ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 1432

Harberger (1993). Similarly, a few technocrats placed tally responsible for the disenchantment with plan-
their stamp on Taiwan’s post-WWII development: ning in less developed countries (Wellisz, 1971).
At the beginning of the 1960s although the
This remarkable group of people.. .provided consistent Singapore government already had little confidence in
and generally sound economic policy guidance, and formal planning documents (Goh Keng Swee, quoted
made a major contribution to Taiwan’s economic devel- in Sharp, 1975), a general belief in planning to formu-
opment. Chiang [Kai-shek] also brought in as consultants late a set of coordinated government policies, mobi-
a number of Chinese-American academic econo-
lize savings and provide public goods was evident.
mists.. .listened to what they had to say, and often acted
Planning preferences and a coherent development
on their advice (Galenson, 1992, p. 17).
strategy, essential to any shade of planning
(Chakravarty, 1991). emerged from the later 1960s as
Just as Chiang and other military and Kuomintang
the political leadership/planners increasingly per-
officials in Taiwan recognized “that economic matters
ceived the strength of the world economy’s new flows
required skilled specialists” (Vogel, 1991, p. 24) in
of trade and foreign investment. As part of the same
South Korea an economically-aware and technically
process, Singapore’s leaders found control over strate-
trained elite was pivotal (Whang, 1992). By contrast,
gic domestic markets and institutions the most effec-
almost everywhere else in post-colonial Asia, leaders
tive way to respond to these opportunities in the world
“seldom had technical or specialized training of any
economy in order to meet the main planning objec-
sort. They were generalists, skilled primarily in the art
tives of creating jobs, absorbing surplus labor and
of politics. .the new leaders rarely sought counsel
rapid economic growth (Goh, 1989). Planning in
from.. .trained economists, scientists, and techni-
Singapore never involved detailed blueprints, because
cians” (Scalapino, 1989, p. 45). For example, in of the priority accorded to reaction to the international
Indonesia, Sukarno’s “immense oratorical talent and market, impossibility of predicting its course and need
his great charisma...were not complemented by the for flexibility to ensure a quick and competitive
ability to recognise and use good economic advice” response. There was no ideological commitment to
(Glassburner, 1991, p. 51). The acceptance of “high free enterprise as such: ‘“The government has to be the
quality economic policy advice” now said to be a fea- planner and the mobilizer of the economic effort” but
ture of Indonesian development did not become char- “the free enterprise system, correctly nurtured and
acteristic until the post-1966 New Order (Hill, 1994a, adroitly handled, can serve as a powerful and versatile
p. 172, 1994b). Economic realism among Singapore’s instrument of economic growth” (Gob, 1972). State-
leadership from the start opened the way to successful owned enterprise provided a significant outlet, espe-
economic planning. cially in the absence of trade protection, for this
government role in gathering and directing a national
economic effort.
(d) Planning for development Singapore planners, helped by intelligence from
Economic Development Board overseas offices,
As Singapore’s recent Strategic Economic Plan closely monitored the world market, and initiatives
observed, “Economic planning has played a very sig- were undertaken to attract desirable industries. For
nificant role in the development of Singapore for more example, the potential of electronics was spotted on a
than thirty years” (Singapore, Economic Planning 1966 ministerial visit to Taiwan (Wee, 1966; Goh,
Committee, 199 1, p. 14)?. The fundamental difference 1992). The Economic Development Board targeted
between a planned and a market economy is the manufacturing activities, in that the Board looked for
replacement of the price system with a combination of industries beneficial to Singapore - on criteria like
positive commands and negative controls. In effecting value added, skill content and capital intensity -
this substitution, interventionism in Singapore which were likely to be attracted to the Republic,
extended to a degree of planning which went well enquired as to the necessary incentives including tax
beyond the World Bank’s (1993, pp. 82-86) “market- concessions and then provided them (Singapore,
friendly” prescription for the role of the state in eco- Economic Development Board, 1993. pp. 26-27).
nomic development. But in manufacturing, the aims remained general;
But planning in Singapore was directed only at the Singapore planners’ approach to the international
domestic economy, and unambiguously aimed to economy contrasted with the targeted protectionism
respond to the international economy to take advan- and idea of “picking winners” practiced in Japan.
tage of developments in it. In the sense of adapting the South Korea and Taiwan, and perhaps possible for a
local economy to the international one, government large developing country. Rather, in keepmg with a
interventionism in Singapore was selective and plan- tiny domestic economy. Singapore adhered to free
ning “market-oriented.” The effect was to sidestep, at trade and tried to be attractive to a range of activities
least in the medium term, difficulties arising from a through supply-oriented policies, an approach later
crippling of the domestic market mechanism - typi- likened to backing all the horses in a race (Gob. 1992:
1434 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Singapore, Economic Planning Committee, 1991, national economy appeared. Many LDCs have
p* 68). economies less developed than Singapore’s was in
Planning depends crucially on enforcement, 1959, a weaker human capital base and shakier insti-
reflected in Jawaharal Nehru’s remark that India was tutional structure, all of which make successful inter-
“not quite so expert at implementation as at planning” ventionism more difficult. It is also true that a small,
(quoted in Waterston, 1970, p. 403). In Singapore, island state such as Singapore is relatively easily and
interventionism was organized around government cheaply controlled, or, put somewhat differently, that
directives and so had considerably more force than in Singapore the low transaction costs of government
indicative planning. Singapore planning featured the interventionism facilitated a particular set of institu-
concentration of decision making in a few hands, also tional arrangements.
observed elsewhere in East Asia (Jones and SaKong, Even where geography provided a similar set of
1980; Wade, 1990). Typically, the same men, for conditions to Singapore’s, history often did not.
example Goh Keng Swee, Hon Sui Sen and Joseph Griffith (1987) argues convincingly that historical
Pillay, served as directors for a host of state-owned forces productive of a strong trade union movement
enterprises and PAP government development initia- and special interest groups in the CARICOM coun-
tives, which economized on entrepreneurial talent tries prevent replication of the Singapore model. In
(Singapore Trade and Industry, January 1969 and other settings, the power of special interest groups -
April 1969; Lee, 1984; Bryant, 1985, p. 13). often capital rather than labor -is familiar. Such rela-
Moreover, the policy helped to ensure loyalty to the tionships never arose under Singapore’s PAP govem-
government and to further its tight control. The PAP ment. It remained independent of interest groups.
leadership achieved effective implementation of plans Five general lessons and a major caveat may be
and policies through the lower levels of bureaucracy adduced from the experience of government interven-
by a willingness to pay government officials salaries tionism in Singapore. The caveat is that probably few
comparable to or above the private sector and by an countries would be so willing as Singapore to tolerate
emphasis on individual accountability (Chew, 1988, such a high foreign presence. In Singapore, however,
pp. 222-223; Straits Times Weekly, December 4, development through multinationals as a substitute for
1993, October 22, 1994, October 29, 1994, November local entrepreneurship required of the Republic no
5, 1994). Plan review procedures are now being used more than what historically it had always done - to
as a means of publicity to mobilize support for gov- respond to changes in the international economy and
ernment economic strategy (Singapore, SEP Working the resulting requirements of foreigners. Moreover,
Group, 1993). Singapore’s development as an international services
and financial center - an opportunity which by its
nature is available to few LDCs - made it easier to
4. CONCLUSIONS accept a high foreign presence in manufacturing, since
services are more heavily dependent on local and
After the split with Malaysia, Singapore lacked a regional knowledge and create a greater role for
development model to emulate, except perhaps Hong indigenous Singaporeans.
Kong’s, In fact, both the Singapore model of develop- One lesson of interventionism in Singapore is that
ment and the evolution of government interventionism the precise form of government does not appear to be
basic to it involved a searching, probing and learning crucial. Research has failed to establish any clear link
which is at the heart of the economic development between economic development and either authori-
process (Bruton, 1985). When asked whether after tarianism or democracy (Przeworksi and Limongi,
1965 Singapore’s leadership had “a model in mind,” 1993). Insofar as conclusions can be drawn,
Lee Kuan Yew replied, “No, we borrowed in an eclec- Singapore’s experience suggests that, if anything,
tic fashion elements of what Hong Kong was doing, regimes shaded toward authoritarianism may have
what Switzerland was doing, what Israel was doing, advantages in the earlier stages of the development
and we improvised. I also went down to Malta to see process: investment and capital formation are central
how they ran the dry docks.” (Lee, 1990/91, p. 24). to economic growth and the voluntary mobilization of
Just as Singapore had to find its own economic and savings, difficult in wealthy countries, is harder still in
political development model, so the experience of poor ones. Key features in Singapore were the broad
government interventionism evolved in the Republic acceptance of government policies by the mass of the
is unlikely to be applicable in any wholesale way to population, continuity of policy with consequent
other developing countries. Part of the reason for this enhancement of credibility which furthered macro-
is that in 1959 Singapore already had a substantial economic stability, a relative freedom from corruption
“transformation capacity”- the economy’s ability to and, of course, the ability to implement policies con-
reallocate resources. That capacity gave the leaders of ducive to growth.
independent Singapore more degrees of freedom in Singapore therefore does not fit easily either the
engineering change when opportunities in the inter- bureaucratic-authoritarian model of Latin American
SINGAPORE’S ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 1435

regimes or the Japanese consensus model. In the for- Fourth, a high human capital base and a trained,
mer, a ruling elite seeks to promote industrialization disciplined bureaucracy, as the example of Singapore
by excluding previously mobilized economic groups indicates, are essential to the success of inter-
from power and by building a collaborative relation- ventionism. Such a bureaucracy cannot be recruited
ship with MNEs, while in Japan, democracy prevailed unless government pay is competitive with the private
after WWII and for almost 40 years the ruling Liberal sector, the requirement recognized in Singapore. At
Democratic Party forged a coalition of voters com- the highest level, the striking feature of Singapore’s
mitted to economic growth (Johnson, 1982, 1987). development, amply confirmed by experience else-
Although Singapore had elements of both models, where in Asia and Latin America, is the funda-
what happened there was less polarized than either mental importance of a tiny elite in formulating
model suggests. After forming a Japanese-style con- and guiding policy.
sensus in the 1959 elections, and subsequently putting Fifth, interventionist government - like the man
heavy reliance on MNE-led development, the spelling banana - must know where to stop. As a
Singapore model showed how the government, rule, less government intervention than in the
despite elements of authoritarianism, could secure Singapore of the late 1960s and 1970s is probably
broad and ongoing consent through the effective desirable both in countries less developed than
delivery of economic growth. Singapore was at that time and in those more devel-
Second, the autonomy of government - freedom oped. In the former, government interventionism may
from special interest groups - is essential. pose a problem because of the lack of administrative
Nevertheless, government and a political party syn- capacity and competence. In the latter, the increasing
onymous with it may increasingly coalesce into a
complexity of the economy makes interventionism
dominant interest group. Such a tendency has been
more problematic and adds to the danger of suppress-
observed in Singapore (Lim, 1983; Lim, Pang and
ing market signals for too long. In both types of
Findlay, 1993) although the very process of rapid
economy, it becomes less likely that planners’
economic development may offer some check to it. In
guesses will end up as superior to those of the
Singapore, development created pressures for the pri-
market. In Singapore, difficulties arising from
vatization now underway, and simultaneously private
long-term interference with the market are sug-
sector rewards too high to attract many of the most
gested by recent criticisms that the government may
talented individuals to a lifetime career in politics
have enforced “oversaving” in the sense of setting
(Sirairs Tinres Weekly, December 18, 1993a; Yeo,
1993). “Evangelical fervor” also abates, not merely a savings rate higher than necessary or sensible.
with time, but in the face of an increasingly attainable, Similarly, government control of wages suppresses
comfortable lifestyle. It is perhaps telling that after a market signals which should guide a reallocation
recent PAP rally, party stalwarts and one government of labor from low to higher productivity acti-
minister were seen carrying their traditional all-white vities and promote needed technological change
PAP “uniforms” on hangers to their automobiles, hav- in the Singapore economy (Disney and Ho,
ing changed into stylish (and expensive) clothes for 1990; Young, 1994).
Sunday lunch in central Singapore (Srruirs Times Perhaps the most important reason why govem-
Weekly, December 18, 1993b). ment interventionism succeeded in Singapore was
Third, government autonomy itself creates incen- because of a pragmatism - the test of what works -
tives which push the government to act “developmen- rather than rigid ideological commitment to a free
tally.” Often the incentives appear to be related to the market or to state direction. There was a clear under-
fact that the government has become the dominant standing of the limitations of smallness and extreme
interest group and requires economic development to openness for an economy such as Singapore’s in
legitimize and perpetuate itself. A further key incen- departing from free trade to “govern the market”
tive to development is survival in the face of some per- (Wade, 1990). In this regard, Singapore’s brand of
ceived external threat, as with South Korea and interventionism, not South Korea’s, may be the more
Taiwan, or following a political trauma, as after the reliable model for less-developed countries aiming to
split between Malaysia and Singapore. become late industrializers.

NOTES

I. Wages are a good indicator of value added. In 1990, 2. The main published planning documents in Singapore
72% of those in electronics production were female, com- were Singapore, Ministry of Finance, 1961; United Nations,
pared to 43% in the rest of manufacturing; wages in the I96 1; Singapore Economic Planning Unit, 1964; Hon. 1972:
electronics industry were below the manufacturing average, Singapore, Ministry of Trade and Industry, 198 1; Singapore,
itself less than wages in most other industrial groupings Ministry of Trade and Industry, 1986; Singapore, Economic
(Singapore, Department of Statistics or Economic Planning Committee, 1991; Singapore, National Science and
Development Board, 1990; Singapore, Ministry of Labour, Technology Board, 1991; Singapore, SEP Working Group,
1993). 1993.
1436 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

REFERENCES
Amdt, H., “Saving, investment and growth; recent Asian Economics,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 29, No.
experience,” in H. Amdt, 50 Years of Development Studies 4 (1991), pp. 1728-1737.
(Canberta: Australian National University, 1993). pp. Fry, M. J., Money, Interest, and Banking in Economic
241-250. Development (Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University
Bardhan, P., “Economics of development and the develop- Press, 1988).
ment of economics,” Journal ofEconomicPerspectives, Galenson, W., Labor and Economic Growth in Five Asian
Vol. 7, No. 2 (1993), pp. 129-142. Countries (New York: Praeger, 1992).
Bardhan, P., “Symposium on the state and economic devel- GATT, International Trade Statistics I993 (Geneva: GATT,
opment,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 4, No. 3 1993).
(1990). pp. 3-7. GATT, Infernational Trade 1989-1990, Vol. II (Geneva:
Benham, F., The National Income of Singapore 1956 GATT, 1990).
(London: Royal Institute of International Affairs, 1959). Giordano, R. and S. Kato, “Singapore: the most successful
Bhagwati, J., “Outward orientation: Trade issues,” in V. ‘Asian dragon ‘,” in Goldman Sachs, The International
Corbo, M. Goldstein and M. Khan (Eds), Growth-oriented Economics Analyst, Vol. 8, No. 2 (1993). pp. S.Ol-S.12.
Adjustment Programmes (Washington, DC: International Glassbumer, B., “An Indonesian memoir,” Bulletin of
Monetary Fund, 1987). pp. 257-290. Indonesian Economic Srudies, Vol. 27, No. 1 (1991), pp.
Bruton, H. J., “The search for development economics,” 45-60.
World Development, Vol. 13, No. lO/ll (1985) pp. Goh Keng Swee, “MNCs brought jobs and sparked change,”
1099-l 124. Straifs Times Weekly (August 29, 1992).
Bryant, R. C., Financial Structure and International Banking Goh Keng Swee, Interview with author (August 17, 1989).
in Singapore, Brookings discussion paper in international Goh Keng Swee, The Asian (August 20, 1972).
economics No. 29 (Washington, DC: Brookings Goh Keng Swee, Decade of Achievement, Budget speech,
Institution, 1985). 1970 (Singapore: Ministry of Culture, 1970).
BuNma, I., God’s Dust: A Modern Asian Journey (London: Goh Keng Swee, “Entrepreneurship in a plural economy,”
Jonathan Cape, 1989). Malavan Economic Review, Vol. 3, No. 1 (1958). DD. l-7.
Chang, Y. S., The Transfer of Technology: Economics of Griffith; W. H., “Can CARICOM countries replicate the
Offshore Assembly - the Semiconductor Industry (New Singapore experience?,” Journal of Development Studies,
York: UNITAR, 1971). Vol. 24, No. 1 (1987), pp. 60-82.
Chakravarty, S., Development planning: A reappraisal,” Harberger, A. C., “Secrets of success: A handful of heroes,”
Cambridge Journal ofEconomics, Vol. 15, No. 1 (1991). American Economic Review, Vol. 83, No. 2 (1993) pp.
pp. 5-20. 343-350.
Chew, S. B., Small Firms in Singapore (Singapore: Oxford Helleiner, G. K., “Manufactured exports from less developed
University Press, 1988). countries and multinational firms,” Economic Journal,
Chow, S. C. and G. F. Papanek, “Laissez-faire, growth and Vol. 83 (1973), pp. 2147.
equity - Hong Kong,” Economic Journal, Vol. 91 Hill, H., “Review of Little et al.,” Bulletin of Indonesian
(1981). pp. 466-485. Economic Studies, Vol. 30, No. 2 (1994a), pp. 171-174.
Collins, S. M., “Comment on Dombusch and Park, ‘Korean Hill H .>“The economy,” in H. Hill (Ed.), Indonesia’s New
growth policy’,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity drder (St. Leonards, NSW: Allen & Unwin, 1994b), pp.
No. 2 (1987), pp. 389-454. 54-122.
Corden, W. M., “Macroeconomic targets and instruments for Hodjera, Z., “The Asian currency market: Singapore as a
a small open economy,” Singapore Economic Review, regional financial center,” IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 25, No.
Vol. 29, No. 2 (1984). pp. 27-37. 2 (1978). pp. 221-253.
Disney, R. and S. K. Ho, “Do real wages matter in an open Hon. S. S., Economic Pattern in the Seventies, Budget
economy? The case of Singapore 1966-1987,” Oxford speech, 1972 (Singapore: Ministry of Culture, 1972).
Economic Papers, Vol. 42 (1990). pp. 635-657. International Monetary Fund, Balance of Paymenfs Stafistics
Economist, “Housing for all” (Singapore survey) (December Yearbook (Washington, DC: IMF, various years).
29, 1979). International Monetary Fund International Financial
Far Eastern Economic Review, “Focus: Singapore ‘80” Statistics Yearbook (Washington, DC: IMF, various
(August 1, 1980). years).
Fields, G. S. and H. Wan, “Wage-setting institutions and eco- Jao, Y. C., “Hong Kong’s future as a financial centre,” Three
nomic growth,” World Development, Vol. 17, No. 9 Banks Review, No. 145 (1985). pp. 35-53.
(1989). pp. 1471-1483. Jao, Y. C., “The rise of Hong Kong as a financial centre,”
Financial Times (London), “Open door creates wealth’ Asian Survey, Vol. 19, No. 7 (1979), pp. 674694.
(Singapore survey) (April 18, 1994). Johnson, C., “Political institutions and economic perfor-
Financial Times (London), “Success in investment” mance: the government-business relationship in Japan,
(Singapore survey) (November 22, 1978). South Korea and Taiwan,” in F. C. Dcyo, The Political
Findlay, R., “Comment on Haberler,” in G. M. Meier (Ed.), Economy of the New Asian Industrialism (Ithaca, NY:
Pioneers in Development (New York: Oxford University Cornell University Press, 1987). pp. 136164.
Press, 1987), pp. 92-103. Johnson, C., MIT1 and the Japanese Miracle (Stanford, CA:
Findlay, R. and S. Wellisz, “Introduction,” in R. Findlay and Stanford University Press, 1982).
S. Wellisz (Eds.), Five Small Open Economies (Oxford: Jones, L. P. and 1. SaKong, Government, Business and
Oxford University Press for the World Bank, 1993) pp. Entrepreneurship in Economic Development: the Korean
I-15. Case (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1980).
Fishlow, A., “Review of Handbook of Development Kim, S. T. K., “Singapore’s National Wages Council: Its
SINGAPORE’S ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 1437

influence on industrial relations,” Malaya Law Review, of Development (Singapore: Nan Yang Xing Zhou Lianhe
Vol. 23 (1981). pp. 52-122. Zaobao, 1984), pp. 253-287.
Koh, A. T., “Saving, investment and entrepreneurship,” in Manning, C. and E. F. Pang, “Labour market trends and
L. B. Krause et al. (Eds.), The Singapore Economy structures in ASEAN and the East Asian NICs,” Asia-
Reconsidered (Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Pacific Economic Literature, Vol. 4, No. 2 (1990). pp.
Studies, 1987). pp. 78-106. 59-8 1.
Krause, L. B., “Hong Kong and Singapore: Twins or kissing McKinnon, R. I., The Order of Economic Liberalization,
cousins?,” Economic Development and Cultural Change, Second edition (Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins
Vol. 36, No. 3, supplement (1988) pp. S45-S66. University Press, 1993).
Lee Hsien Loong, Singapore’s Economic Policy: Vision for Mason, E. S. et al., The Economic and Social Modernizatton
the 1990s Speech at the Commonwealth Institute, of the Republic of Korea (Cambridge, MA: Harvard
London, 1986. University Press, 1980).
Lee, J., “How MAS directs Singapore Inc.,” Euromoney Mills, L. A., Southeast Asia: Illusion and Reality in Politics
(September 1984), pp. 103-107. and Economics (Minneapolis, MN: University of
Lee Khoon Choy, On the Beat to the Husfings (Singapore: Minnesota Press, 1964).
Times Books International, 1988). Monetary Authority of Singapore, Annual Report 1992193
Lee Kuan Yew, “Lessons that Africa can draw from (Singapore: Monetary Authority of Singapore, 1993).
Singapore’s experience,” Extracts from a speech to the Monetary Authority of Singapore, Savings-investment
African Leadership Forum, Straits Times Weekly Balances in Singapore: Determinants and Medium-term
(November 13, 1993). Outlook (Singapore: Economics Department, Monetary
Lee Kuan Yew, “The Geoffrey Stem interview -Lee Kuan Authority of Singapore, 1991).
Yew,” LSE Magazine, Vol. 2, No. 4 ( 1990-9 I), pp. 2 l-25. Myrdal, G., Asian Drama (Harmondsworth, Middlesex:
Lee Kuan Yew, interview, “Singapore needs 10 more years Penguin, 1968).
to become a more mature society,” Straits Times Weekly New York Times, “Two faces of Singapore: Lofty aims, press
(May 5, 1990). curbs” (August 5, 1993).
Lee Kuan Yew, Extrapolating from the Singapore People’s Action Party, The Tasks Ahead: PAP’s Ftve-year
Experience, Speech to the International Chamber of Plan 1959-1964 (Singapore: PETIR, 1959).
Commerce, Orlando, Florida, 1978 (Singapore: Ministry Pang, E. F., “Development strategies and labour market
of Culture, 1978). changes in Singapore,” in E. F. Pang (Ed.), Labour Market
Lee Kuan Yew, Social Revolution in Singapore, Speech to Developments and Structural Change: The Experience of
the British Labour Party Conference (Singapore: ASEAN and Ausfralia (Singapore: Singapore University
Government Printing Office, 1967). Press, 1988). pp. 195-242.
Lee Sheng Yi, “Business elites in Singapore,*‘in P. S. J. Chen Please, S., “Saving through taxation - Reality or mirage?,”
and H. D. Evers, Studies in ASEAN Sociology (Singapore: Finance and Development, Vol. 4, No. 1 (1967), pp.
Chopmen Enterprises, 1978), pp. 38-60. 24-32.
Lim, C. Y., “Development economics by R. M. Sundrum: A Przeworski, A. and F. Limongi, “Political regimes and eco-
review article,” Malayan Economic Review, Vol. 28, No. nomic growth,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 7
1 (1983), pp. 88-103. No. 3 (1993), pp. 51-69.
Lim, C. Y. and Associates, Policy Options for the Singapore Rueschemeyer, D. and L. Putterman, “Synergy or rivalry”,”
Economy (Singapore: McGraw-Hill, 1988). in L. Putterman and D. Rueschemeyer (Eds.), State and
Lim, L., “Capital, labor, and the state in the intemationaliza- Market in Development (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
tion of high-tech industry: the case of Singapore,” in M. 1992), pp. 243-262.
Douglass and J. Friedmann (Eds.), Transnational Capital Sachs, J. D., Trade and Exchange Rate Policies in Growth-
and Urbanization on the Pacific Rim (Los Angeles: Centre Oriented Adjustment Programmes, NBER Working Paper
for Pacific Rim Studies, UCLA, 1987). pp. l-62. No. 2226 (Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic
Lim, L., “Singapore’s success: The myth of the free market Research, 1987).
economy,” Asian Survey, Vol. 23, No. 6 (1983). pp. Scalapino, R. A., The Politics of Development: Perspectrves
752-764. on Twentieth-Century Asia (Cambridge, MA: Harvard
Lim. L. and E. F. Pang, Trade, Employment and University Press, 1989).
Industrialisation in Singapore (Geneva: International Sen, A., “Development: Which way now?,” Econonirt
Labour Organisation, 1986). Journul, Vol 93 (1983), pp. 745-762.
Lim. L. and E. F. Pang, “Labour strategies and the high-tech Sharp, I., “The builders,” in This Smpapore (Singapore:
challenge: The case of Singapore,” Euro-Asia Business Times Publishing, 1975).
Review, Vol. 3, No. 2 (1984). pp. 27-3 1. Silcock, T. H., A Htsto~ of Econonnc Teachtng and
Lim, L., E. F. Pang, and R. Findlay, “Singapore,” in R. Graduates in Singapore, 1934-I 960 (Singapore:
Findlay and S. Wellisz (Eds.), Five Small Open Department of Economics and Statistics, University of
Economies (Oxford: Oxford University Press for the Singapore, 1985).
World Bank, 1993). pp. 93-139. Silcock, T. H., The Commonwealth Economy m Southeast
Lipton, M., “Review of Handbook of Development Asia (Durham, NC: Duke University Press, 1959).
Economics,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 38, Singapore, Singupore Census ofPopulation 1990. Stanstuol
No. 2 (1992), pp. 416427. Release 4: Economic Character-isttc.r (Singapore
Low, L., “Privatisation in Singapore,” in P. Cook and C. Department of Statistics, 1993).
Kirkpatrick (Eds.), Privatisation in Less Developed Singapore, Report on the Census ofPopu/atton 1970 Vol. I
Counfries (Brighton: Wheatsheaf Books, 1988). (Singapore: Department of Statistics, 1973).
Low, L., “Public enterprises in Singapore,” in You Poh Seng Singapore, Department of Statistics, Yerrrhook of St~~rr.vrir~.r
and Lim Chong Yah (Eds.), Singapore: Twenty-five Years (Singapore: Singapore National Printers, vanou5 years)
1438 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Singapore, Departmentof Statistics, Singapore NationalAccounrs Srraifs Times Weekly, “Sunday best” (December 18, 1993b).
I987 (Singapore: Singapore National Printers, 1988). Srrairs Times Weekly, “Government pay boost for 65,000”
Singapore, Department of Statistics or Economic (December 4, 1993).
Development Board, Report on the Census of Industrial Srrairs Times Weekly, “Too much savings? Not true - BG
Producrion (Singapore: Singapore National Printers, var- Lee” (August 29, 1992).
ious years). Strairs Times Weekly, “Vote will decide upgrading priority”
Singapore, Economic Development Board, Yearbook (April 18, 1992).
1991/1992 (Singapore: Economic Development Board, Srrairs Times Weekly, “Stand up and be quoted” (July 13,
1993). 1991)
-_- -,.
Singapore, Economic Planning Committee, Ministry of Szczepanik, E., The Economic Growth of Hong Kong
Trade and Industry, The Srraregic Economic Plan (London: Oxford University Press, 1958).
(Singapore: Singapore National Printers, 1991). US Department of Labor, Inrernarional Comparisons of
Singapore, Economic Planning Unit, First Developmenr Hourly Compensation Cosrs for Production Workers in
Plan, 1961-1964: Review of Progress (Singapore: Manufacturing 1993 (Washington, DC: USDL, 1994).
Government Printing Office, 1964). US Tariff Commission, Economic Facrors Af,Tectingthe Use
Singapore, Ministry of Finance, Developmenr Plan of Items 807.00 and 806.30 of rhe Tariff Schedule of rhe
1961-1964 (Singapore: Government Printing Office, United Stares (Washington, DC: US Tariff Commission,
1961). 1970).
Singapore, Ministry of Labour, Report on Wages in Vogel, E. F., The Four Lirrle Dragons (Cambridge, MA:
Singapore 1992 (Singapore: Singapore National Printers, Harvard University Press, 1991).
1993). United Nations, World lnvesrmenr Reporr 1992 (New York:
Singapore, Ministry of Trade and Industry, The Singapore United Nations, 1992).
Economy: New Direcrions (Report of the Economic
United Nations, A Proposed Indusrrializarion Programme
Committee) (Singapore: Singapore National Printers, .for rhe Srare of Singapore (New York: UN Commission
.IYtSb).
,.,.,~
for Technical Assistance, 1961).
Singapore, Ministry of Trade and Industry, Highlighrs of
Wade, R., Governing the Marker: Economic Theory and the
Singapore’s Economic Developmenr Plan for rhe Eighties
Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization
(Singapore: Curriculum Development Institute and
(Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1990).
Ministry of Trade and Industry, 1981).
Waterston, A., “A hard look at development planning,” in T.
Singapore, National Science and Technology Board,
Morgan and G. Betz (Eds.), Economic Development:
Window of Opportuniries: National Technology Plan
Readings in Theory and Pracrice (Belmont, CA:
1991 (Singapore: Singapore National Printers, 1991).
Wadsworth, 1970).
Singapore, SEP Working Group, Implementarion of the
Wee, C. C., “Export-Singapore’s new road to prosperity,”
Srraregic Economic Plan (Singapore: Ministry of Trade
Singapore Trade and Indusrry. August 1966.
and Industry, 1993).
Wellisz, S., “Lessons of twenty years of planning in devel-
Singapore Legislative Assembly, Debates, First session of
oping countries,” Economica, Vol. 38, No. 150( 1971) pp.
the Legislative Assembly, Part II, 18 November 1964, co].
121-135.
702.
Singapore Legislative Assembly, Debates, Vol. 22, first session Whang, I. J., “Economic management for structural adjust-
of the Legislative Council, Part I, 9 December 1963, col. 147. ment in the 1980s; in V. Corbo and S. M. Suh (Eds.),
Singapore Legislative Assembly, Debates, Vol. 22, No. 2,28 Structural Adjusrmenr in a Newly Indusrrialized Counrry:
November 1963, co]. 103. The Korean Experience (Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins
Singapore, Ministry of Labour, Annual Reporr 1967 (Cmd 7 University Press, 1992).
of 1969). Wong, K. P., “Saving, capital inflow and capital formation,”
Singapore, Parliamentary Debates, First session of the first in C. Y. Lim and P. J. Lloyd (Eds.), Singapore: Resources
Parliament, Vol. 24, 14 December 196.5, co]. 121. and Growth (Singapore: Oxford University Press, 1986).
Singapore Trade and Industry, “Public servant with a talent World Bank, World Bank Arias 1994 (Washington, DC:
for the bold plan, wide sweep” (April 1969) pp. 8-14. World Bank, 1994).
Singapore Trade and Indusrry, “Han Sui Sen: Key man for World Bank, The Easr Asian Miracle (Oxford: Oxford
new era of industrial development” (January 1969), p, 44. University Press for the World Bank, 1993).
Srrairs Times Weekly, “Politics for politicians only?’ World Bank, World Bank Atlas (Washington, DC: World
(December 24, 1994). Bank, 1967).
Srrairs Times Weekly, “PM [Goh Chok Tong]: Maximise Yeo, N. H., interview, “Flow of ministerial talent will ensure
growth while the going is good” (November 12, 1994). Singapore remains vibrant,” Srrairs Times Weekly
Srrairs Times Weekly>,“To get a good government, you need (December 25, 1993).
good men in charge” (November 5, 1994). Young, A., The Tyranny of Numbers: Confronting the
Straits Times Weekly, “Building a reputable civil service” Sraristical Realiries of the Easr Asian Growth Experience,
(October 29, 1994). NBER Working Paper No. 4680 (Cambridge, MA:
Srrairs Times Weekly, “New system to set ministers’ salaries” National Bureau of Economic Research, 1994).
(October 22, 1994). Young, A., “A tale of two cities: factor accumulation and
Straits Times Weekly, “PM concerned over ‘so many minis- technical change in Hong Kong and Singapore,” NBER
ters’ wishing to quit” (December 18, 1993a). Macroeconomics Annual 1992. Vol. 7 (1992), pp. 13-63.

Вам также может понравиться