Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 19

OXFORD REVIEW OF ECONOMIC POLICY, VOL. 20, NO.

2
DOI: 10.1093/oxrep/grh018

EDUCATION AND ECONOMIC


PERFORMANCE: SIMPLISTIC THEORIES
AND THEIR POLICY CONSEQUENCES

ALISON WOLF
King’s College London1

A largely unquestioned consensus proclaims that educational policy is an effective tool for delivering
prosperity and increasing rates of economic growth. This consensus rests on far less secure foundations
than is commonly supposed. International comparisons confirm that, as they become richer, people seek
ever more education for their children; but provide no clear-cut evidence of economic benefits accruing to
countries which are high-spending in education terms. Analyses which extrapolate from the incomes of
educated individuals rest on assumptions about how wages are determined, and the extent to which
rewards are for skills acquired in schooling, which are highly questionable. Moreover, an uncritical
belief in educational expansion leads to target-driven policies with serious negative effects on educa-
tional quality. A more realistic view of education’s economic impact, and a move away from centralized
planning for economic ends, would actually improve the quality of education.

I. INTRODUCTION draw directly on university-based research, and,


indeed, provide direct funding for it. If schools and
High levels of formal education are commonly seen universities were all closed down permanently, fu-
as one of the major prerequisites of the developed ture growth rates would unquestionably plummet
world’s current wealth, and as one of the major and, over time, national income would fall far below
determinants of future growth and prosperity. At current levels.
one level this is so obvious as to be banal. No modern
economy could function without large numbers of However, it does not follow that education policy is
people who have attained high levels of formal therefore an effective tool for ensuring economic
education; and innovatory companies (especially prosperity, let alone that it can guarantee specific
those involved in international trade) frequently levels of growth or national income. Many policy-
1
I would like to thank the editors, the reviewers, and participants in an editorial seminar in Oxford for very helpful comments
on an earlier draft.

Oxford Review of Economic Policy vol. 20 no. 2 2004


© Oxford University Press and the Oxford Review of Economic Policy Limited 2004; all rights reserved. 315
OXFORD REVIEW OF ECONOMIC POLICY, VOL. 20, NO. 2

makers currently believe that it does and can. Their Times that ‘education is the best anti-poverty and
views are based on imputed relationships between social and economic development strategy. . . . It
education and the economy for which the empirical provides . . . the skills to transform [people’s] lives
evidence is, in fact, extremely weak. This matters and lift their nations’ (Brown and George, 2002).
because current policy beliefs feed into major deci-
sions about educational spending and governance Garret Fitzgerald, prime minister of the Republic of
which at best divert the system from activities which Ireland for most of the 1980s, is convinced that the
are likely to have a much more direct impact on country’s growth surge and emergence as the
future prosperity, and at worst may even be per- ‘Celtic Tiger’ are due in large part to the ‘long-
verse in their economic effects. established and, I think, universal Irish conviction
that education is key to economic growth’ (Fitzgerald,
This paper first outlines the current policy consen- 2004). Similar quotations can be found in myriad
sus in this area. It then discusses and evaluates the party manifestos and OECD, EU, or UN reports. In
theoretical basis for this consensus. Why might it the UK, a comparison of White Papers and govern-
seem plausible to expect that increasing the amount ment commissions before and after the 1960s shows
of education people receive will deliver increases in that, whereas earlier documents gave major promi-
output? And why, conversely, might an apparent nence to non-economic purposes for education, the
relationship between education and output amount later ones are concerned almost entirely with edu-
to less than it seems? Following this, the paper cation, the economy, growth, and ‘employability’.
summarizes the empirical evidence. It asks how far,
at between-country level, the evidence supports the French secondary-school policy has been restruc-
idea that high levels of education spending are tured around a goal of taking 80 per cent of pupils to
associated with greater prosperity; and also, at baccalauréat level ever since cabinet members
individual and within-country level, how much we visiting Japan noted Japanese high-school gradua-
know about substantive links between people’s tion rates and linked these to the country’s then high
education and their productivity. Section IV of the growth rate. A number of countries have adopted
paper then returns to current and recent policy- precise numerical targets for higher education par-
making, with particular reference to the UK, and ticipation on explicitly economic grounds. They
evaluates recent policies inspired by beliefs about include Germany (40 per cent), Sweden (50 per
the relationship between education and the economy. cent), and the UK (50 per cent): the UK’s target
The concluding section summarizes the scope of formed part of the 1997 Labour Party Manifesto,
conventional policy, and its limitations; and makes and has been central to government policy since the
some brief recommendations for change. Labour victory of that year. Justifying and promot-
ing it in a feature article for the Guardian newspa-
(i) The Current Consensus per written on 23 May 2002, the UK’s then Secre-
tary of State for Education, Estelle Morris, ex-
Policy-makers have, over the last 40 or so years, plained that ‘A one percentage point increase in the
attempted to use education as a mechanism for number of workers with higher education qualifica-
increasing economic growth. Indeed, the view that tions raises GDP by 0.5 percent.’
expanding education contributes directly and pow-
erfully to economic prosperity is so pervasive that It is clearly true that, on average, richer countries
people barely notice or remark on it. For David have more of their population being educated for
Blunkett, then Labour’s secretary of state for edu- many more years than poorer ones: but then they
cation, ‘learning is the key to prosperity. Investment also have more motorways, more hospitals, and (at
in human capital will be the foundation of success in least for the moment) more symphony orchestras.
the knowledge-based global economy of the twenty- No one is suggesting that a direct way to greater
first century’ (Blunkett, 2000, p. 3) His Conserva- national wealth is to spend more and more on any of
tive predecessors fully agreed—so did his col- these, even though a good case can be made out for
leagues. The Chancellor, Gordon Brown, in con- the link between any one of them and individual
junction with the then governor of the Bank of citizens’ welfare—and even, in the case of motor-
England, argued in the pages of the Financial ways (transport) or hospitals (healthy workers)

316
A. Wolf

between their operations and economic dynamism. able—whether it is personal computers and mobile
Clearly, the enthusiasm for educating our way to telephones, or drugs, or travel insurance—depend
growth must rest on some underlying mechanism, on the existence of highly trained researchers,
assumed or made explicit, which is assumed to be engineers, and financial administrators. None of
extremely powerful. This is, indeed, the case. those people could carry out their jobs without
extensive education.

II. EDUCATION, HUMAN CAPITAL, However, the fact that human capital is of critical
AND THE ‘RESIDUAL FACTOR’ importance to modern societies does not in itself
establish that all and any forms of educational
The current belief in education as a powerful tool of ‘input’ automatically raise their recipient’s marginal
economic policy can trace its origins to the 1960s, in product. Many policy-makers, unfortunately, tend
the seminal work of Gary Becker (Becker, 1964; to assume just that. This, in turn, derives in large part
3rd edn, 1993), and also that of Edward Denison on from the way in which the links between education
the ‘residual factor’ in economic growth (Denison, and growth have been measured and analysed and
1962; OECD, 1964). Following Becker, economists presented to receptive political ears.
tend to discuss the importance of ‘human capital’,
whereas non-economists tend to talk about the As already noted, Becker’s work on human capital
importance of the work-force’s ‘skills’ (National took its direction from economists’ realization that
Skills Task Force, 2000; DfES, 2003). changes over time in physical capital and labour-
force size left large parts of the concurrent change
(i) What Might Education Achieve? in countries’ income unaccounted for. The work of
Edward Denison (1962, 1964) was extremely im-
As Becker explained in the preface to the first, 1964 portant in identifying other factors which might
edition of his book, Human Capital, his work has its account for economic growth. Almost all of these
origins in ‘the finding that a substantial growth in relate to the basic components of classical growth
income in the United States remains after the theory (land, capital, labour) but involve breaking
growth in physical capital and labor has been ac- them down further (e.g. to differentiate among
counted for’ (Becker, 1993, p. xxi). He and others factors that improve the quality and efficiency of the
argued for the importance of recognizing that peo- work-force). Denison also emphasized the ‘ad-
ple’s knowledge and skills are a form of capital that vance of knowledge’, or technical progress.
can yield income in just the same sense as ‘a bank
account, one hundred shares of IBM, assembly A critical and extremely influential aspect of
lines’ (Becker, 1993, p. 15). Such capital is embod- Denison’s, and much other later work, is that it
ied in people—hence human capital. Education and offered very precise estimates of how much differ-
training are, Becker argues, the most important ent factors influenced growth rates and, from this,
investments made in human capital, but his discus- recommendations about how to ensure growth in
sion emphasizes the importance of informal educa- the future. For example, Denison offered a number
tion within the family, and of on-the-job training, as of different ways in which the USA might increase
well as formal instruction. its growth rate by 1 percentage point. These include,
for example, an increase by 1 hour in the average
At a general level, the idea that investments in working week, and a doubling of net immigration
human capital matter for economic progress seems between 1962 and 1982—but also, ‘Add one-and-a-
not only plausible but intuitively and obviously cor- half years to the average time that would otherwise
rect. A more skilled and ‘higher quality’ work-force be spent in school by everyone completing school
is (almost by definition) more likely to be productive; between now and 1980’ (Denison, 1964, p. 21).
to note and correct problems before they affect
output; to understand what customers want; to This combination of simplicity and specificity—in
suggest and introduce improvements. Many inven- terms of inputs and outputs—is obviously very
tions that, over the last century, have made people’s appealing to any policy-maker. Two other points
lives safer, more comfortable, and more enjoy- about it are crucially important to understanding

317
OXFORD REVIEW OF ECONOMIC POLICY, VOL. 20, NO. 2

contemporary politicians’ infatuation with ‘educa- writers), as quoted in section I. In addition, develop-
tion for growth’, and its effects. The first is that the ment funding and policy recommendations have
measure of education used by Denison and by most used rate-of-return analysis to set priorities for
other contemporary and later economists studying education: for example, in downgrading support for
education, economic performance, and growth, is a vocational education (see, for example,
very simple one: namely, years of formal education Psacharopolous, 1985; Glewwe, 1996).
completed. This is because it is by far the most
generally available measure (and a fairly reliable However, if graduate salaries do not reflect or
one in straight measurement terms, even when self- depend on the skills they learned as undergraduates,
reported). However, it carries with it the very then one cannot extrapolate from them to future
questionable assumption that a year of schooling benefits to be gained from additional graduates.
can be treated as fairly uniform in terms of what is Similarly, in the development case, if wages do not
learned, regardless of when, where, and at what age reflect marginal product, then they are not a secure
it occurs. A second and equally important point basis on which to decide relative funding priorities
about precise estimates of how education contrib- within education. Put more generally, estimates
utes to output (and growth) is that they rest on the may be misleading for two important reasons. The
assumption that individuals’ earnings reflect their first is if the higher earnings of the educated are not
individual marginal product (OECD, 1964; Temple, because of their education, but because of other
2001). The incomes of the educated can, in that characteristics they possess; and the second is if
case, be used to derive accurate and unbiased people’s wages do not reflect their marginal prod-
estimates of the contribution of education to eco- uct.
nomic output in the past, and in the future.
At its most extreme, the first of these arguments
For just about any country you care to name, there suggests that education levels are more or less
is, indeed, a consistent and positive relationship perfectly correlated with innate ability, and it is this
between length of education and earnings: the edu- which employers are rewarding. Following Spence
cated earn more. Analyses generally show a posi- (1973), the concept of ‘signalling’ has come to be
tive rate of return to each and every additional year associated with this idea. Education and qualifica-
of education (see, for example, Griliches 1997; tions are used to indicate attributes which are
Sianesi and Van Reenan, 2000). More education independent of, though associated with, the skills
certainly seems like a good idea for the individuals and content with which education is overtly con-
concerned; but these findings have also been critical cerned. At their most extreme, signalling models
in convincing politicians that ratcheting up the num- posit a situation in which the higher pay of the more
bers of highly educated workers is an effective way educated has nothing to do with academic or voca-
to deliver economic growth. But are such earnings tional skills learned in education, but is entirely to do
differences indeed a direct result of formal educa- either with schooling’s supposed or actual associa-
tion developing skills which, in turn, raise individuals’ tion with innate ability, or its association with psy-
marginal product? chological and personality traits, such as diligence.

(ii) Why Are the Educated Paid More? Very few people would argue that returns to educa-
tion are entirely the result of its association with
Extrapolating from individual rates of return to higher ability: conversely, most people accept that
education and economic policy recommendations is some of the apparent effects are indeed returns to
currently most common for higher education. The ability, not to ‘human capital formation’. Denison
continuing income advantages of graduates are (1964, p. 16), for example, notes his assumption that
used to argue that university expansion will generate
three-fifths of the income differentials that appear, when
growth, as individuals’ ‘upskilling’ translates into men of similar age are classified by years of education,
higher output, and, indeed, that the economy there- result from the effect of more education on the ability to
fore ‘needs’ more graduates (CBI, 1994; CIHE, contribute to production; the remaining two-fifths reflect
2003). This is the view expressed by politicians such the tendency for individuals of greater natural ability and
as Estelle Morris (and her departmental speech- energy to continue their education, and that of other

318
A. Wolf

variables that are associated with, but not the result of, the The point can be illustrated using everyone’s fa-
amount of education. This three-fifths assumption . . . vourite occupational group, namely lawyers. Law-
enabled me to compute an index of the effect of increased yers are almost invariably the highest-earning occu-
education on the ability of the average worker to contrib- pational group in Western societies, and a belief that
ute to production.
people are paid their marginal product surely implies
Any such calculation must include such an assump- that we should be expanding the numbers of lawyers
tion, whether or not it is basically a guess (as in as a major economic priority. I do not know anyone
Denison’s own case) or based on empirical analy- who believes this, but once you start admitting that
sis. Detailed work using longitudinal data-bases in earnings are not a good indicator of marginal prod-
the UK and USA (see, for example, Murnane et al., uct for significant social groups, the whole case for
1995; Blundell et al., 2003) has provided us with using earnings as an unbiased indicator for society
increasingly sophisticated estimates of how far the as a whole is surely at risk. More generally, we now
more educated are, at a given point in time, also (in the West) live in societies where the proportion
more intrinsically able and of how far that ability (as of GDP which is spent by governments averages
measured by tests very early in life) affects later close to half. Income distributions and individual
earnings over and above the effects associated with wages and salaries depend on a host of institutional
formal education and diplomas (Dearden et al., factors, over and above individual productivity.2
2002). Many employees—notably in health and educa-
tion—have their salaries directly determined by
Analysts and policy-makers do not always ac- government policies, as do all civil servants, central
knowledge or allow for the role of ability (Temple, or local, and government-spending decisions (e.g.
2001). It is critical that they should, since it indicates on defence procurement, or legal aid) also have a
how far the calculated benefits of the past and major impact on earnings in other sectors.
present are replicable in the future, or are likely to be
far smaller. But it is also a ‘manageable’ issue, in the The dynamics of ‘signalling’ further complicate the
sense that it does not undermine the assumption that equation. Signalling theories are quite often dis-
people are being paid their marginal product. One cussed as though one had to choose between believ-
can estimate the effects, and, therefore, separate ing either that education has no effect whatsoever
out—and extrapolate—those due to the ‘skill en- on productivity, and that employers use education
hancement’ aspects of education. purely as a signal of ability, or believing that educa-
tion-related differentials are all a result of ‘human
The latter becomes much more problematic if, on capital formation’. I have never met anyone who
the other hand, wages and marginal product are not held the former position (though, as we have seen,
associated. The assumption that they are—and that a good number of people seem to hold the latter).
one can therefore estimate quite precisely the eco- The labour-market evidence is, rather, consistent
nomic effects of additional education—has been with the co-existence of three processes.
strongly criticized for quite as long as there have
been proponents of Denison-type models (see, for First, education imparts new and valuable skills and
example, Vaizey, 1962; OECD, 1964; Pritchett, knowledge. It is also, second, correlated with under-
1996). This is not to say that people’s earned lying ability, and used, with some justification, by
incomes never have any relationship to their skills employers as a proxy for this. Third, however,
and productivity. However, accepting some rela- education provides formal credentials. These may
tionship (stronger or less strong for different groups be quite imperfectly associated with actual produc-
or societies) is very different from assuming the tivity, but important in the labour market in rationing
relationship to be both general and direct enough to and controlling access to jobs and opportunities
allow precise estimation of education’s effects on because employers see them as a useful (though
productivity. admittedly imperfect) indicator. If credentials, as

2
As Margaret Stevens points out (personal communication; see also Stevens, 1999), if wages do not reflect marginal products,
it is quite as possible to underestimate as to overestimate the social returns to education. See Glewwe (1996) for a related argument.

319
OXFORD REVIEW OF ECONOMIC POLICY, VOL. 20, NO. 2

well as their holders’ actual (innate and acquired) III. COUNTRY COMPARISONS
skills and abilities, affect future incomes, then peo-
ple have strong incentives to acquire yet more of The previous section criticized the idea that we can
them, and, specifically, more than their contempo- routinely link specific amounts of an educational
raries and competitors, even if they do not actually input (years of education or particular diplomas) to
increase their potential productivity much in the specific amounts of an output (GDP). However, this
process (see, for example, Collins, 1979; Wolf, does not mean that (all or some) education is
2002a; Sianesi, 2003). irrelevant to workers’ productivity, or to helping the
economy grow. If the empirical evidence suggests
It is extremely hard to estimate the extent to which a strong relationship in practice between levels of
formal education, when it affects earnings, does so education and levels of GDP, or between educa-
via genuine skill acquisition, and how far credential- tional expansion policies and growth, then the theo-
holders benefit at the expense of other people who retical problems raised above may be judged rela-
might perform just as well. However, both factors tively unimportant, and governments’ enthusiasm
appear significant (Jenkins and Wolf, forthcoming). for education vindicated. This section of the paper
For example, in the USA, high-school drop-outs, and therefore summarizes key empirical evidence, first
adult immigrants, may obtain a high-school diploma at the between-country level, and then within coun-
equivalent in the form of the GED (General Educa- try.
tional Development) certificate and, indeed, almost
half a million a year now do. Labour-market data (i) Country Comparisons
show clearly that the certificate does have value, but
less than a ‘normal’ high-school diploma, and that If countries which are broadly similar in other
this is best explained not in terms of differences in respects have different growth rates and different
the cognitive skills associated with the two diplomas, education policies, it is very tempting to see one as
but by employers using the diplomas as signals not the direct cause of the other. Governments certainly
merely of skills but also of attitudes and likely work do it all the time, especially in response to the
ethic (see, especially, Cameron and Heckman, 1993; international surveys of comparative achievement
Murnane et al., 1999). which have become such an established part of the
education scene—notably the IEA’s international
The main conclusion must be that, while (almost) maths and science surveys or the OECD’s PISA
nobody would deny that education creates ‘human studies of teenagers’ attainment and its surveys of
capital’, the relationship between this and what adult literacy (see, for example, OECD, 1995, 2001;
happens in the labour market, or the real economy, Ruddock, 2000).
is far more complex than a simple input–output
model implies, and not susceptible to precise estima- In any country which does badly, or simply less well
tion. One can easily imagine credentialist pressures than expected, politicians and the media tend imme-
leading many young people to acquire ever higher- diately to compare their country with others which
level qualifications and, in the process, skills which have done better and are, at the time, economically
are of little interest to employers, who do, however, successful. They then call for, or, indeed, imple-
want workers who have mastered, to a high level, ment, education reforms which will move them
skills taught earlier in the educational process. Since closer to the ‘winning’ systems. Recent examples
those who do well earlier are also most likely to include making English primary school mathematics
acquire higher qualifications, it is to these latter— more like that of Germany and Japan, in the wake of
probably degrees—that high returns will appear to the Third International Maths and Science Survey
accrue, because their holders will be employers’ results; while, more recently, the German Chancel-
choice. A government which assumes that returns lor’s declaration of a national educational emer-
to education are bound to be accurate signals of gency was a response to PISA results in which
individual productivity, or of future returns to more German teenagers trailed Scandinavian (and, in-
of the same, is likely to make seriously bad deci- deed, British) students. In other words, people start
sions. with and from the consensual opinion that education

320
A. Wolf

matters critically for the economy and choose their reassuring, since the idea that increases in schooling
role models and reforms accordingly. might actually reduce growth is profoundly anti-
intuitive. None the less, their work also confirms
The research literature, however, attempts to iso- how extremely sensitive results are to model speci-
late the impact of education on countries’ economic fications, and that some apparently ‘obvious’ rela-
performance using large data-sets (covering from tionships between education variables and growth
58 to 91 countries) rather than carefully selected are no such thing.4
comparators. Indeed, Krueger and Lindahl remark
on the veritable ‘Tsunami of cross-country regres- Overall, as an endorsement of the idea that expand-
sion studies threatening to wash us all away’ ing educational provision is a sure-fire way of
(Krueger and Lindahl, 1999, p. 15). delivering growth, these studies at best come closer
to one hand clapping than to any sort of ovation.
The most striking feature of these studies is the They are also, inevitably, limited by the simple and
marked absence of any clear education effects. For restricted nature of their variables (physical capital
something which is supposedly so obvious, and so stock, years of education). Cross-country compari-
powerful, a promoter of economic well-being and sons of a more detailed and institutional sort may
growth, it is extraordinary how many studies find no clarify whether, how, and when education is able to
relationship between increases in schooling levels improve economic performance.
and growth.3 Indeed, some studies, based on exten-
sive data-sets, actually find a negative relation- The developed world
ship—see, for example, Lau et al. (1991); Benhabib Much of the academic literature on education,
and Spiegel (1994); and Pritchett (1996) for results training, and growth argues for the central impor-
based on different sets of estimates. tance of the first two for the last, and, as such, has
had a major influence on the policy environment.
For those of us who believe that education can This has been especially true in the UK, where, in
increase people’s productivity, even if it does not the latter decades of the twentieth century, the
always do so, this is disconcerting. It seems to British élite became increasingly convinced that its
suggest that the strong relationship between educa- economy was failing because its education system
tion and individual earnings, which has been main- was failing, too (see, for example, Barnett, 1986).
tained within countries as average education levels
rise, may indeed have most to do with signalling, or Particular attention has been paid to the ‘Asian
spiralling credentialism, or indicate that many edu- tiger’ economies and to Germany (see, for example,
cated people occupy jobs which are well paid but for Finegold and Soskice, 1988; Ashton and Green,
reasons which have little to do with high marginal 1996; Crouch et al., 1999; Brown et al., 2001). The
products. history of some of the ‘Asian tigers’ is a particular
favourite for those wishing to make a case not only
Krueger and Lindahl (1999) argue, in response to for the importance of education generally but also
these findings, that measurement error is likely to be for the role of government in directing it. For
very important in international comparisons of this example, the government of Korea, where annual
type, and that, in much of the data, there is actually growth in real wages averaged around 7 per cent
more noise than signal. On that reasoning, and by throughout the 1960s and 1970s, ran a massive
making changes to their model in response, they national literacy campaign immediately after the
obtain results in which the effect of changes in end of the Second World War, then expanded
schooling on growth appears as positive. This is secondary schooling, and then vocational high schools

3
Krueger and Lindahl (1999) and Temple (2001) provide excellent overviews of the literature and of the methodological issues
associated with different studies and results.
4
The key adjustment which they make in response to presumed (and highly probable) measurement error is to constrain the
coefficient on capital growth (p. 19). With this reduced, the coefficient on schooling change rises. The authors find that initial levels
of education do not appear, in their models, to have any effect on economic growth among OECD countries: a finding which is
itself both surprising and at odds with governments’ belief in the need to ensure high levels of education today as a spring-board
for survival, let alone success, in the ‘knowledge economy’ of the future.

321
OXFORD REVIEW OF ECONOMIC POLICY, VOL. 20, NO. 2

and technical universities, even though parents ‘failure’. Owen (1999), in his account of the decline
wanted their children to attend general and aca- and revival of British industry since 1945, concludes
demic programmes. that in only one of the sectors that he studies does
training seem to have been of major importance to
It is hard to believe that Korea’s education policies decline (or revival). Finally, if schoolchildren’s rela-
did not help its post-war success, and the same is tive performance were really so significant, one
true of, for example, the symbiotic relationship would expect at least some correlation between
between Germany’s Dual System for apprentice- international survey results in one decade and eco-
ship, and the success of its manufacturing sector, nomic performance some way down the line. Yet,
which continues to contribute an unusually high as Robinson (1999) has demonstrated, no such link
share of GDP for a developed country (see, for exists: there is no correlation whatsoever between
example, Soskice, 1994; Culpepper, 1999; Dore, teenagers’ performance on international surveys of
2000). But it does not follow that education and attainment and economic performance in the fol-
training policy were the major and critical factors lowing decades.
even in these countries’ economic growth patterns
(as compared to, say, the Erhard economic re- Developing countries
forms in Germany, which unleashed the 1950s Comparative analyses which focus on the develop-
economic miracle). At present, Germany is, in its ing world confirm the absence of any simple rela-
turn, looking to education to solve its economic tionships but also provide indications of why asso-
problems. Its own history, as well as that of others, ciations between education and growth are so elu-
counsels caution. sive. A number of authors (e.g. Thomas and Wang,
1996; Lopez et al., 1998) emphasize the importance
Among the successful post-war economies, exam- of other policies such as openness to trade, and
ples where governments took highly interventionist, argue that education and these other policies inter-
manpower-planning-related approaches to educa- act. Only when the economic policy environment is
tion (such as Korea) can be matched by others appropriate can education promote growth, allow-
(such as Hong Kong) where they did not. There is ing skills (human capital) to be brought to bear
no obvious relationship, within the wealthy OECD, effectively.
between university enrolment rates and income per
head: Switzerland, notably, has held out most firmly Certainly, developing countries provide vivid exam-
against huge increases in university enrolments, ples of how to combine high levels of expenditure on
while retaining its position as the richest of the non- education with low levels of economic output. Those
oil states.5 The quality of America’s education which spent the most on expanding education in the
system has been castigated at home for decades, mid- to late twentieth century seem also to have
(see, for example, National Commission, 1983): the been disproportionately likely to believe in man-
country consistently does badly in international com- power and other forms of central planning, to pour
parative surveys, and until the innovation-based large sums of money into loss-making state enter-
boom of the 1990s, it figured prominently in institu- prises, and to expand state bureaucracies in order to
tion-based analyses as an example of how not to create jobs for otherwise unemployed graduates
‘educate for growth’. from their expanding universities.6

The UK’s own economic revival in the last 20 years Studies of developing countries also illustrate how
has involved a work-force, the vast majority of easily education can become a process of intense
whom were educated in the years of educational competition for credentials and, at one and the same
5
It is important to distinguish between different forms of post-secondary education when comparing ‘tertiary’ enrolment figures,
as presented by, for example, OECD or EU summary tables. Switzerland has, by OECD standards, a very low enrolment rate in
universities, but has a highly developed system of post-school apprenticeship and higher vocational training.
6
Examples include Egypt and Sri Lanka. The former for many years had a policy of rapid expansion of, first, upper-secondary
and then tertiary education. Relatively highly paid jobs in the state bureaucracy were then created to soak up the numbers of
unemployed graduates who might otherwise threaten social stability (creating continuing strong demand for university places among
the population for whom education did indeed offer high returns). In Sri Lanka the situation has been similar, with higher education
operating primarily as a route into government jobs, for which there is intense competition exacerbated by ethnic tensions.

322
A. Wolf

time, extremely unlikely to develop the type of skills levels. It is after the enormous economic successes
which enhance productivity. Dore’s work, in par- of the 1970s and 1980s that Hong Kong children
ticular, has illustrated how commonly formal educa- start out-performing their English counterparts, as
tion becomes a process of rote learning, through they compete for jobs which are increasingly pro-
which the children who are academically most able fessional-level, and accessible through formal quali-
and determined compete for scarce white-collar, fications.
public-sector jobs (Dore, 1976, 1997; see also Little,
1997). Bils and Klenow (1998) offer an ingenious empirical
method of estimating the extent to which growth
(ii) Family Matters: A Dynamic Relationship generates education or education growth. The basic
argument for why ‘education leads to growth’ is that
In general, the empirical data suggest that relying on education increases productivity and so the edu-
education to promote economic growth is only too cated have higher wages. However, workers also
likely to create as many problems as it solves, by tend to earn more as they build up time, and skills, on
generating spiralling credentialism . In fact, one can the job: we can call it an ‘experience premium’.
advance an even stronger criticism of governments’
current infatuation with education as a policy tool: In most countries, over recent decades, the average
namely that, if governments get their other eco- duration of education for young workers has in-
nomic policies right, education will largely take care creased markedly compared to their older work-
of itself. mates. If all this additional education has really
increased their productivity, both immediately (since
This is because growth generates education as they have less to learn when they start work) and in
much as vice versa . The relationship is dynamic and the longer term (because they learn faster and more
two-way. In a growing economy, governments do thoroughly), then wage statistics should reflect this.
not need to persuade and chivvy citizens to get Over time, we should find that the experience
educated. Most will do so anyway, for good per- premium declines. Highly educated young workers
sonal reasons; though, of course, the more cheaply should get paid more on entry than the previous
education is offered, the more they will choose to generation did, but less of an ‘experience premium’
acquire.7 because they have less to learn. And those countries
with the most rapidly narrowing premiums should be
This two-way relationship derives from the obvious the fastest growing, reflecting the benefit of their
benefits of education to individuals, in the form of educated young workers.
better career chances and higher incomes, plus the
universal tendency of parents to further their chil- None of these patterns can be found and the breadth
dren’s welfare. Moreover, as I and others have or narrowness of the ‘experience’ bonus in work-
argued at length elsewhere (see, for example, Frank ers’ wages seems to bear no relationship to growth
and Cook, 1995; Wolf, 2002a; Stevens, 2004), the rates. If high-quality schooling is making any differ-
higher the level of formal qualifications in a society, ence to the relative economic performance of coun-
the riskier it becomes for oneself or one’s children tries, it is doing so in a very undramatic fashion, since
to be unqualified. So while it may be true in some (once again) its effects appear to be swamped or
general sense that education fosters growth, it is neutralized by other factors. What Bils and Klenow’s
certainly true, in a very specific sense, that growth results do confirm, however, is that, while schooling
creates education. As families obtain extra income, may not have much obvious impact on growth, fast-
the overwhelming majority seek good schools for growing economies do encourage further increases
their children, press them to obtain qualifications, in schooling. Growth generates education, whether
and crowd into expanded institutions at ever higher or not education generates growth.

7
There may be problems with the provision of particular specialized skills, where government intervention is necessary.
However, much current government policy is about generating more and more education at a very general level—which is not where
supply problems are at all likely.

323
OXFORD REVIEW OF ECONOMIC POLICY, VOL. 20, NO. 2

Table 1
Qualifications in the UK Work-force: Demand and Supply

Level of % citing this Total No. of jobs Total No. of individuals


highest qualification level, 2001 in Britain requiring aged 20–60 possessing
required to perform this level of qualification, qualifications at this level
respondent’s job 2001, ‘000s (but no higher), 2001, ‘000s

Level 4 or above: 29.2 7,122 7,359


Level 3 16.3 3,976 6,379
Level 2 15.9 3,878 5,302
Level 1 12.1 2,951 3,549
No qualifications 26.5 6,464 2,881

Source: Felstead et al. (2002). The figures are derived from the 2001 Skills Survey and the 2001 Labour
Force Survey; for a detailed discussion, see, especially, the notes to Tables 4.1 and 4.5 in Felstead et al.
In addition, studies consistently find that many jobs capital, at any given instant it is extremely unlikely
which were once open to non-graduates are now that a major constraint on growth is inadequate
‘graduate entry’, even though their nature has not demand for (or, indeed, total, private plus public,
changed. ‘Over-education’, in the sense that many spending on) education.
people hold higher levels of formal education than
necessary for the job they do, is a common phenom- The quality of supply is, of course, a quite independ-
enon in both the developed and the developing world ent issue, where governments have a great deal of
(see, for example, Murphy 1993; Alpin et al., 1998). influence. Unfortunately, simplistic policies have, in
important respects, tended to undermine rather than
Table 1 illustrates this graphically for the UK. The advance quality. Before I describe how (in section
figures compare the numbers of jobs requiring a IV), the next section provides a brief survey of
given level of formal qualification (based on incum- research which sheds light on ways in which educa-
bents’ own analysis) with numbers in the work- tion may, indeed, help to raise the marginal products
force possessing that level. In every category but of the educated.
one there is a clear surplus of individuals with the
required level of qualification over the number of (iii) When does Education ‘Work’?
jobs which require skills at this level. The one
exception is jobs for which no formal qualification is Formal education is a major source of human capi-
required at all—six and a half million of those tal, but cross-country evidence indicates that it is no
compared to less than three million workers without magic bullet, and that whether (and how much)
formal qualifications. education increases its recipients’ marginal product
will depend, critically, on the general economic and
So while it may be true in some general sense that policy environment. It also depends on what that
given levels of economic output and development education involves. At the within-country level, we
require certain overall levels of human capital in the can obtain some indications of what sort of educa-
work-force, securing these is the least of govern- tion ‘matters’ economically, from rate-of-return
ment’s worries. In any twenty-first-century coun- analyses for a few unusually rich databases, studies
try, rich or poor, parents and children will ensure that of individual firms, and research on technical inno-
the demand for ‘enough’ education is present, and vation.
the more wealth there is (from previous growth) and
the wealthier people are, the more important quali- Summarized very briefly, three important messages
fications become. While, over time, a modern emerge. First, there are cases where more educa-
economy may need ever-higher levels of human tion does seem clearly associated with higher pro-

324
A. Wolf

ductivity, but their nature differs between countries et al., 1995). And detailed qualitative studies of a
and across time. For example, ‘natural experi- variety of occupational sectors (see, especially,
ments’, such as an increase in the school-leaving Hoyles et al., 2002) find that mathematical and
age, show that young people with more education quantitative skills have become increasingly impor-
earn more than their immediate predecessors within tant in a wider range of jobs, largely because of the
a similar job market, presumably because of their increasing importance of IT, and the opportunities it
higher skills (Meghir and Palme, 1999).8 Glewwe offers for data generation and analysis.
was able to use a rich Ghanaian data set, including
independent measures of workers’ ability and at- Third, and finally, the economic importance of both
tainment, and to establish not simply that there a sizeable output of innovative research, and the
appears to be credentialism in the public sector, symbiotic relationship between a country’s suc-
along with more general problems of selectivity bias, cessful industries and its universities are well at-
but also, and most importantly, that school quality tested: especially for countries which are already
had declined over time. Falling rates of return to rich, rather than catching up with the developed
primary education, he argued, should not be taken to world. The strength of countries in various different
mean that money should be redirected away from it; sectors (e.g. pharmaceuticals, chemicals, software
on the contrary, more should be spent to restore engineering) is closely related to the areas in which
quality and increase returns (Glewwe, 1996, p. 284). they possess centres of university excellence (e.g.
Porter et al., 2000). Similarly, while not all ‘clusters’
Jones’s work, also in Ghana (Jones, 2001), indicated of excellence involve business with universities or
that, in factories there, more-educated workers even technical institutes—some of the Italian clus-
were indeed more productive, and paid accordingly ters of small, successful craft-based manufacturers
(although she was not able to control for prior provide a counter-example (Kay, 1993)—in other
ability). However, Weiss’s study of manufacturing industries, such clusters do, indeed, seem to be both
in the USA (again with no prior ability controls) extraordinarily productive, with clearly discernible
found that high-school graduates were no more spillovers related to geographic location (see, for
productive on a day-by-day basis than high-school example, Audretsch et al., 2003), and access to both
drop-outs, but did have better attendance levels knowledge and high-quality employees.
(Weiss, 1984). So, again, education may increase
productivity—but not always.
IV. EDUCATING FOR THE ECONOMY:
Second, a growing body of evidence points to the SIMPLISTIC THEORIES AND
importance of quantitative/mathematical skills in THEIR POLICY IMPACT
developed economies. For example, in the UK,
workers with A-level maths (i.e. who took ad- I have argued above that the idea that increasing
vanced/specialist maths in upper secondary school) education levels is an effective policy tool for in-
earn significantly more than their peers, even after creasing output rests on assumptions and interpre-
controlling for a host of factors, including general tations of data that are highly questionable. But does
levels of education and childhood ability/achieve- this matter? In countries where governments are
ment measures. This effect only becomes evident relatively uninterested in education, public (or rather
after several years in the labour market, so cannot parental) demand is pretty much guaranteed to keep
be the result of employers using maths as a signal of education levels rising alongside prosperity . Con-
higher ability at the time of labour-market entry versely, if other governments have a strong faith in
(Dolton and Vignoles, 2000). In the USA, the education for growth, and spend more as a result,
importance of mathematics attainment, compared one can surely expect that the economy will not
to other educational and attainment measures has actually suffer and, if other things go right, may be
been increasing steadily in recent years (Murnane able to benefit.

8
However, qualifications which certify acquisition of particular substantive and apparently valued skills may lose their labour-
market value quite rapidly during periods of educational expansion, as has happened with some English ones, notably lower-level
academic (GCSE) certificates. This suggests that credentialism can also cut in quite fast (Sianesi, 2003).

325
OXFORD REVIEW OF ECONOMIC POLICY, VOL. 20, NO. 2

This would be a comforting conclusion, but of process for as long as possible. The more years
course, the levels of spending which go into educa- each person spends in formal education, the more
tion and the quality of educational output are by no teachers are needed, and the more downward
means the same thing. This section argues that the pressure there is likely to be on teachers’ salaries.
current policy consensus can have serious adverse Given both existing acute teacher shortages in key
effects on the quality of education, using recent UK subjects such as maths and science (Smith, 2004),
government policy as an example. and the likelihood that average teacher quality has
been declining in recent years as relative salaries
In discussing the origins of current ideas, in the and conditions deteriorate (Eide et al., this issue),
growth and human-capital literature of the 1960s, the risks as well as the benefits of chasing increases
section II flagged as important the fact that the in ‘education-years’ should at least be addressed.
measure of education used in ‘studying education, The presumption that any additional year of educa-
economic performance and growth, is a very simple tion must yield positive economic benefits is a
one: namely, years of formal education completed’. powerful barrier to such an appraisal.
In academic analysis, this is done in large part
because other more substantive measures are absent; The formal growth literature does, of course, ac-
none the less, it is accepted as a reasonably good proxy knowledge that years of schooling are an imperfect
for actual learning and skill enhancement. measure: in Denison’s celebrated list of ways to add
one percentage point to the growth rate, his recom-
Because so much of the discussion of returns to mendation is to ‘Add one-and-a-half years to the
education is in terms of years of schooling, and average time that would . . . be spent in school . . .
because international statistics (whether from the or make an equivalent improvement in the qual-
EU, OECD, or UNESCO) also take that form, it is ity of education’ (Denison, 1964, p. 21, italics
hardly surprising that governments do likewise. In mine). Moreover, there is one potentially more
the UK, current governmental efforts to increase satisfactory measure of quality available, namely
the proportions of the age cohort staying in full-time qualifications acquired. North America has rather
education to age 18 are fuelled by comparisons with few of these at sub-baccalaureate level, but most
other European countries and take it as given that other developed countries have a wide range of
this will increase the skills of the additional students formal, national qualifications and diplomas which
and the skill ‘stock’ of the nation. In a recent are generally administered, or, at the least, heavily
memorandum to the House of Commons Education regulated, by the state (Wolf, 2002b).
and Skills Select Committee, holding hearings on
14–19 education and training, the Department for In the last 20 years, British education policy has
Education and Skills identified increasing staying-on been even more occupied with increasing qualifica-
rates as a top priority: a major reason being that the tion numbers than with increasing staying-on rates,
UK ranks ‘27th out of 30 among developed nations and it might seem that I have, therefore, been unduly
for participation of 17 year olds in education and critical of policy. Qualifications should, in theory, be
training’ (DfES, 2004). able to provide an objective measure of skills ac-
quired, and so of potential productivity gains. How-
Of course, it is perfectly possible that 17-year-olds ever, here, too, simplistic policy formulations have
will learn useful and productive skills by staying in distorted educational provision.
education, but the general mind-set is a curious one.
In most industries, one tries to reach a substantive The education targets9 which first became impor-
outcome quickly and efficiently, not extend the tant in the early 1990s encapsulate the problem.
9
Government’s growing preoccupation with the economic functions of education has, in the UK, developed alongside centralization
of control and the advent of a public-sector-wide accountability culture built around targets, league tables, audit trails, and the like (Power,
1997). It can be difficult to disentangle these different influences, but the qualification targets which have such a major influence on
the nature and conduct of British education certainly have their primary origin in beliefs about what the economy ‘needs’ from education.
The most important piece of education legislation in recent decades was the 1988 Education Reform Act, which established a national
curriculum for children aged 5–16 and a system of national tests at ages 7, 11, and 14 (respectively the ends of ‘Key Stages 1, 2, and
3’ of compulsory schooling). Published league tables, compiled by government, show the comparative performance of individual schools
and of local education authorities on these tests, and also at GSCE (General Certificate of Secondary Education—graded public
examinations taken at age 16) and A level (academic graded public examinations taken at age 18).

326
A. Wolf

They were originally inspired by the CBI (Confed- Table 2 summarizes different formulations of the
eration of British Industry), a strong advocate of overall National Education and Training Targets
building up human capital as an effective ‘supply- which drive education policy. The early ones were
side’ approach to boosting productivity and growth. expressed primarily in terms of National Vocational
In a well-publicized task-force report of 1989 (To- Qualifications (NVQs), which were introduced in
wards a Skills Revolution), the CBI argued that ‘it the late 1980s with the intention of greatly increasing
is necessary to set world class [qualification] targets both the relevance and the popularity of vocational
. . . [which] will have to be reviewed and raised until (as opposed to academic) qualifications. However,
the United Kingdom is on a par with its main during the 1990s, a ‘National Qualifications Frame-
competitors’ (CBI, 1989, p. 19). It also (CBI, 1994) work’ was introduced which classified all qualifica-
argued strongly for continuing expansion of higher tions (including university ones) at one of five levels,
education and a 50 per cent participation target. and later targets use these.

The CBI was highly influential with the Conserva- At present, all the existing 2002 targets remain as
tive governments of the late 1980s and early 1990s given, but a number of new targets have been
(Wolf, 2002a), which were determined to make the added. They include:
education system more vocationally relevant and
were strong believers in education’s relevance to • a 7 per cent reduction in the number of adults
and effects on growth (see, for example, DES, not participating in learning;
1991). ‘National Education and Training Targets’ • reducing by 40 per cent by 2010 the number of
were introduced in 1991 and progress towards adult workers currently without a level 2 quali-
meeting them became and remains central to the fication;
way that government reviews and conducts its own • improving the basic skills of 1.8m adults be-
programmes and, therefore, to the success and tween 2001 and 2007, with an intermediate
behaviour of public-sector employees, whether DfES target of 750,000 by 2004;
officials reporting to the Treasury and Downing • 80 per cent of 11-year-olds reaching the ex-
Street, further education college principals, small pected standard of literacy (level 4 as meas-
training ‘providers’, or part-time teaching staff. The ured on official tests) for their age and 75 per
rationale was summarized by the CBI in a pamphlet cent reaching the standard in numeracy;10
welcoming the targets’ arrival: ‘The primary source • 50 per cent of 16-year-olds getting 5 higher
of competitive advantage lies in investing in people. grade GCSEs (or equivalent) and 95 per cent
The UK cannot afford to debate this issue, it must obtaining at least 1 GCSE.
believe it’ (CBI, 1991, pp. 7–8).
The decision to create a national framework was
The Labour government, which took over in 1997, almost inevitable, given the prior decision to adopt
fully shares its predecessors’ view of the impor- quantitative targets and use them to steer policy.
tance of human capital and the desirability of tar- With many thousands of different qualifications in
gets. One of its first actions was to set up a ‘National existence (often of a highly specialized nature),
Skills Task Force’ which argued the case for skills some form of equivalence and categorization was
as a way of improving UK productivity (compared necessary. Even in the vocational field, where
unfavourably with the USA, France, and Germany), NVQs had ‘levels’ from the start, hundreds of older
and the importance of policies to ‘attain . . . skills qualifications lived stubbornly on, as employers and
appropriate for the knowledge economy of tomor- employees continued to use them in preference to
row’ (National Skills Task Force, 2000, p. 13). It the new NVQs (Wolf, 1997). But the result of
also recommended some additional targets as an creating the framework, and placing all existing
important way of securing this goal. qualifications within it, was that qualifications of

10
The ‘expected standard’ is a level in the National Curriculum, which defines all subjects in relation to 10 levels. While these
were not originally meant to be age-related, in practice they were defined in terms of what it was thought an average child at a given
stage might achieve. The ‘expected’ level for 11-year-olds was thus originally conceived as the median level for that age. Eleven-
year-olds’ attainment on National Curriculum tests in maths, English, and science is the basis for primary-school league tables.

327
OXFORD REVIEW OF ECONOMIC POLICY, VOL. 20, NO. 2

Table 2
The National Education and Training Targets: Successive Formulations

1991 1995 1998

By 1997, 80% of all young people By 2000, 85% of all young people By 2002, 50% of 16-year-olds
to reach NVQ2 or equivalent to achieve 5 GCSEs at grade C achieving 5 or more GCSEs at
or above, an Intermediate GNVQ grades A*–C and 95% achieving
or an NVQ2 1 or more GCSEs at grades A*–G

By 2000, 50% of young people to By 2000, 75% of young people to By 2002, 85% of 19-year-olds
reach NVQ3 or equivalent achieve level 2 competence in with a ‘level 2’ qualification.
communication, numeracy, and IT By 2002, 60% of 21-year-olds
by age 19; and 35% to achieve with a ‘level 3’ qualification
level 3 competence by age 21
By 2000, 60% of young people to
achieve 2 GCE A levels, an
Advanced GNVQ or an NVQ
level 3 by age 21

By 1996, all employees should No employee target No employee target


take part in training or
development activities

By 1996, 50% of the work-force By 2000, 60% of the work-force No work-force target
aiming for NVQs or units qualified to NVQ level 3,
towards them Advanced GNVQ or 2 GCE
By 2000, 50% of the work-force A level standard
qualified at least NVQ3 By 2000, 30% of the work-force
or equivalent to have a qualification at
NVQ4 or above

No adult learning target No adult learning target By 2002, 50% of adults to have a
‘level 3’ qualification. By 2002, 28%
of adults with a ‘level 4’ qualification

very different types and labour-market value, be- to the provision of formal qualifications, and ‘provid-
came ‘equivalent’ in the eyes of auditors, funders, ers’ will often sign contracts with the funding bodies
and policy-makers. This, in turn, created some which specify very precisely the numbers of quali-
obvious incentives for providers of education and fications of a particular type and level to be achieved.
training (including civil servants) to deliver the sim- For a period of time in the mid-1990s, a large part of
plest/cheapest/most accessible qualifications at a the funding for many courses was paid only if and
given level rather than those most useful to the when the learner actually received the qualification
economy (or the individual learner). (‘output-related funding’). Most of the qualifica-
tions involved were vocational ones, with 100 per
The effects of targets can be illustrated particularly cent internal assessment, carried out by the teachers/
clearly in the further-education sector, which is the providers concerned, with the predictable effects on
main provider of post-16, non-university education assessment quality. A number of high-profile scan-
and training—see Mager et al. (2000) for a fuller dals highlighting the results of this policy meant that
discussion. Funding in this sector is very largely tied the proportions were modified, but the basic princi-

328
A. Wolf

ples still apply in large parts of the vocational It is, therefore, not surprising to discover that two-
curriculum (Stanton, 1996; Mager et al., 2000).11 thirds of learners on ‘adult basic skills’ courses,
taking the qualifications and counting towards the
Funding formulae for further education are also targets, are actually aged 16–18 (NIESR, 2004).
fine-tuned regularly to give colleges an incentive to There is also considerable anecdotal evidence that
help meet particular high-profile targets (currently, students who wish to work towards GCSEs in maths
those for adult basic skills and for adult level-2 or English are being entered for basic skills tests at
qualifications). These incentives are likely to be level 2 without the college bending over itself to point
very effective, given the sector’s chronic financial out the consequence, which is that they will have
problems, but they also give colleges a strong incen- then ‘used up’ their current entitlement to one free
tive to direct potential students who might be able to level-2 qualification and must pay for their GCSE
undertake harder courses towards easier ones which course. From the government’s point of view, such
lead to the relevant types of qualification, and, within students have helped meet two targets (basic skills
a Qualification Framework level, to provide courses and level 2); from the college’s, they have been
which it will be easy for students to pass. enrolled on high-earning courses; but level-2 basic
skills and GCSE are only notionally equivalent, and
The problems which this approach can generate are their labour-market values, as well as their substan-
especially evident at present in the area of adult tive content, are far apart (Wolf and Jenkins, 2002;
basic skills. Poor performance by British adults on Smith, 2004).
the ‘International Adult Literacy Survey’ (OECD,
1995) sparked a major inquiry and the ‘Skills for Distorting effects such as these are by now well
Life’ initiative to improve adult skills. The strategy’s documented in a range of public-sector contexts and
dominant rationale is again economic: to increase increasingly well understood (see, especially, Power,
individuals’ incomes but also because ‘employ- 1997; Hanushek et al., 2002; Le Grand 2003). As
ers . . . cannot compete in a . . . knowledge-based Charles Goodhart pointed out some years back, any
economy without a workforce able to add real value measure used for control purposes becomes unre-
at every level’ (DfES, 2001, p. 8).12 Extra money liable; so if qualifications are used for monitoring and
has poured into the programme which is driven by funding, it is overwhelmingly likely that they will, in
the target of ‘improving the basic skills of 1.8 million the process, become less reliable as sources of
adults between 2001 and 2007, with an intermediate information on their holders’ skills.
target of 750,000 by 2004’.
However, targets are by no means unique to the
In practice, this is a target for numbers passing education sector; so do they really have anything to
multiple-choice basic skills tests (which test reading do with the simplistic view of growth and education
and numeracy but not writing). The tests double up criticized here? I would argue that they do. That
as ‘key skills’ tests for 16–18-year-olds, in which view is an important reason why key education
guise they also attract high levels of (qualification- targets are simple quantities (levels of qualification,
related) funding and are part of the study pro- years in education), and why politicians believe that
gramme of many 16–18-year-old students. The a continual ratcheting up of target numbers will bring
Learning and Skills Council, which funds all post-16 continued benefits.
programmes, logically enough treats all candidates
alike in its record-keeping—they are, after all, tak- In its most straightforward form, the basic equation
ing the same tests.13 of orthodox growth theory posits that levels of

11
The Treasury’s flagship programme of Employer Training Pilots also ties funding to acquisition of formal level-2 qualifications,
reflecting the same conviction that this guarantees both relevant outputs and accountability; while intermediaries such as the Union
Learning Fund, which receives money to encourage workplace learning, also lay down specific targets for providers, including
qualification numbers.
12
The document also includes estimates of just how much money UK industry loses every year from workers’ poor skills. See
Ananiadou et al. (2003) for a discussion of these figures’ origin and robustness.
13
Anyone over 16 taking maths or English GCSE is also counted. As one Learning and Skills Council official observed, this was
a target ‘doomed to succeed’.

329
OXFORD REVIEW OF ECONOMIC POLICY, VOL. 20, NO. 2

output can be explained by levels of certain key generated simplistic policies with substantial delete-
inputs, and raising the quantity of any one of those rious effects. How might matters be improved?
will (other things being equal) raise total output:
One important need is for policy-makers simply to
Q = f (K, L, A, t), understand economic theory and evidence better.
They need, for example, to understand that quality
where Q = total real output, K = total real capital matters; that economists use years of education in
stock, L = total labour force employed, A = total land much of their work simply because it is the best
in use, and t is time. proxy available; but that if chasing quantity reduces
quality, societies can actually end up worse off than
Of course, the equation can be and has been before in terms of the human-capital formation they
amended (notably, in this context, to take account of seek. They might also remember that the growth
labour-force quality and technical progress). None literature of the 1960s, from which they (often unwit-
the less, it has also been enormously seductive in this tingly) draw inspiration, also emphasized the impor-
basic form, because it seems so simple and power- tance of technical progress: something which de-
ful. Scott (1989, 1998), for example, makes this point pends critically on pockets of university and research
forcibly, arguing that enormous expectations have excellence rather than mass uniform provision.16
been loaded on to this one function,14 and that the way
it is expressed encourages people to equate growth Most of all, governments need to abandon their love
with the accumulating of discrete inputs, when, in fact, affair with quantitative targets. This, however, will
growth and prosperity are deeply dependent not just on be hard to achieve. These targets provide central
quantities, but on how things are combined, and control in an apparently simple and clear way which
rearranged, and interact. Most politicians do not other policy levers cannot emulate. Contemporary
think of themselves as economists, but they do politicians, the world over, are highly enamoured of
respond to apparently straightforward ideas and education policy because it seems to offer a tool for
policies which they can implement, from the centre, delivering prosperity, in an age when this is expected
in a top-down, cumulative way. In the 1950s, it was of governments, and when their repertoire of plau-
capital investment which politicians the world over sible instruments is limited. Expanding education
tried to encourage and accumulate; today it is labour has the enormous advantage, moreover, that it is
inputs, but the same mind-set prevails. politically almost cost-free. Everyone believes edu-
cation is a good thing; and there are no interest
If you believe that growth is achieved by increasing groups who will be visibly harmed by expansion, or
the volume of different inputs, then, as a govern- will mobilize in opposition. Nor is there likely to be
ment, you are led inexorably towards a centralized, clear evidence in the short term of failure or suc-
target-setting approach to education. A logical out- cess, other than reaching the targets themselves,
come is the setting of qualification targets, which which is seen as self-evidently desirable.
can be monitored, counted, classified, and projected
forward far more precisely than unaccredited learn- So weaning politicians away from education targets
ing with no clear audit trails. British further educa- may be hard. The best hope, ironically, lies in the
tion clearly demonstrates the result.15 financial crises which expansion itself generates.
As Barr (this issue) describes, the effects of univer-
sity expansion, financially and in their impact on
V. CONCLUSIONS quality, have forced reforms which make students
responsible for an increased part of their costs, and
The current political consensus concerning educa- in the process will increase the importance of
tion’s contribution to economic performance has student preferences over central planners’ deci-
14
‘An apparent advantage of [this equation] is that it explains both the level of output at any given time and changes in that
level from one time to another. I question this quite staggering claim’ (Scott, 1998, p. 74, italics original).
15
Higher education offers plenty of other examples of these effects. The pursuit of student numbers, and the subconscious
equating of years enrolled and formal diplomas with substantive skills acquired is, not surprisingly, associated with a 20-year period
when per-student funding halved while the average number of ‘contact hours’ for students declined and class sizes increased.
16
I am indebted to Dieter Helm for making the point.

330
A. Wolf

sions. There is no reason in principle why other post- realistic about its demands, than central government
compulsory students, in further education and adult can ever be. Education is not only about economic
provision, should not operate under the same policy performance , but it does have a vital contribution to
regime; indeed, in financial terms, this would in- make. It is far more likely to achieve its economic
crease the equity of the UK system overnight. potential the more decisions are spread among those
for whom quality matters, directly, rather than lodged
Students and their parents are far closer to the with those whose major incentive is to deliver the
relevant parts of the labour market, and far more numbers.

REFERENCES

Aldrich, R. (ed.) (2002), A Century of Education London, Routledge-Falmer.


Alpin, C., Shackleton, J. R., and Walsh, S. (1998), ‘Over- and Undereducation in the UK Graduate Labour Market’,
Studies in Higher Education, 23(1), 17–34.
Ananiadou, K., Jenkins, A., and Wolf, A. (2003), The Benefits to Employers of Raising Workplace Skill Levels: A
Review of the Literature, London, National Research and Development Centre for Adult Literacy and
Numeracy.
Ashton, D., and Green, F. (1996), Education, Training and the Global Economy, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.
Audretsch, D., Kehmann, E., and Warning, S. (2003), ‘University Spillovers: Strategic Location and New Firm
Performance’, Centre for Economic Policy Research Discussion Paper 3837.
Barnett, C. (1986), The Audit of War: The Illusion and Reality of Britain as a Great Nation, London, Macmillan.
Becker, G. (1964), Human Capital, University of Chicago Press.
— (1993), Human Capital, University of Chicago Press, 3rd edn.
Benhabib, J., and Spiegel, M. (1994), ‘The Role of Human Capital in Economic Development: Evidence from Aggregate
Cross-country Data’, Journal of Monetary Economics, 34(14), 143–74.
Bils, M., and Klenow, P. J. (1998), Does Schooling Cause Growth or the Other Way Around?, Working Paper 6963,
Boston, MA, National Bureau of Economic Research.
Blundell, R., Dearden, L., and Sianesi, B. (2003), ‘Evaluating the Impact of Education on Earnings in the UK: Models,
Methods and Results from the NCDS’, Institute of Fiscal Studies Working Paper WO3/20.
Blunkett, D. (2000), ‘Modernising Higher Education—Facing the Global Challenge’, speech delivered at the University
of Greenwich, London, Department for Education and Employment, February.
Brown, G., and George, E. (2002), ‘A Lesson in Development’, Financial Times, 18 June.
Brown, P., Green, A., and Lauder, H. (eds) (2001), High Skills—Globalisation, Competitiveness, and Skill Formation,
Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Cameron, S. V., and Heckman, J. J. (1993), ‘Determinants of Young Male Schooling and Training Choices’, NBER
Working Papers 4327, National Bureau of Economic Research.
CBI (1989), Towards a Skills Revolution—A Youth Charter, interim report of the Vocational Education and Training
Task Force, London, Confederation of British Industry.
— (1991), World Class Targets, London, Confederation of British Industry.
— (1994), Thinking Ahead: Ensuring the Expansion of Higher Education into the 21st Century, London,
Confederation of British Industry.
CIHE (2003), The Impact of Higher Education, London, Council for Industry and Higher Education.
Collins, R. (1979), The Credential Society, New York, Academic Press.
Crouch, C., Finegold, D., and Sako, M. (1999), Are Skills the Answer? The Political Economy of Skill Creation in
Advanced Industrial Countries, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Culpepper, P. D. (1999), ‘The Future of the High Skill Equilibrium in Germany’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 15(1),
43–59.
Dearden, L., McIntosh, S., Myck, M., and Vignoles, A. (2002), ‘The Returns to Academic, Vocational and Basic Skills
in Britain’, Bulletin of Economic Research, 54, 249–74.
Denison, E. F. (1962), ‘How to Raise the High-employment Growth Rate by One Percentage Point’, American Economic
Review Papers and Proceedings, May.

331
OXFORD REVIEW OF ECONOMIC POLICY, VOL. 20, NO. 2

Denison, E. F. (1964), ‘Measuring the Contribution of Education (and the Residual) to Economic Growth’, in OECD
Study Group, The Residual Factor and Economic Growth, Paris, Organization for Economic Cooperation and
Development, 13–55.
DES (1991), Education and Training for the 21st Century, London, Department for Education and Science.
DfES (2001), Skills for Life. The National Strategy for Improving Adult literacy and Numeracy Skills, London,
Department for Education and Skills.
— (2003), 21st Century Skills: Realising Our Potential, London, Department for Education and Skills.
— (2004), Memorandum to the Education and Skills Select Committee on 14–19 Education and Training,
London, Department for Education and Skills.
Dolton, P., and Vignoles, A. (2000), ‘The Pay-off to Mathematics A Level’, in C. Tikly and A. Wolf (eds), The Maths
We Need Now: Demands, Deficits and Remedies, London, Institute of Education.
Dore, R. (1976), The Diploma Disease: Education, Qualification and Development, London, George Allen & Unwin.
— (1997), The Diploma Disease: Education Qualification and Development, 2nd edn, London, Institute of
Education.
— (2000), Stock Market Capitalism. Welfare Capitalism: Japan and Germany versus the Anglo-Saxons, Oxford,
Oxford University Press.
Felstead, A, Gallie, D., and Green, F. (2002), Work Skills in Britain 1986–2001, DfES/SKOPE.
Finegold, D., and Soskice, D. (1988), ‘The Failure of Training in Britain: Analysis and Prescription’, Oxford Review of
Economic Policy, 4(3), 21–53.
Fitzgerald, G. (2004), ‘Why Do the English Fail to See the Real Worth of Study?’, Times Higher Education Supplement,
13 February.
Frank, R., and Cook, P. (1995), The Winner-Take-All Society, New York, The Free Press.
Glewwe, P. (1996), ‘The Relevance of Standard Estimates of Rates of Return to Schooling for Education Policy: A Critical
Assessment’, Journal of Development Economics, 51, 267–90.
Griliches, Z. (1997), ‘Education, Human Capital and Growth: A Personal Perspective’, Journal of Labor Economics,
15, S330–42.
Hanushek, E., Heckman, J., and Neal, D. (eds) (2002), ‘Designing Incentives to Promote Human Capital’, The Journal
of Human Resources, 37(4), special issue.
Hoyles, C., Wolf, A., Molyneux-Hodgson, S., and Kent, P. (2002), Mathematical Skills in the Workplace, Final Report
to the Science, Technology and Mathematics Council.
Jenkins, A., and Wolf, A. (forthcoming), ‘Employers’ Selection Decisions: The Role of Qualifications and Tests’, in
S. Machin and A. Vignoles (eds), The Economics of Education and Education Policy in the UK, Princeton,
NJ, Princeton University Press.
Jones, P. (2001), ‘Are Educated Workers Really More Productive?’, Journal of Development Economics, 64(1), 57–
79.
Kay, J. (1993), Foundations of Corporate Success, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Krueger, A., and Lindhal, M. (1999), ‘Education for Growth in Sweden and the World’, NBER Working Paper 7190,
National Bureau of Economic Research.
Lau, L., Jamison, D., and Louat, F. C. (1991), Education and Productivity in Developing Countries: An Aggregate
Production Function Approach, Washington, DC, World Bank.
Le Grand, J. (2003), Motivation, Agency and Public Policy: Of Knights and Knaves, Pawns and Queens, Oxford, Oxford
University Press.
Little, A. (ed.) (1997), ‘The Diploma Disease’, Assessment in Education, 4(1) (special issue).
Lopez, R., Vinod, T., Wang, Y. (1998), ‘Addressing the Education Puzzle: The Distribution of Education and Economic
Reform’, Policy Research Working Paper 2031, Washington, DC, World Bank.
Mager, C., Robinson, P., Fletcher, M., Stanton, G., Perry, A., and Westwood, A. (2000), The New Learning Market,
London, Further Education Development Agency.
Meghir, C., and Palme, M. (1999), ‘Assessing the Effect of Schooling on Earnings Using a Social Experiment’, Stockholm
School of Economics Working Paper 313.
Murnane, R. J., Willett, J. B., and Levy, F. (1995), ‘The Growing Importance of Cognitive Skills in Wage Determination’,
Review of Economics and Statistics, 77, 251–66.
— — Tyler, J. H. (1999), ‘Who Benefits from Obtaining a GED? Evidence from High School and Beyond’, Working
Paper Series 7172, Cambridge, MA, National Bureau of Economic Research.
Murphy, J. (1993), ‘A Degree of Waste’, Oxford Review of Education, 19, 9–31.
National Commission on Excellence in Education (1983), A Nation at Risk, Washington, DC, US Department of
Education.

332
A. Wolf

National Skills Task Force (2000), Skills for All: Proposals for a National Skills Agenda, London, Department for
Education and Employment.
NIESR (2004), Evaluation of the Basic Skills Programme: First Report, London, National Institute of Economic and
Social Research.
OECD (1964), The Residual Factor and Economic Growth, Paris, Organization for Economic Cooperation and
Development.
— (1995), Literacy, Economy and Society: Results of the First International Adult Literacy Survey, Paris,
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development.
— (2001), Knowledge and Skills for Life: First Results of the OECD Programme for International Student
Assessment (PISA), Paris, Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development.
Owen, G. (1999), From Empire to Europe: The Decline and Revival of British Industry since the Second World War,
London, Harper Collins.
Porter, M. J., Hirotaka, T., and Mariko, S. (2000), Can Japan Compete?, Basingstoke, Macmillan.
Power, M. (1997), The Audit Society, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Pritchett, L. (1996), ‘Where Has All the Education Gone?’, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 1581,
Washington, DC, World Bank.
Psacharopoulos, G. (1985), ‘Returns to Education: A Further International Update and Implications’, Journal of Human
Resources, 20 (4).
Robinson, P. (1999), ‘Learning from Comparing: New Directions in Comparative Educational Research’, in R. Alexander,
P. Broadfoot, and D. Phillips (eds), Learning from Comparing: New Directions in Comparative Educational
Research, Vol. 1, Contexts, Classrooms and Outcomes, Oxford, Symposium.
Ruddock, G. (2000), Third International Maths and Science Study Repeat (TIMSS-R): First National Report,
Department for Employment and Education.
Scott, M. F. (1989, 1998), A New View of Economic Growth, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Sianesi, B. (2003), ‘Returns to Education: A Non-technical Summary and Policy Discussion’, Institute for Fiscal Studies,
mimeo.
— Van Reenan, J. (2000), ‘The Returns to Education: A Review of the Macro-economic Literature’, Discussion
Paper No. 6, London, London School of Economics and Political Science, Centre for the Economics of Education.
Smith, A. (2004), Making Mathematics Count: The Report of the Post-14 Mathematics Inquiry, London, Department
for Education and Skills.
Soskice, D. (1994), ‘Reconciling Markets and Institutions: The German Apprenticeship System’, in L. Lynch (ed.),
Training and the Private Sector, Chicago, IL, University of Chicago Press.
Spence, A. M. (1973), ‘Job Market Signaling’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2(3), 355–74.
Stanton, G. (1996), Output-Related Funding and the Quality of Education and Training, London, ICRA, Institute
of Education.
Stevens, M. (1999), ‘Human Capital Theory and UK Vocational Training Policy’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy,
15(1), 16–32.
Stevens, R. (2004), University to Uni: The Politic of Higher Education in England since 1944, London, Politico’s.
Temple, J. (2001), ‘Growth Effects of Education and Social Capital in OECD Countries’, OECD Economic Studies,
Summer.
Thomas, V., and Wang, Y. (1996), ‘Distortions, Interventions and Productivity Growth: Is East Asia Different?’,
Economic Development and Cultural Change, 44(2), 265–88.
Vaizey, J. (1962), The Economics of Education, London, Faber.
Weiss, A. (1984), ‘Determinants of Quit Behavior’, Journal of Labor Economics, 2(3), 371–87.
Wolf, A. (1997), ‘Growth Stocks and Lemons: Diplomas in the English Market-place 1976–1996’, Assessment in
Education, 4(1), 33–49.
— (2002a), Does Education Matter? Myths about Education and Economic Growth, London, Penguin Press.
— (2002b), ‘Qualifications and Assessment’, in R. Aldrich (ed.), A Century of Education, London, Routledge-
Falmer.
— Jenkins, A. (2002), ‘The Growth of Psychometric Testing for Selection. Why has Test Use Increased, Will
Growth Continue, and What does this Mean for Education?’, CEE Discussion Paper No. 29, London, Centre
for the Economics of Education.

333

Вам также может понравиться