Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 25

Corporate Law and the

Sovereignty of States
Jason Kaufman
Harvard University

This article explores the origins of a social form with lasting and profound sociological
implications: the corporation. Though corporations date back as far as the Roman
Republic, the early United States fostered a significant transformation in corporate law.
Shortly after the American Revolution, several states pioneered a system whereby
corporate charters became available to almost anyone (at a price), leading (eventually)
to a proliferation of corporate charters unlike anything ever seen before in world history.
This proliferation of corporate charters first occurred in colonies that were originally
chartered as corporations: Massachusetts, Connecticut, and Rhode Island, all of which
used the corporate organizational form for a wide array of social pursuits. These
colonies also experienced repeated conflict with the Crown over the rights and privileges
of corporations. As American “states,” they built on these experiences to liberalize access
to the means of incorporation and to elucidate the rights and freedoms of corporations.
Other studies aptly document the diffusion of the corporate organizational form after
1800; this article takes up the antecedents to the use and popularity of the modern
corporate organizational form. These observations do not supersede scholarly work
regarding the economic origins of the American business corporation, but they do shed
valuable light on the interdependence of states and markets, as well as the nature of
institutional-legal transformation more generally.

INTRODUCTION of the corporation as part of a larger shift in


modern social relations, a shift toward an “asym-
he rise of the corporate organizational form
T has long been regarded as one of the defin-
ing innovations of the modern era. Most schol-
metric society” where corporations dwarf both
individuals and society.
Private corporations are “legal persons” enti-
ars agree that it marks a critical shift in the tled to do things ordinary individuals cannot,
relation of capital to enterprise and enterprise particularly when it comes to matters of finan-
to labor (e.g., Berle and Means 1932; Chandler cial management and legal accountability. Under
1962; Hurst 1970; Perrow 2002; Roy 1997). common law, corporations have “perpetual suc-
Coleman (1982) goes so far as to portray the rise cession”: they exist beyond the lives of their

Direct all correspondence to Jason Kaufman, 648 Fund of Harvard University. Invaluable research
William James Hall, 33 Kirkland St., Cambridge, assistance was provided by Marco Gonzalez, Jacob
MA 02138 (jkaufman@wjh.harvard.edu). The Model, and Michael Nguyen. I also thank partici-
author is grateful for advice and support from Bruce pants in colloquia held by the Charles Warren Center
Carruthers, Lis Clemens, Chris DeSan, Frank for American History, the Weatherhead Center for
Dobbin, Coleen Dunlavy, Hendrik Hartog, Stan International Affairs, and the Center for American
Katz, Fred Konefsky, Ken Mack, Pauline Maier, Political Studies (CAPS) at Harvard University, the
Bill Novak, Joel Podolny, Robert Steinfeld, Alan Sociology Department of the University of
Taylor, Kathleen Thelen, Chuck Tilly, and the anony- Wisconsin-Madison, the Centre for American
mous reviewers of the ASR. This research was fund- Studies at the University of Western Ontario, and the
ed in part by a grant from the William F. Milton American Sociological Association.

AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW, 2008, VOL. 73 (June:402–425)


CORPORATE LAW AND THE SOVEREIGNTY OF STATES—–403

founding members. Corporate assets are legally York, and Pennsylvania are especially useful, so
protected from both shareholders and creditors I examine these states in some detail. Second,
in many cases, thus creating a legal shield the article contributes quantitative data on rates
between corporate actors and corporate respon- and purposes of interstate incorporation. Third,
sibilities. In the contemporary context, corporate it corrects a general tendency in the literature on
assets are also subject to different taxation and the history of the common law corporation to
regulation schemes than unincorporated busi- ignore some of the seminal conditions under-
nesses. The private, legal corporate form has lying the transformation of the corporation and
evolved as a powerful tool for the growth and the role of emerging polities therein. A detailed
management of capital by providing incorporat- examination of this transformation sheds new
ed organizations legal rights and protections not light on the general relationship between the
otherwise afforded to unincorporated ventures.
sovereignty of states and the construction of
The legal structure of the modern corporate
economic entities. This article also uses neo-
form derives from efforts in medieval Europe to
institutionalist theory to explain how long-term
grant legal autonomy to universities, towns, and
exposure to and conflict over an ambiguously
ecclesiastical institutions. Trade guilds and com-
mercial monopolies were also granted corporate defined organizational form has promoted its
status in special circumstances. Even the earli- widespread use following the political emanci-
est corporations thus represent the delegation of pation of those American colonies most expe-
state authority to subsidiary entities, a form of rienced with that form.
power-sharing that raised questions about the This article does not aim to contradict the
extent and limit of the powers of both the incor- wide and well-respected literatures on either
porator and the incorporated. the economic or organizational imperatives
The ease of acquiring a corporate charter is underlying the emergence of the modern cor-
one key example of the transformation of the porate organizational form or the diffusion of
corporation in the United States. Until the late that form in the mid- to late-nineteenth centu-
nineteenth century, legal restrictions on the ry (e.g., Chandler 1977; Coleman 1982;
issuance of corporate charters were the norm Creighton 1990; Evans 1948; Handlin and
under English common law, particularly after the Handlin 1945; Hartog 1983; Perrow 2002; Roy
Bubble Act of 1720 reaffirmed the need for 1997). Instead, I focus on the important, and
businesses to secure a charter of incorporation often overlooked, period before the corpora-
from the Crown before issuing transferable tion became a primary vehicle of American
shares of ownership (DuBois 1938). “To be a economic and civic action. I demonstrate that
corporation was a special privilege, not an inher- the proliferation of the corporate form in the
ent right of individuals,” notes business histo- early United States was related to those states’
rian Joseph S. Davis (1917: I, 5–6). Following colonial experiences with the corporate organi-
the American Revolution, however, the United zational form. I argue that familiarity and expe-
States dramatically transformed this common
rience with the corporate organizational form on
law conception of restricted access to the means
the part of colonial legislators, attorneys, and
of incorporation. By opening access to incor-
ordinary citizens encouraged its continued use
poration and helping to spread the organiza-
during the postcolonial period. In the early post-
tional form, these states catalyzed wider
transformations in the legal and organizational Revolutionary period, the specific utility of the
structure of the American cor poration. corporation was less clear than its institutional
Following an early period in which a relatively accessibility. Notably, the corporate organiza-
undifferentiated corporate organizational form tional form soon morphed from a relatively
was used for a wide variety of purposes, inno- ambiguous form of social organization to a vari-
vations were made in the specificity of and ety of legally- and organizationally-specific
access to corporate charters. uses. During this period, both states and cor-
The contributions of this article are three- porations struggled to define state authority
fold. First, I elucidate the role of the corpora- over corporate rights. Such instances of insti-
tion in the colonial United States. The cases of tutional differentiation and legal reform merit
Massachusetts, Rhode Island, Connecticut, New serious sociological attention.
404—–AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

BACKGROUND responses to perceived crises in the railway


industry. Fligstein (2001:19) writes, “If pro-
RIVAL EXPLANATIONS OF THE ORIGINS OF ducing stability in multiple markets requires
THE MODERN PRIVATE CORPORATION rules, then governments are deeply implicated
Economic historians have found that many early in defining the various social structures that
Americans were wary of adopting the corporate stabilize markets,” thus emphasizing stabiliza-
organizational form for business purposes. Prior tion as a post hoc effort to introduce a desired
to the mid-nineteenth century, the legal advan- condition. Seavoy (1982:xii, emphasis added)
tages of incorporation were unclear—limited explicitly states that liberal incorporation laws
liability was not yet a standard benefit of incor- were the product of an American political sys-
poration, for example. The fear that corporations tem that was “highly responsive to the needs of
might be profligate with their funds offset any major interest groups and to the aspirations of
other would-be benefits. Creditors were much its citizens.”
more likely to invest in family-owned busi- I will argue here that several post-
nesses because families could be better trusted Revolutionary state legislatures forged a radi-
to take a long-term view of a business cal new path in the legal regulation of
(Lamoreaux 1997; McGouldrick 1968). This incorporation activity not (or not only) because
challenges the prevailing belief among econo- they saw it as the most efficient means of
mists that the corporate organizational form encouraging industry—some argued, in fact,
originally rose to prominence (in the United that private corporations were the most ineffi-
States) out of the necessities of the marketplace cient means of doing so—but, in part, as a result
(cf. Paskoff 1983). This does not negate argu- of those states’ own origins as private corpora-
ments about its subsequent evolution as a valu- tions, as well as royal efforts to limit their pow-
able tool for economic activity (cf. Chandler ers as such. As I will show, the majority of
1962; Coase 1937; North 1990; Williamson private corporations chartered between 1780
1981), but it does render a need to examine and 1810 were not business concerns at all;
more carefully the noneconomic origins of the they were churches, townships, schools, and
early American corporation. voluntary organizations.
Sociologists, too, have worked hard to uncov- I also challenge the argument that the specific
er the social dimensions of economic markets cultural background of the early American
and corporate behavior. The historical devel- Puritans predisposed American society toward
opment of various schemes for organizing pro- its particular form of market organization. Innes
duction, consumption, and exchange have been (1995) suggests, for example, that the Puritans’
focal points for scholars working in this field belief in the Protestant Ethic predisposed them
(e.g., Adams 2005; Campbell and Lindberg not only to value commerce and the accumula-
1990; Carruthers 1996; Coleman 1982; Dobbin tion of capital but also to see monopolies as
1994; Erikson and Bearman 2006; Evans 1995; inimical to the public interest. In turn, this cul-
Fligstein 1990; Mintz and Schwartz 1985; tural background supported the uniquely
Mizruchi 1982; Roy 1997; Zelizer 1994). American version of neoliberal capitalism extant
Nonetheless, despite their insistence that mar- today. Indeed, English Puritans founded three
ket norms and regulations are more a product early American business centers: Massachusetts,
of institutional and cultural schemas than organi- Connecticut, and Rhode Island. But if the cul-
zational efficiency, economic sociologists often tural preferences of the Puritans were respon-
share with economists the view that the gov- sible for this outcome, then why did Puritan
ernment generally intervenes in the economy in ventures in other parts of British North America,
response to the perceived needs of the market- such as Providence Island in the West Indies, fail
place. In other words, while economists and to found similar cultures of capitalism?
economic sociologists differ about the motives Though it runs counter to his own cultural-
for government action, they both see such action ist argument, Innes (1995:206–07) provides a
as a largely reactive and economically motivat- telling answer to this question: the
ed process (cf. Biernacki 2005). Dobbin (1994), Massachusetts Bay Colony was erected on a
for example, sees railway regulation in the unique legal basis, as were its offshoots,
United States, France, and Britain as a series of Connecticut and Rhode Island. All three were
CORPORATE LAW AND THE SOVEREIGNTY OF STATES—–405

originally chartered as private corporations. All relationship between incorporator and incor-
three also faced long periods of uncertainty porated. One might refer to variance in the abil-
with regard to their legitimacy and rights as ity of different types of social actors to gain
corporations. As a result of these struggles, lib- corporate charters as differences in their rela-
eral incorporation policies evolved in these tionship to the means of incorporation (pace
colonies that encouraged further experimenta- Marx). As Americans’ relationship to the means
tion with the corporate organizational form. of incorporation changed, subsequent revisions
were made to the substance of the law of cor-
CONTRIBUTION TO EXISTING porations, not vice versa.
KNOWLEDGE Because the relational structure of the cor-
poration (i.e., access to the means of incorpo-
Law and legal development have long been ration) was fundamental to the revolutionary
focal points of inquiry in economic sociology. project of protecting legislative autonomy, we
As mentioned earlier, economists and economic thereby see an important connection between
sociologists share a tendency to see state action struggles over political autonomy and the trans-
as a response to market factors. This explo- formation of Americans’ relationship to the
ration of the colonial origins of American cor- state via corporate law. It is impossible to know
porate law demonstrates the need to consider the exactly why legislators in these states persisted
institutional development of states and eco- in their positive opinion of corporations in the
nomic entities in tandem. Historian Charles face of prior difficulties chartering them. Indeed,
Andrews (1934: I, 43) wrote, “The colonial ambiguous language in early American charters,
governments in New England represent the sys- coupled with legal ambiguity over the relative
tem of a trading company applied to the polit- power of colonial and imperial legislatures to
ical organization of a state.” This observation is issue such charters, made the corporation an
consistent with recent work by sociologists institution subject to revision and dispute
regarding the sociopolitical organization of mar- (Clemens 1997; Clemens and Cook 1999;
kets and economic entities (e.g., Adams 2005; Friedland and Alford 1991; Meyer and Rowan
Carruthers 1996; Chibber 2003; Dobbin 1994; 1977). Perhaps a long history of exposure to and
Erikson and Bearman 2006; Evans 1995; familiarity with the corporate organizational
Fligstein 1990; Perrow 2002; Roy 1997). form predisposed New England attorneys and
Understanding the history of incorporation entrepreneurs to consider the corporation a valu-
and corporate law is key to understanding the able means of establishing new enterprises.
relationship between the state and the public and Furthermore, it is not uncommon for people to
private spheres. Economic sociologists see cor- put heightened value on those privileges open-
porate law as a product of firms’ struggles to ly denied them. In tracing the trajectory of such
survive in the face of competition: most states denials and colonial responses, I argue that
face exactly the same challenge. The struggle of repeated conflict over the role of the corpora-
the American colonies to survive as corporate tion in the colonies led this legal-institutional
entities gave birth to the idea that such a right form, once severely restricted in its dispersion,
should be readily attainable. This is not meant to be transformed into a widely accessible, often
to suggest that economic entities are solely the used legal tool in the early decades of the
product of states but to illustrate the potential Republic. This is not an inevitable outcome,
for institutional practices in one sphere to bleed only the outcome of these specific circum-
into or transform those in other spheres (e.g., stances. Nonetheless, these cases do point more
Clemens and Cook 1999; DiMaggio and Powell generally to the importance of seeing state for-
1983; Friedland and Alford 1991; cf. Huntington mation, legal development, economic develop-
1968). ment, and associational/civic development as
One generalizable observation we can make mutually constitutive processes. In each case, we
about this process regards the nature of legal see organizational actors looking for legitimate
change. In this case, and presumably others, means of establishment as “legal fictions” with
American corporate law was not transformed by competitive advantage over similar entities. The
an original intent to change its substance but American move to decouple the right of incor-
through changes to its relational structure, or the poration from state purview is significant in
406—–AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

world-historical terms, as it establishes the and long-standing differences between the two
increasingly global precedent of “freedom of countries’ concepts of the corporation exist to
incorporation.” this day (Karsten 2002; Kaufman forthcoming).
In more abstract terms, one might describe
this process as an example of what Thelen ANALYSIS
(2003:225) calls “institutional layering,” or “the
partial renegotiation of some elements of a CATALYST: COLONIAL AMERICAN
given set of institutions while leaving others in STRUGGLES OVER THE NATURE AND RIGHTS
place.” The content of the American corporation OF CORPORATIONS
changed much more slowly than did its rela-
tional structure. Carruthers and Halliday (1998) The oldest “continually operating” corporation
might refer to this process of change as an illus- in North America is the President and Fellows
tration of “law’s recursive loop,” or the manner of Harvard College.2 Though founded in 1636,
in which new legal doctrines form without con- Harvard College did not become a corporation
scious design but are instead post hoc respons- until 1650, at which time it was granted a num-
es to social and legal conditions that change ber of rights, privileges, and immunities not
and cumulate over time. Changes in the content otherwise available to educational institutions.
of the corporation do not appear to have been The Harvard College corporation now had “per-
a concern of those who originally transformed petual succession,” or the right to pass itself
its relational structure. Instead, U.S. courts made from one set of administrators to another, thus
these post hoc changes to bring American legal guaranteeing that the institution would outlive
standards up to speed with the new competitive its founders. The charter also established the
climate of corporate activity in the mid-nine- College’s right to buy and sell property, “sue and
teenth century. plead or be sued and impleaded,” and choose
One key circumstance that contributed to this “officers and servants.” The colonial legisla-
process was the decision of legislatures in post- ture granted the College and its staff some
Revolutionary America not to adopt English exemption from “taxes and rates,” as well as “all
statutory law. Instead, they declared themselves personall ciuill offices militarie exercises or
free to adopt pieces of English law while retain- seruices watchings and wardings.”3 A few years
ing the power to modify or ignore them as they later, following a brawl between Harvard stu-
wished (Brown 1964; Nelson 1994).1 A suc- dents and Cambridge residents, it was decided
cessful jurisdictional break from England afford- that local law enforcement officials would have
ed American state legislatures a novel only limited power on campus, thus establish-
opportunity to reinstitutionalize their sociolegal ing the precedent of campus police and internal
conception of the corporation. The common discipline in all but the most extreme cases
law countries of the British Commonwealth (Morison 1936:24–25).
retained the traditional conception of the cor- The incorporation of the College was not
poration until late in the nineteenth century, unusual under English law. Universities had
long been considered private concerns worthy
of legal incorporation, thereby providing their
1 To be more precise, most of the new American members some means of conducting collegiate
states formally adopted English common law but affairs while assuring the “perpetual” life of
rejected English statutory law (Brown 1964; Horwitz the College. The Harvard charter is clearly mod-
1971). The distinction lies in the belief that common eled on that of medieval English universities.
law reflects timeless moral principles based on judi- What is noteworthy, however, is the circum-
cial interpretation of natural law, whereas statutory stance under which it was incorporated: where-
law reflects the specific dictates of the legislature. By as English corporations were chartered by the
the early nineteenth century, however, “the original
natural law foundation of common law rules began
to disintegrate” (Horwitz 1971:310). This led to the
“Americanization” of the common law, or the notion 2 Harvard is not the oldest corporation in America

that American judges can interpret law in light of the but the oldest corporation still in existence.
exigencies and needs of society, free of English legal 3 A copy of the charter is reprinted in Morison

precedent (Nelson 1994). (1936:5–8).


CORPORATE LAW AND THE SOVEREIGNTY OF STATES—–407

King with the consent of Parliament, the gov- A rival claim to the land granted to the
erning body that incorporated Harvard was a Massachusetts Bay Company also weakened
private corporation itself—the Governor and their charter. The land had previously been
Company of the Massachusetts Bay in New offered to a group called the Council for New
England, which received its own corporate char- England, which had established a corporation,
ter only 21 years earlier, on March 4, 1629. the Dorchester Company, to settle the area. The
It was common mercantilist policy for the Dorchester Company tried and failed to create
King to grant charters to private overseas trad- a series of fishing villages along the coast north
ing firms like the Massachusetts Bay Company. of Boston Harbor. Its legal representatives still
Normally, a group of English investors would argued for the continued validity of the
pool their capital, incorporate, and then make Dorchester Company’s claim, though, and they
arrangements to send hired colonists, or repeatedly tried to have the Massachusetts Bay
“merchant-adventurers,” abroad. This is how a charter revoked. Such wrangling over the legal
Spanish Company, a Turkey Company, and a validity of land grant charters was a common
Levant Company were founded. In British North feature of early American political geography
America, the Virginia Company, the Plymouth (Kaufman forthcoming).
Plantation, and a Caribbean venture called the The Massachusetts Bay Company charter
Providence Island Company were also char- was further threatened by English suspicions
tered in this way. None lasted long in this incar- about religious heresy in the colony. In 1633, a
nation, though, which is important because it is special Commission for Regulating Plantations
not only their founding as corporations but the (colloquially refer red to as the “Laud
colonies’ continued experiences with the cor- Commission,” after its head, William Laud,
porate organizational form that is key to the Bishop of London) investigated claims that the
institutional process studied here.4 colonists were religious extremists violating
Most British colonies were not founded as church policy. For a short time, the Laud
corporations, however. Much of British North Commission tried to restrict emigration to the
America was originally settled either as “royal colony. In July 1634, they went so far as to
colonies” (colonies under the direct jurisdic- demand that the company’s corporate charter be
tion and rule of the King in Parliament) or “pro- submitted to them for inspection (Bremer 2003).
prietary colonies” (colonies under the The Company’s response to the Laud
jurisdiction of specific patent-holders). Thus, the Commission’s request is significant, for it is a
first of the New England “corporate colonies,” landmark departure from both English colonial
the Massachusetts Bay Company, is an unusu- policy and corporate law. The governing coun-
al example. As famed English legal historian cil of the Massachusetts Bay Company resolved
Frederic Maitland (2003:42) notes, the nature “not to return any answer or excuse” to official
and experience of the New England colonies requests that they deliver their charter to
with the corporate organizational form is quite England for scrutiny. They forestalled a second
unique in common law history. In addition to its request by claiming that they could not do so
uniqueness, the Massachusetts Bay Company until the colony’s legislative assembly next met,
suffered 150 years of legal problems stemming several months hence. England responded by
from the manner under which it was incorpo- threatening to send a military envoy to seize the
rated. The legal representatives of the Massachusetts Bay Company charter by force.
Massachusetts Bay Company did not file their The colonists in turn built military fortifica-
charter application properly, rendering the char- tions in strategic locations around Boston
ter suspect. The malleability and ambiguity of Harbor, including a sentry post at Beacon Hill,
seventeenth-century English corporate law the current site of the Massachusetts State
allowed for this kind of experimentation, though House. Though no British convoy ever arrived
it also led to protracted legal battles over the to seize the charter, the very fact that the com-
intent and scope of the law. pany had refused to assent to royal orders was
a violation of the common law understanding of
corporate privilege (Handlin and Handlin
4 The spelling of all proper nouns has been changed 1969:93): corporations served “at the king’s
to match modern usage. pleasure,” meaning that special privileges were
408—–AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

granted them with the proviso that they would hazard, slapdash array of independent colonies
remain directly accountable to the King and and wayward settlements. Though the impetus
Parliament. for reform was felt throughout British North
The leaders of the Massachusetts Bay colony America, the New England colonies bore the
sought to resist such intrusions. They could do brunt of it.
so in part because they had taken the unusual The Massachusetts Bay Company officially
step of bringing their charter and corporate lost its corporate charter in 1684. For several
seal—a medallion used to stamp all official years, Massachusetts existed in legal limbo, as
corporation documents—with them across the did all subsidiary corporations associated with
Atlantic. As long as Massachusetts possessed it, including Harvard College. Where did this
the seal, it possessed de facto power to act as a leave New England’s already-chartered corpo-
corporation (Bremer 2003). This, coupled with rations, legally speaking?
the migration of a majority of the corporation’s Increase Mather, president of Harvard at the
officers to Massachusetts, meant that the colony time, sought to find out during a trip to England
and the corporation were now unified in a sin- in the spring of 1688. He was traveling as
gle place. “This removal was a fact of the great- ambassador for both the College and the
est importance not only in the history of New Company, their fates being legally and sym-
England,” writes historian Herbert Osgood bolically intertwined. Mather’s trip lasted three
(1896:505), “but in the development of modern years, during which time King James II was
governmental forms.” The New England deposed and William of Orange crowned in his
Puritans’ repatriation of their corporate seal place. Mather made repeated requests for royal
was a signal step in transforming the corporate resolution on the corporate powers of the New
organizational form from a simple legal privi- England colonies. “Answer was made,” writes
lege to the basis for an entire polity. Mather (1691:21), “that it should be so if I
Though the Massachusetts Bay Company desired it, but that a better way would be for the
managed to keep its charter (for the time being), General Court [i.e., legislative assembly] of the
its subsequent decision to charter a college Massachusetts Colony to incorporate their
brought new problems. Despite Massachusetts’s College, and to make it an University, with as
insistence that it had the right to charter a col- ample privileges as they should think neces-
lege, English law at the time clearly stated that sary.” The king in council was thus sending the
corporations could only be founded with offi- matter back to New England for action.
cial license from the King (Andrews 1934). The Unfortunately, this parry left New Englanders
Massachusetts Bay Company issued Harvard its in the lurch, for few believed that colonial char-
charter during a period of jurisdictional uncer- ters had the same force of law as those issued
tainty following the execution of Charles I. directly from England. As late as 1772, for
The American colonies were largely left example, the royal governor of Massachusetts,
alone, legally speaking, throughout the politi- Thomas Hutchinson, was asking the Lords of
cal turmoil of the English Civil War. Settlers Trade for resolution on this matter. As
from Massachusetts founded the new colonies Hutchinson rightly observed, there was nothing
of Connecticut and Rhode Island and success- in the bylaws of the colony stating whether
fully gained corporate charters for each, further royal or colonial charters held preeminence. He
extending the reach of this new conception of asked that the Massachusetts charter be revised
the corporation-as-political-organization. The “to abridge or restrain the Prerogative which is
Glorious Revolution brought new troubles for in the Crown of creating Corporations” and
the corporate colonies of New England, how- stressed that every time the colonial assembly
ever. In England, Puritans lost much of their pre- passed such acts, it only strengthened “the
vious political power, and the new regime sought exception that is taken to this part of the
to rein in its American subjects. This was a peri- Prerogative [i.e., royal monopoly over the power
od of great legal-jurisdictional uncertainty in to grant corporate charters]” (Davis 1917: I,
Britain: England was in transition to a new sys- 18). Governor Hutchinson was in fact correct.
tem of parliamentary rule under a new monarch, The Board of Trade clearly stated that
William of Orange. There was a concerted effort “Incorporation should arise from the bounty of
to “rationalize” what had previously been a hap- the Crown by letter patent, rather than by act of
CORPORATE LAW AND THE SOVEREIGNTY OF STATES—–409

[colonial] Assembly” (Davis 1917: I, 18). higher education founded in the colonial peri-
Enforcement of this policy was never consistent, od were chartered by the King in Parliament
however. Most colonial corporations were either rather than their respective colonial legislatures
overlooked or simply tolerated by royal author- (Baldwin 1898, 1901; Davis 1894). Interes-
ities. “Indeed, of the many [business charters] tingly, Yale’s overseers came to blows over a
that must have been passed upon,” writes Davis similar matter with the Connecticut General
(1917: I, 18), “only five seem to have been dis- Assembly nearly a century later, in 1784, when
allowed.” English legal authorities were not they challenged the state legislature’s self-pro-
doing much to prevent incorporation, though claimed right to “visitation” in response to com-
they were not encouraging it either. Other plaints about the lackluster state of affairs at Yale
colonies used corporations, but none as wide- (Dana 1784).
ly and passionately as New England, where the The illegal incorporation of Harvard College
corporation remained a cherished ideal for col- is relevant to the political development of the
lective governance. Massachusetts Bay colony in more ways than
On October 7, 1691, Massachusetts received one. The College was an important social proj-
the official seal of England, thus reestablishing ect to the Puritans, one meant to create an ample
the colony’s legal existence following the rev- supply of human and social capital in the colony.
ocation of its corporate charter. The seal came It resonated, too, with settlers’ general sensitivity
with the added proviso, though, that the King to issues of contract and title. Townships and
could now appoint a royal governor to oversee common lands were often created as corporate
affairs in the colony and all laws passed by the trusts (Private Statutes 1780–1800). In addition,
colonial legislature were subject to a royal veto a fair percentage of the colony’s leading doctors,
within three years of their passage. The King’s lawyers, preachers, teachers, politicians, and
changes to the Massachusetts Bay charter were businessmen would later be Harvard graduates.
an obvious blow to the colonists. Mather writes Many seventeenth-century New Englanders saw
at length about his struggles to preserve the the fate of the College as part and parcel of the
original charter, as well as his eventual realiza- long-term health of their colonies. They likely
tion that further resistance might goad the King passed such concerns on to their children, espe-
into rescinding colonial autonomy altogether. cially those who attended Harvard themselves.
Harvard’s struggles, moreover, were nowhere Their ideas about charter rights would also trav-
near over. The College’s charter was nullified by el with them across the country as New
the annulment of the original Massachusetts Englanders started migrating westward in search
Bay charter, and it had yet to be reinstated. of open land.
Speaking on behalf of Mather and the Fellows The College charter issue remained wholly
of the College, James Allen said (quoted in unresolved until 1707, when the Massachusetts
Morison 1936: II, 518; cf. Herbst 1982): General Court (i.e., the provincial legislature)
Harvard without a charter “will Indeed be no simply declared that the 1650 charter had never
Reall Colledge, but quickly come to be nothing been repealed or annulled, thereby reinstating it.
at all.” Hofstadter (1955:106) refers to this compro-
In May of 1692, Mather drafted a new char- mise as an “admission of the hitherto uncertain
ter creating a Harvard College corporation of 10 right of the [Massachusetts] General Court to
men with virtually unlimited control over the charter a college without sanction from the
affairs of the college. In July of 1696, word Crown.” As a result, the legal standing of the
arrived from England that the 1692 charter was College remained ambiguous until after the
being “disallowed” because it did not provide American Revolution, when the Massachusetts
the Crown the right to “visit” the college (i.e., state legislature promptly took action to confirm
oversee its affairs) (Morison 1936: II, 512, 517). the College’s charter (Maier 1992, 1993).
This issue of corporate freedom from royal (i.e., In point of fact, the legal power to grant cor-
state) oversight was key to the New England porations remained ambiguous throughout the
colonists. Colonial Massachusetts, Rhode colonies before Independence. Except in cases
Island, and Connecticut were unique in seeking where such powers were explicitly granted, “the
colonial, rather than royal, charters for their colonial assemblies which undertook to create
first universities—the other six institutions of corporations were forced to rely upon an implied
410—–AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

power so to act, and the question whether this Englanders behind them) when they had man-
implication was justified remained somewhat aged to function for so long without it? The
unsettled throughout nearly the entire colonial answer reveals much about American legal
period” (Davis 1917: I, 17). development. Under their original, common
Significantly, some colonial legislatures made law conception, corporations (partially) pro-
a concerted effort to hide acts of incorporation tected their members’ assets from creditors and
in language that avoided specific reference to lawsuits and also afforded investors a means of
incorporation itself. Connecticut’s Yale College, holding assets in perpetuity. Incorporation was
founded by Harvard alumni, took this route a “legal fiction” that placed a defensive shell
after noting the extensive difficulties Harvard around Americans’ assets, thus improving
faced in achieving incorporation. As Hofstadter investors’ chances of preserving and indeed
(1955:36) writes: building upon them. In England (and the rest of
The Connecticut clerics faced a dilemma. To get Europe), such privileges were hard to procure;
a charter from the legislature was to risk the total in Puritan New England, by contrast, they were
dissolution of the college, as the charter might part and parcel of government policy.
readily be voided by the Crown if the college As William Smith, a New York lawyer, wrote
received unfavorable attention; but to seek a royal in a 1767 letter (quoted in Shirley [1895]
charter was to run the risk, as the Massachusetts 1971:24), “This [incorporation] is the only way
men had learned, of inviting royal and Episcopal to render the project permanent, to secure wis-
interference. Yale’s founders decided to solve this
problem as best they could by getting a charter
dom and council equal to the work, to defend
from the colonial legislature and by masquerading it against opposition, and to encourage future
their college under the most trivial guise, hoping donations.” Massachusetts’s private statutes
that English indifference to or ignorance of colo- incorporating nonprofit organizations like Christ
nial affairs would leave it unmolested. Hence they Church, Boston (incorporated 1789) and the
called it not a ‘college’ but by the more modest title Scots Charitable Society (incorporated 1786)
‘collegiate school’; hence they call its head not the also mention the need to incorporate to bring
president, as at Harvard, but the ‘rector.’ suit against individuals for debts owed (Private
In this case, Connecticut seemed reluctant to Statutes 1805).
use, or at least publicize, Yale’s use of the pow- Incorporation was also seen as an important
ers of incorporation.5 Ultimately, Yale had to legal protection of institutional autonomy.
wait 44 years, until 1745, before it was officially Smith’s letter continues, “I shall [only] add that
incorporated. Dartmouth College, which orig- a charter is more necessary for such an institu-
inally sought a similar grant from Connecticut, tion in this country than it can be in England.
was denied a charter by the governor and coun- An incorporated body will not only acquire
cil “upon the ground that their action would rights maintainable by law in the courts of jus-
not be valid if ratified in England .|.|. and that tice, but command the favor of the government,
a corporation within a corporation might be who without that sanction, may at such dis-
troublesome as Yale College had sometimes tance from the Crown oppress the undertaking
been” (quoted in Shirley [1895] 1971:22). a thousand ways and utterly destroy it.” In sum,
“Similar caution dictated the general policy of incorporation offered private organizations mul-
all the colonial legislatures [with noted excep- tiple legal powers useful in pursuing their goals.
tions] in matters of this description,” writes Equally pressing is the question of the
legal historian Simeon Baldwin (1909:242). colonists’ desire to defend their provincial char-
Why did corporate status matter so much to ter rights in the face of opposition from royal
institutions like Harvard and Yale (and the New authorities. For example, religious dissenters
looking to escape persecution in Puritan
Massachusetts founded Rhode Island. Though
5 This reluctance may help explain why the granted a royal charter of incorporation in 1643
Connecticut state session books do not contain com- by King Charles I, Rhode Islanders immediately
plete records of private statutes incorporating com- sought recertification of their corporate status
panies. Connecticut’s unique experience with, and following the restoration of the monarchy after
approach to, the corporation deserves much further the English Civil War. They (rightly) feared that
attention. a change of rule in England might jeopardize the
CORPORATE LAW AND THE SOVEREIGNTY OF STATES—–411

legitimacy of their charter. Charles II granted weapon in boundary disputes with New York,
Rhode Island a new charter in 1663, perma- Rhode Island, and Massachusetts (Andrews
nently instituting religious freedom in the 1934; Bremer 2003; Mann 1987; Martin 1991).
colony. This charter granted Rhode Island Charter rights were thus perceived as a vital
unprecedented autonomy from the Crown and component of interstate, as well as internation-
gave the legislative assembly almost complete al, political autonomy.
control over colonial affairs. This charter was Incorporation was clearly a key part of the
seen as an important safeguard in fending off New England Puritans’ vision for their new
territorial incursions initiated by her neighbors, society. The colonies were established as char-
Massachusetts and Connecticut. Ambiguity in tered corporations, and the corporate principle
charters regarding territorial boundaries was a was widely used in trying to people them. One
huge source of anxiety and contentiousness dur- especially important and controversial domain
ing the early colonial and post-Revolutionary of early American corporate law was the prac-
periods (Kaufman forthcoming). Provincial tice of incorporating townships, or subprovin-
charters were thus important to New England cial polities. “New England’s first leaders
colonists not only for legal protection from the needed no coaching in how to put together a
King, but also for protection from neighboring business cor poration,” writes Martin
colonies. After the American Revolution, Rhode (1991:137). “Nor was it a great logical leap to
Island resisted signing the new United States apply the principles for settling the colony to set-
Constitution because its citizens saw confeder- tling a town.|.|.|. The very first towns in New
ation as a potential threat to Rhode Island’s England, which were founded, not by colonial
local autonomy. Despite widespread dissent, legislatures, but directly by the plantation com-
Rhode Island retained its 1663 charter until panies, were governed by these same business
1842, thus signifying the extent to which the
principles governing plantation companies.”
colonists viewed the original charter rights as
Towns were governed by those men and women
sacrosanct and immutable (Andrews 1934;
(yes, women) who owned suitably large parcels
Conley 1977; Richman 1905).
of land therein, much as a corporation is gov-
The Connecticut case is equally telling. In
erned by its shareholders today. Myths of New
Hartford in the 1680s, residents attempted to
England town meetings notwithstanding
hide their corporate charter when asked to cede
(Putnam 2000; Tocqueville 1988), many early
it to Westminster.6 Settlers from Massachusetts
seeking new land spearheaded Connecticut’s New England towns were run by absentee land-
incorporation. Though the Massachusetts lords who had no qualms about denying suffrage
General Court recognized the founding of this to propertyless settlers (Martin 1991). Though
new colony, official sanction was only sought specifics varied from township to township and
from the Crown after the restoration of the colony to colony, the corporate organizational
monarchy. Charles II incorporated Connecticut form was integrally related to the collective
in 1662, adding a proviso that allowed it to political life of colonial New England.
usurp the independent colony of New Haven, While common in New England, other
which wanted no part of Connecticut. Because American colonies lacked comparable experi-
New Haven lacked a corporate charter of its ence using the corporate organizational form as
own, it had few legal means to defend its juris- the basis for settlement. Massachusetts,
dictional autonomy. Thereafter, Connecticut Connecticut, and Rhode Island all existed for at
wielded its corporate charter as an important least their first 50 years as private corporations.
The remaining 10 colonies were founded either
as royal provinces (e.g., New York) or propri-
6 The
etary colonies (e.g., Pennsylvania), or they were
Charter Oak, where the document was hid- converted to one of these following very short
den, remains an important symbol of Connecticut
state history; it now graces the back of their newly
periods of incorporation (e.g., Virginia, which
minted state quarter. Remnants of the oak, which was originally chartered as a corporation but was
fell in 1856, were made into token objects, includ- soon converted to a royal colony, at a time when
ing an oak chair that still sits in the State Senate the entire colony still contained only a few hun-
(Cohn 1988). dred settlers).
412—–AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

Unfortunately, it is hard to know with cer- royal assent. Nonetheless, the practice of incor-
tainty how many corporate charters were issued porating towns continued apace. Debate and
in each of the colonies prior to the American legal contention over the colony’s powers of
Revolution because: (1) charters could be issued corporate issuance continued until 1775, when
by either the colonial legislatures, Parliament in Massachusetts formally broke with the Crown.
England, or both and (2) corporations were “One of the f irst acts passed by the
sometimes founded without official license [Massachusetts] General Court in 1775, after the
from either of the above legislative authorities, resumption of the charter, was that which
as was the case for many township corpora- removed all conditions imposed in the earlier
tions. The length of the colonial period also incorporation of towns, and which, furthermore,
makes examining all annual legislative records granted to all incorporated districts both the
in detail an enormous task. I thus looked at the status of towns and full rights of representation”
legislative records of the Massachusetts General (Cushing 1896:26–27). The exact nature and
Court for several decades (Province of the legitimacy of those rights, on the other hand,
Massachusetts-Bay, Colonial Session Laws): were still poorly understood. The corporation
from 1660 to 1670 and 1710 to 1720, for exam- was, at this time, an institution with clear legit-
ple, the General Court did not issue any corpo- imacy but unclear content and form. These char-
rate charters, though it seems townships were acteristics made it highly susceptible to
nonetheless created using the corporate organi- emulation, contestation, and adaptation, all of
zational form extant at the time (Martin 1991).7 which would help further transform the insti-
In the decade immediately preceding the tution after the Revolution. This brings us direct-
Revolution, 1760 to 1770, the Massachusetts ly to the question of what happened to the
General Court issued 33 charters. Notably, none corporate organizational form during and after
of these were for explicitly business purposes: the American Revolution.
29 charters created township corporations and
four created religious organizations. THE CORPORATION AFTER AMERICAN
These variable rates are consistent with the INDEPENDENCE
changing constraints put on the General Court’s
powers of incorporation in these periods. In the Despite their many ambiguities and uncertain-
1740s, for example, the Massachusetts General ties, so-called “charter rights” were a motivat-
Court ran afoul of the Lords of Trade for incor- ing concern for many, but not all, American
porating townships. Since each township in the revolutionaries. With a long history of charter
colony was guaranteed representation in the disputes, New Englanders were especially
legislative assembly, jurisdictional control over attuned to this issue.8 A major catalyst that
the means of creating new township corpora- transformed complaint into rebellion in
tions was a potentially contentious issue. Massachusetts, for example, was a 1773 royal
Thereafter, the Lords of Trade intervened in a decision to ignore statutes in the Massachusetts
number of attempted township incorporations Charter of 1691 stipulating that government
in Massachusetts, reigniting debate about the officials be paid by the provincial legislature,
colony’s right to create corporations. The Lords thus providing the legislature informal veto
of Trade objected to the expansion of the power. This decision was perceived as a major
General Court and argued that Massachusetts violation of colonial jurisdiction and charter
could not incorporate new townships without rights. A commentator in the Massachusetts
Spy (quoted in Maier 1972:219) wrote, “The
moment that he [the King] or they [his minis-
ters] attempt to render themselves independent
7 Towns in colonial Massachusetts were not gen-
of the people, that moment their authority ceas-
erally chartered prior to the late eighteenth century. es, they themselves break the compact with the
Nonetheless, their organizational structures and legal
foundations were conceived along the same lines as
chartered corporations. Following the Revolution,
dozens of towns in Massachusetts were explicitly 8 Systematic evidence is hard to muster, but it

chartered by the legislature (Martin 1991; Private would appear that charter rights were not a signifi-
Statutes 1780–1800). cant topic of protest in the other colonies.
CORPORATE LAW AND THE SOVEREIGNTY OF STATES—–413

people [i.e., the charter], and from that moment Crown; however, they rarely expressed them in
the people become alienated from their juris- terms of corporate autonomy.
diction, and have a constitutional right to form English colonial authorities repeatedly
their government anew.” attempted to restrict the New England colonies’
One argument in support of the rebellion in liberal use of the corporate organizational form.
Massachusetts was the sanctity of the colony’s The revocation of the original Massachusetts
charter. “We have ever supposed our Charter the Bay Company charter in 1684 was partly justi-
greatest security that could be had in human fied on grounds that the company had exceed-
affairs,” declared the people of Weymouth, ed its corporate powers. As late as the 1740s and
Massachusetts, in response to the controversial ’50s, the Lords of Trade were attacking the
Stamp Act of 1765 (quoted in Reid 1987:97). incorporation of townships in Massachusetts
In 1772, when members of the Massachusetts (Cushing 1896:20–21). In response, the new
legislature argued that their charter guaranteed Massachusetts state legislature tackled the char-
them control over the royal governor’s salary, the ter question almost immediately. According to
royal governor replied, in the words of histori- one account (Cushing 1896:262): “One typical
an Bernard Bailyn (1974:204), that “the peculiarity of the Massachusetts constitution
Massachusetts charter was not a treaty between [of 1780] was the careful manner in which the
two independent states but a Crown gift of lim- corporate privileges and property rights of the
ited powers granted to a group of petitioners.” President and Fellows of Harvard College .|.|.
Clearly, the citizens of Massachusetts felt oth- were confirmed to them.” Another account said:
erwise. They were agitated about the issue of “The great men who formed the constitution of
corporate charters and their jurisdictional right 1780, knew how sacred pre-existing chartered
to issue them. Rhode Islanders expressed sim- rights were” (Josiah Quincy quoted in Cushing
ilar concerns. They were extremely active in 1896:262). Any uncertainty about the College’s
pre-Revolutionary protests against the King and corporate status was thus quickly resolved.
mustered troops for battle only days after Examination of the session laws of several
Massachusetts militiamen fired on the British state legislatures from 1781 through 1810 sheds
at Lexington and Concord. Politicians in other further light on the history of the corporation in
colonies had political grievances with the post-Revolutionary New England. Figure 1

Figure 1. Cumulative Incorporations by State (1780 to 1810)


414—–AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

Figure 2. Cumulative Incorporations per 1,000 White Males (1790 to 1810)

shows the cumulative number of corporate char- Unlike every other state examined,
ters issued (for all purposes) in the 13 original Connecticut’s legislative records offer an incom-
American states. I counted charters by exam- plete account of corporate issuance. The pub-
ining all the published statutes passed in each lished state session laws do not record private
respective legislature for each year between statutes before 1789 and the subsequent pub-
1780 and 1810.9 Each incorporating statute was lished records appear to be substantially incom-
recorded and coded as one of eight different plete.11 I therefore believe that the number of
types of enterprise: business, infrastructure, charters reported in the Connecticut state ses-
polity (townships and districts), education, reli- sion laws, as shown here, underrepresents the
gion, charity, learned and other miscellaneous actual number. Though minor variations may
societies; groups with indeterminable or exist in the figures reported from other states,
ambiguous purpose were coded as “other.” I I did not find any reason to suspect the gener-
coded multipurpose organizations, such as char- al magnitude of charters reported. Efforts to
itable schools, by their primary function (e.g., f ind alternative sources on Connecticut
“education” in the case of a school for pau- incorporations were unsuccessful. Given the
pers). Figure 2 shows state incorporation rates narrative history of incorporation in post-
standardized by the estimated number of white Revolutionary Connecticut, and its earlier his-
males in each province.10 tory as a contested cor porate colony, I
hypothesize that, like Massachusetts and Rhode
Island, it would have had higher-than-average
9 Corporations created via general incorporation
laws could not be counted in this manner because no
legislative acts were required for their issuance, nor male population, as given in the Census, as a rough
could I find records of charters otherwise granted. proxy for the eligible pool of voters. Per capita fig-
Nonetheless, Evans (1948:10) says that few, if any, ures based on the total population were not signifi-
were issued in this early period and refers to the time cantly different from those shown here.
as “the period of the special charter.” Further study 11 While reviewing the Connecticut state sessions

should evaluate this assertion, though finding the records, I discovered that they had many probable
appropriate documents for this prebureaucratic peri- omissions—they contain alterations to charters that
od of American history will be difficult indeed. are not recorded in prior meetings of the legislature,
10 I extrapolated yearly population figures from the for example. Several known municipal incorpora-
1790, 1800, and 1810 U.S. Censuses. I use the white tions were also missing from the state session laws.
CORPORATE LAW AND THE SOVEREIGNTY OF STATES—–415

Figure 3. Incorporations (by type): Massachusetts, 1781 to 1790

incorporation rates for the period examined case for Massachusetts and Rhode Island, at
here. Unfortunately, I know of no means of test- least. Unfortunately, adequate means of stan-
ing this hypothesis. dardizing incorporation rates by the relative
In terms of raw numbers, Massachusetts was economic development of each state are not
by far the leader in corporate issuance (Figure available—reliable industrial, agricultural, and
1): 857 charters were issued from 1780 through trade figures for this period are virtually non-
1810, whereas the next largest incorporator, existent. We do know that unincorporated busi-
New York, issued only 318, a little more than nesses, townships, and churches were quite
one-third as many. Pennsylvania was next, with common at this time (Karsten 1997; Lamoreaux
230 charters; followed by South Carolina with 1997; Paskoff 1983). How exactly these unin-
164 and Rhode Island with 149. corporated entities differed from incorporated
Adjusted for (white male) population size, entities in their jurisdictional and legal powers
Rhode Island was the nation’s leading incorpo- is an inordinately complex issue beyond the
rator, followed by Massachusetts (Figure 2).12 scope of this article. It would require, for exam-
All other states had far lower per capita incor- ple, state-by-state analysis of the complex and
poration rates. Though complete data are not ever-changing law of contracts, property rights,
available for Connecticut, it is plausible that taxation, torts, and so forth. This topic, though,
is very much worth further investigation.
over the first 20 years of the Republic the three
One question we can answer, at least indi-
former “corporate colonies” of New England
rectly, is how and why state legislatures began
(Massachusetts, Connecticut, and Rhode Island)
issuing corporate charters in the immediate
were well ahead of the other states in the num-
post-Revolutionary period. To answer this ques-
ber of corporate charters issued relative to their
tion, I focus specifically on the types of enter-
levels of demographic expansion. This is the prise chartered by the Massachusetts General
Court. Figure 3 shows the breakdown of char-
ters (into eight different categories) issued in
12 Absent accurate state-level population data for Massachusetts from 1781 to 1790: a remarkable
1780 to 1790, Figure 2 assesses per capita incorpo- 61 percent of charters were issued to new town-
ration rates only for 1790 to 1810. ships and districts. As mentioned earlier, there
416—–AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

is direct precedent for this in the pre- Several other states, by contrast, handled the
Revolutionary disputes between the church-state question differently. For a short
Massachusetts legislature and the royal gover- period, the Virginia state legislature refused to
nor over the issuance of township charters. The issue charters to religious organizations
second largest category of incorporation, reli- (Buckley 1995). Pennsylvania, which had a
gious organizations (mostly churches, as well as long tradition of noninterference in religious
a few parish organizations), represents 15 per- affairs, opted to pass a general incorporation law
cent of the total. Incorporations for business in 1791, allowing any church, literary, or char-
purposes (businesses plus infrastructure com- itable organization to obtain a charter upon
panies) make up only a small portion of the application to the attorney general (Frost 1990).
total (7 percent). In concert with the original cor- Among the original 13 states, five others—
porate-commonwealth model of the New York (1784), New Jersey (1786), Delaware
Massachusetts Bay Company (Innes 1995; (1787), Georgia (1789), and Maryland (1802)—
Martin 1991), the new state legislature contin- also passed general incorporation laws for reli-
ued to deploy the corporate model largely as a gious groups. 13 The motivation for liberal
means of creating new civic and ecclesiastical issuance (but not “general incorporation”) in
polities. Massachusetts, on the other hand, appears to
Figure 4 shows the second decade of incor- indicate a desire to control, rather than liberate,
poration in post-Revolutionary Massachusetts, religious congregations, which is consistent
1791 to 1800. During this decade, Massa- with that state’s earlier history of church-state
chusetts issued a total of 255 charters, in con- interaction (Innes 1995). This highlights the
trast to 97 in the previous decade. The state high degree of ambiguity underlying the post-
legislature appears to have gained momentum Revolutionary institution of the corporation:
in its overall issuance of charters. We do not there was substantial disagreement across and
know, though, what percentage of this trend within states about whether the issuance of cor-
was due to an increased supply of charters (i.e., porate charters was best seen as a means of
increased ease of acquisition of charters), as strengthening or weakening state power over
opposed to an increased demand (i.e., more corporations. Such disagreements continued
requests for charters). The extant state records well into the nineteenth century, when most
do not provide information about charters states began clarifying these distinctions by cre-
requested but not granted. ating and regulating different categories of cor-
We do know that the Massachusetts General porations with different expectations.
Court issued 70 new township charters between Politics, too, was an important and highly
1791 and 1800. Nearly as many charters were unpredictable source of ambiguity in the course
issued to religious organizations and infra- of the early American corporation. Factional
structure companies. Interestingly, the increase disputes in state legislatures could decide the
in religious incorporations seems to have been fate of charter requests above and beyond the
triggered by a decision in the state legislature abstract considerations incumbent on such deci-
regarding mandatory taxes for support of sions (c.f. Handlin and Handlin 1945; Hartz
Congregationalist (i.e., Puritan) churches. 1948). In early nineteenth-century New York, for
Beginning in the late 1780s, only those non- example, opposing political parties chartered
Congregationalist taxpayers who could prove rival banks (Hammond 1957). Pennsylvania
that they were members of an incorporated non- deserves special mention in this respect, given
Congregationalist church could qualify for its anomalous history regarding freedom of
exemption from local church taxes, thus prompt- incor poration. Late eighteenth-century
ing numerous requests for church charters Pennsylvanians were strongly divided over this
(McLoughlin 1971:636–59). A number of non- issue (Brunhouse 1942). In 1784, an anti-
tax-exempt Congregationalist churches received incorporation bloc in the legislature sought to
charters at this time as well. This is evidence that
incorporation was increasingly seen as a desir-
able appendage of church organization even for 13 Dates in parentheses indicate the year of passage
those congregations that would not benefit from of general incorporation laws. The number of cor-
the tax exemption. porations made under these laws is not known.
CORPORATE LAW AND THE SOVEREIGNTY OF STATES—–417

Figure 4. Incorporations (by type): Massachusetts, 1791 to 1800

block incorporation of Philadelphia, as well as presence of an otherwise vibrant textile indus-


the newly reorganized University of try based on small workshops and family-owned
Pennsylvania (formerly the College of businesses (Paskoff 1983; Perrow 2002;
Philadelphia). Though both were eventually Scranton 1983; Shelton 1986; Ware 1931).
chartered, the state legislature remained reluc- Though endogenous factors related to the indus-
tant to issue special charters of incorporation try merit consideration (e.g., availability of nat-
throughout this period. This anticorporate stance ural resources, proximity to ports and rivers,
seems to stem from the state’s earlier history as presence of skilled workers), scholars often
a proprietary colony under the personal, and overlook that the Pennsylvania state legislature
largely unpopular, authority of the Penn fami- was comparatively unwilling to grant corpo-
ly. Members of the “antiproprietary” party in rate charters for this purpose at this time.14 That
Pennsylvania saw corporate charters as a poten- the first corporate manufacturing concerns in
tial extension of Penn family privilege and so the United States were created in Massachusetts
opposed them. Unlike Massachusetts, whose seems similarly related to that state’s willingness
history stressed the need for the legislature to to use governmental power to encourage and
protect its right to issue charters at will, protect private entrepreneurship. Rhode Island
Pennsylvanians were split over perceived abus- also quickly leaped to the fore as a center of
es of power. As late as 1810, Pennsylvania had large-scale American textile manufacturing.
issued fewer “special” charters per capita than Connecticut, too, became a center of early
all of the original 13 states save Virginia (and American industry, though the role of incorpo-
Connecticut, though figures for this state are ration in these advances is less clear there. I
incomplete).
The comparison between Pennsylvania and
Massachusetts sheds interesting light on the 14 During this period, general incorporation laws
fate of the two states’ economies in the post- in Pennsylvania did not cover business organiza-
Revolutionary period. Numerous scholars have tions. This precludes the possibility that I simply
commented on the relatively late start of large- failed to note their proliferation in the state session
scale manufacturing in Pennsylvania, despite the laws.
418—–AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

hypothesize that early American entrepreneurs corporate charters, given the legal fees such
first built vast new plants in New England in part applications would generate for them.
because of those states’ favorable policies In supply-side terms, many state legislatures
toward would-be incorporators. The familiari- seem to have learned by the 1810s that corpo-
ty of local attorneys and entrepreneurs with the rate chartering could be an important source of
corporate organizational form also likely pro- revenue and capital control. Legislators often
moted its use in New England. In most other required groups seeking incorporation to pay
states, by contrast, unincorporated companies licensing fees, taxes, and anything else the leg-
remained the predominant form of business islature could think of. Bank charters, for exam-
organization throughout this period ple, often required recipients to invest large
(Fenstermaker 1965; Lamoreaux 1997). The sums in state-appointed enterprises and pay
exact causal order of the relationship between taxes to the state in exchange for the privilege
incorporation and economic development of doing business. “In 1813 and 1822 as a price
deserves further study. Examination of the for renewing their charters, the Baltimore banks
papers and diaries of early industrialists might had to form a turnpike company, buy its stock,
provide evidence concerning their decisions and manage it,” reports Fenstermaker (1965:17).
about where to locate and in what legal- “The City Bank of New Haven in 1831 had to
organizational form, for example. Though rarely buy $100,000 of stock in the Hampshire and
extant today, records of legislative debates over Hampton Canal Company, and the Quinibaug
the issuance of charters would help shed further Bank had to purchase $100,000 of the capital
light on this issue as well. stock of the Boston, Norwich, and New London
Because it was not possible to locate records Railroad Company in 1832.” Many chartered
of failed appeals for incorporation, I can only banks were obliged to loan a given percentage
conjecture about the size and scope of demand of their capital stock to citizens engaged in local
for corporate charters during this period. In farming or manufacturing. In some cases, banks
addition to the legislatures’ sudden new ability were required to pay a “bonus” for their char-
and willingness to grant charter requests, New ter, as did the Bank of South Carolina in 1801
Englanders’ motivation to seek incorporation and the Louisiana State Bank in 1814
appears to stem in part from that region’s par- (Fenstermaker 1965).
ticular legal culture, ensconced as it was in a Presumably, the balance of power in respec-
long tradition of litigiousness and jurisdiction- tive state legislatures was an important compo-
al dispute (Hoffer 1992; Mann 1987; Tomlins nent in attaining consensus on charter appeals.
In Pennsylvania, as previously mentioned, a
and Mann 2001). Presumably, both mimetic
strong anticorporate faction in the legislature
and competitive isomorphism were also at work
sought to block incorporation of the city of
here (DiMaggio and Powell 1983): a first wave
Philadelphia and the University of Pennsylvania.
of incorporations likely encouraged others to
Regional rivalry between eastern and western
follow suit. The Massachusetts session law
Pennsylvania state legislators also stymied early
records contain veritable “incorporation waves,”
efforts at passing special acts of incorporation
such as June 19, 1801, when three different
for transportation companies (Hartz 1948). In
turnpike companies were incorporated. Regional
other states, such as New York in the early
clusters were also evident, especially in western
1800s, competition between rival political fac-
and northern Massachusetts (Maine was still tions led to a flurry of charters issued to parti-
part of Massachusetts at this time), where san banks (Hammond 1957). Legislative
bunches of charters were simultaneously factionalism regarding corporate charters helps
requested by neighboring towns, churches, explain why these two states were early adopters
schools, charities, and businesses.15 In-state of general incorporation laws, which likely
lawyers, too, probably promoted the pursuit of helped avoid partisan bickering over individual
charters.
Most American states eventually adopted this
15 I have not confirmed the statistical validity of less invasive approach to chartering corpora-
such observations. Only a portion of charters indicate tions. Interestingly, the three New England
the location of the applicants. states, plus New Hampshire, were laggards in
CORPORATE LAW AND THE SOVEREIGNTY OF STATES—–419

this respect. Well into the twentieth century, By the 1820s, American courts began
they did not have constitutional provisions addressing issues that the legislatures had raised
“requiring [business] incorporation under gen- regarding the rights and privileges of corpora-
eral laws” (Evans 1948:11). Apparently, they tions. A series of landmark court cases—
were loath to relinquish state control over the Dartmouth College v. Woodward (1819) being
means of incorporation, a legacy, perhaps, of the most famous—sought to revise American
their earlier struggles to exact such control from corporate law in ways consistent with the activ-
the Crown. These states, especially ities of actual American corporations, now so
Massachusetts, also placed relatively strong plentiful in number. Over time, state and federal
regulatory constraints on in-state businesses. courts not only upheld the notion of freedom of
By the Progressive Era, Massachusetts was well incorporation but also began to defend the sanc-
ahead of the nation in terms of corporate regu- tity of the private corporation from state inter-
lation (Abrams 1964). ference (Horwitz 1977). Arguably, judges
expanded their conception of the public good to
TRANSFORMATION OF THE AMERICAN embrace America’s increasingly brisk econo-
CORPORATE ORGANIZATIONAL FORM, 1810 my. Private gain was heralded as a key compo-
TO 1850
nent of the public good, a rationalization that
would subsequently come to undergird all
Public opinion about the nature and desirabili- American political-economic policy (Appleby
ty of private corporations in the early Republic 1984; Dobbin 1994; Hurst 1964, 1970). It is dif-
was far from unanimous; much of it was down- ficult to piece out the cause-and-effect rela-
right hostile. The role or form of the corpora- tionship between evolving standards of
tion was not yet settled either. Well before corporate law and republican neoliberal ideol-
Andrew Jackson’s famous anticorporate cam- ogy. We do know, at least, that the corporation’s
paign, politicians and journalists were quoting role in the polity had been growing, exponen-
Adam Smith on the dangers of corporate tially in some jurisdictions, since the founding
monopolies. In 1826, leading American jurist of the Republic.
James Kent exclaimed in his Commentaries on Beginning in the 1790s, but not culminating
American Law ([1826] 1871: II, 220): “The until the late nineteenth century, state legisla-
demand for acts of incorporation is continual- tures throughout the United States began insti-
ly increasing, and the propensity is the more tutionalizing a new form of access to the means
striking, as it appears to be incurable; and we of incorporation: general incorporation laws.
seem to have no moral means to resist it.” These These enabled entrepreneurs to receive charters
fears largely reflected the conventional English of incorporation without special legislative
conception of the corporation as a restricted approval (Creighton 1990; Evans 1948; Roy
royal grant. Many Americans viewed corpora- 1997; Seavoy 1982). This meant that the means
tions as government-sanctioned monopolies, of incorporation were now open to any group
with the dangerous ability to interrupt the nat- that could complete the necessary paperwork.
ural course of society. In addition to incorporating for-profit busi-
Nonetheless, it was hard to argue down the nesses, general incorporation laws were wide-
cause of incorporation given the vast number of ly used to charter voluntary associations (e.g.,
private companies already incorporated in some fraternal lodges, charities, societies, sodalities,
states. The more politicians railed against the and congregations), both as a means of pro-
dangers of incorporation, the more they lent tecting group assets and as a template for
credence to the (proto-Madisonian) argument expanding and federalizing such organizations
that the best protection against the dangers of (cf. Clemens 1997; Hall 1992; Kaufman 2002;
corporations was to allow more companies to Skocpol 2003).
incorporate (Horwitz 1977; Kaufman 1999). A related nineteenth-century transformation
The “freedom of incorporation” doctrine gained of the corporate organizational form was the
rhetorical support from both sides—those who construction of different legal categories of cor-
sought to use legislative power to encourage poration. Originally, American law made no
free enterprise, as well as those who feared the distinction between public and private corpo-
power of unduly restrained free enterprise. rations. Municipal governments were viewed, in
420—–AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

fact, as little more than publicly owned land- Carruthers and Halliday’s (1998) concept of
holding companies, a practice that dates back to “law’s recursive loop,” the notion that new legal
medieval England, where the sanctity of a city doctrines have a pronounced tendency to evolve
charter revolved around ownership of city prop- not as conscious, purposive doctrine but as post
erty, or commons (Hartog 1983; Teaford 1965). hoc responses to changing, cumulating social
Beginning in the 1810s and ’20s, American conditions. The former corporate colonies of
courts began to differentiate the rights and pow- New England first supported the widespread use
ers of public corporations from those of of the corporate organizational form long before
privately-held corporations (Newmyer 1976). In the courts and legislatures began refining their
addition to certifying the civic benefits of pri- conceptions of the corporation. Only after the
vate, for-profit corporations, the courts for- proliferation of corporations, and much litiga-
mally reframed public corporations as direct tion between competing corporations, such as
appendages of state power. Such corporations Charles River Bridge v. Warren Bridge (36 U.S.
had a responsibility to the people and could 420 [1837]), did the courts begin to tackle the
only own property as a public trust. Thus con- subtleties of corporate law in earnest.
strued, “a public corporation was nothing but an
agency of the state; whereas a private corpora- CONCLUSIONS
tion assumed the character of a private citizen”
(Hartog 1983:193–94). This new definition of This article elucidates several signif icant
public corporations was quite similar to the pre- processes for institutional theory. First, I demon-
Revolutionary common law definition of a cor- strate that the common law corporation origi-
poration—it was the court’s new conception of nally existed as a relatively undifferentiated
the private corporation that was truly innovative organizational form, one that could be used for
(Appleby 1984; Horwitz 1971, 1977). American a variety of purposes. Second, I show that sev-
courts began to rein in public corporations while eral British North American colonies began
at the same time granting private corporations using the corporation in ways not intended or
unprecedented freedom. This marks a turning approved by the King in Parliament. Third, I
point in the legal rationalization of the American argue that experience with the corporate organi-
corporation following an earlier period of exper- zational form in these colonies helped cultivate
imentation and dissemination. knowledge and appreciation of that form over
In terms of institutional theory, this differ- time, despite royal opposition to its continued
entiation marks an effort to more clearly define use. Fourth, I show that these same colonies
the functions and forms of the corporation. It chartered unusually high numbers of corpora-
follows an earlier period in which a relatively tions after Independence, many for enterprises
undifferentiated, ambiguous organizational form that standard economic histories of the corpo-
spread and gained increasing legitimacy. ration do not commonly consider. Fifth, I argue
Scholars of nineteenth-century corporations that American legal doctrine regarding the cor-
might closely examine debates over the relative poration only began grappling with the nuances
pros and cons of rationalizing corporate law in of corporate law after an initial proliferation of
this manner. Why exactly courts and legislatures corporations in the American states. We thus see
were motivated to do so is not clear (cf. Karsten the expansion and transformation of a now com-
1997). I hypothesize that the courts’ decisions mon sociolegal institution through indirect
declaring the sanctity of private corporations means. Royal resistance to its use, as well as
were, in part, a reaction to the increased densi- domestic, noneconomic preferences associated
ty of private corporations, itself the product of with its desirability, encouraged the early devel-
earlier legislative willingness to freely grant opment of an institution that would later inspire
private charters. That is, American jurispru- the creation of a new sphere of legal doctrine.
dence regarding corporations appears to have One might characterize the early develop-
evolved only after many state legislatures had ment of the corporation in the United States as
already institutionalized freedom of incorpora- a case in which a relatively undifferentiated
tion. Though a formal test of this hypothesis is institution persisted despite struggles over its
beyond the scope of this article, it deserves fur- content and relational structure. In turn, this
ther attention. If true, this would support accentuated its desirability in a period of new-
CORPORATE LAW AND THE SOVEREIGNTY OF STATES—–421

found political opportunity (i.e., Independence). The relational transformation of the corporate
The ambiguity underlying conflict over colonial organizational form changed the very meaning
use of the corporation later became an impetus of private enterprise in the early United States.
to imitation, adaptation, and transformation. While the right of governments to regulate com-
After an initial period of selective proliferation merce was upheld, the notion that only excep-
(primarily in New England), the corporation tional circumstances demanded incorporation
rapidly diffused across the country and became waned. Having made the means of incorpora-
increasingly differentiated, rationalized, and tion so readily accessible, American courts and
bureaucratized. All of this is consistent with legislators faced efforts to define the exact rights
the sociological variant of institutional theory and responsibilities of corporations. Courts and
(see review in Clemens and Cook 1999). legislatures have not always been consistent in
A less predictable outcome of this process is their vision of the American private corporation,
the weakening of state control over an institu- but the long-term trend has been toward greater
tion that some colonial politicians desired to corporate autonomy, except in cases where the
control. The shift of control from the Crown to openness of markets is at stake (Dobbin 1994).
the separate states marks a shift in the perceived Though there is already a long tradition of
locus of controversy. As colonists, Puritan politi- scholarship dedicated to the subject of the
cians sought to repatriate control over corpora- American corporation and its historical origins,
tions by extolling the right of colonial few, if any accounts focus on the colonial ori-
legislatures to create and regulate them. gins of American corporate law, its prehistory
Following Independence, with state autonomy as it were. American corporate law is increas-
firmly in place, the need to exert this control ingly the norm in international commerce and
lapsed. This points to the need to study the con- some unarticulated form of the American “free-
nections between corporate institutions and state dom of incorporation” doctrine is common in
formation in a world-historical perspective. most developed nations today (Chandler 1977;
Because corporations are legal fictions created Coase 1937; Coleman 1982; Fligstein 2001;
by states, their fates are inevitably intertwined. North 1990; Williamson 1981). This makes
The concurrent rise of corporations and polities understanding the uniquely American origins of
in the Puritan colonies of New England is a this doctrine especially significant.
unique factor in American political develop- Without legislative willingness to charter pri-
ment (Kaufman forthcoming). vate corporations, the economic and political
Seen from this perspective, Americans’ well- development of the “first new nation” (Lipset
noted capacity to form not only for-profit but 1973) might have been vastly different. By
also nonprofit private organizations (Tocqueville freely endorsing a legal entity above and beyond
1988) is directly related to America’s history of individual trusts and partnerships, American
support for, and conflict over, states’ power to state legislatures released a force that would
create corporations. Given the evidence at hand, only begin to realize its potential in the decades
Americans’ unusual propensity to “associate” to come. American jurists and legislators could
does not appear to be the result of Americans’ have easily constructed American civil law
ingrained preferences, nor the absence of state around British common law precepts, and they
organizations dedicated to related pursuits. often did. In the case of corporate charters,
American voluntarism instead appears directly however, some American states forged new
related to state support for private corporations, ground, much of which would later be copied
or at least the unprecedented willingness to worldwide.
grant charters of incor poration. Novak A further observation following from this
(2001:172) writes: “Nineteenth-century leg- study regards the nature of American corpo-
islators, judges, and commentators defended rate governance. Building on English common
associations not as alternatives to a legal- law practice, the New England Puritans
constitutional state, but as constitutive compo- espoused the idea that only shareholding mem-
nents of it.|.|.|. [Associations] were in fact legal- bers of corporate colonies and townships should
ly-constituted and politically-recognized be full participants in their governance. They
delegations of rule-making authority and pub- made clear distinctions between freeholders
lic resources.” and other residents (Martin 1991). These
422—–AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

colonies were thus governed primarily by and Jason Kaufman is John L. Loeb Associate Professor
for large property-owners. The modern of the Social Sciences at Harvard University. His
American corporate system has adopted an current work explores the comparative political devel-
incarnation of this institutional frame: profit- opment of the United States and Canada; sumptuary
law and vice crime before, during, and after
sharing with employees is rare, and corporate Prohibition; and the cultural worlds and social net-
governance is run in the interest of manage- works of American college students.
ment and shareholders rather than employees or
society as a whole (Coleman 1982; Perrow
2002; Roy 1997). Future studies should explore REFERENCES
parallels with state-corporate relations in other Abrams, Richard M. 1964. Conservatism in a
nation-states. Presumably, for example, corpo- Progressive Era: Massachusetts Politics,
ratist arrangements in Western European poli- 1900–1912. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
ties stem in part from their civil law trajectories Press.
Adams, Julia. 2005. The Familial State: Ruling
of strict state control over corporations and the
Families and Merchant Capitalism in Early
means of incorporation. Modern Europe. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University
By changing citizens’ relationship to the Press.
means of incorporation, certain American states Andrews, Charles M. 1934. The Colonial Period of
radically changed the balance of social and eco- American History. Vols. 1–4. New Haven, CT:
nomic power in the Western world. Weber Yale University Press.
(1978) devoted much of his career to under- Appleby, Joyce O. 1984. Capitalism and a New Social
standing the legal foundations of such power. Order: The Republican Vision of the 1790s. New
Though he did not comment much on the par- York: New York University Press.
Bailyn, Bernard. 1974. The Ordeal of Thomas
ticularities of American law, his extensive study
Hutchinson. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press.
of comparative law pointed in this direction: Baldwin, Simeon E. 1898. Modern Political
“If, by virtue of the principle of formal legal Institutions. Boston, MA: Little, Brown, and Co.
equality, everyone ‘without respect of person’ ———. 1901. “Private Corporations, 1701–1901.”
may establish a business corporation or entail Two Centuries Growth of American Law,
a landed estate, the propertied classes as such 1701–1901. New York: Charles Scribner’s Sons.
obtain a sort of factual ‘autonomy,’ since they ———. 1909. “History of the Law of Private
alone are able to utilize or take advantage of Corporations in the Colonies and States.” Anglo-
these powers” (p. 699). American Legal History. Vol. 3. Boston, MA:
Little, Brown, and Co.
The arguments presented here, though pre- Berle, Adolf A. and Gardiner C. Means. 1932. The
liminary, point to the importance of studying Modern Corporation and Private Property. New
political, economic, civic, and legal develop- York: Macmillan.
ments as mutually-constitutive processes. Biernacki, Richard. 2005. “The Action Turn?
Freedom of incorporation doctrine did not grow Comparative-Historical Inquiry Beyond the
in a juridical vacuum nor solely in response to Classical Models of Conduct.” Pp. 75–91 in
perceived economic needs. It was the result of Remaking Modernity: Politics, History, and
a century and a half of struggle and debate over Sociology, edited by J. Adams, E. S. Clemens, and
A. Shola Orloff. Durham, NC: Duke University
the right of intermediary associations to exist as
Press.
full-fledged polities. This clearly demonstrates Bremer, Francis J. 2003. John Winthrop: America’s
the importance of considering colonial Forgotten Founding Father. New York: Oxford
antecedents and long-term processes in the University Press.
study of national institutional development. It Brown, Elizabeth Gaspar. 1964. British Statutes in
also reaffirms social scientists’ newfound inter- American Law, 1776–1836. Ann Arbor, MI:
est in issues of institutional durability and University of Michigan Press.
change, processes whereby longstanding organi- Brunhouse, Robert L. 1942. The Counter-Revolution
zational forms come to have new significance in Pennsylvania, 1776–1790. Philadelphia, PA:
University of Pennsylvania/Pennsylvania Historical
and meaning over time (Clemens and Cook
Commission.
1999; Pierson 2004; Thelen 2003). The corpo- Buckley, Thomas. 1995. “After Disestablishment:
rate organizational form has evolved more Thomas Jefferson’s Wall of Separation in
quickly in some polities than others, but its Antebellum Virginia.” Journal of Southern History
ramifications are now felt worldwide. 61:4445–480.
CORPORATE LAW AND THE SOVEREIGNTY OF STATES—–423

Campbell, John L. and Leon N. Lindberg. 1990. Davis, Joseph Stancliffe. 1917. Essays in the Earlier
“Property Rights and the Organization of History of American Corporations. Cambridge,
Economic Activity by the State.” American MA: Harvard University Press.
Sociological Review 55(5):634–47. DiMaggio, Paul J. and Walter W. Powell. 1983. “The
Carruthers, Bruce G. 1996. City of Capital: Politics Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism
and Markets in the English Financial Revolution. and Collective Rationality in Organizational
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Fields.” American Sociological Review 48:147–60.
Carruthers, Bruce G. and Terence C. Halliday. 1998. Dobbin, Frank. 1994. Forging Industrial Policy: The
Rescuing Business: The Making of Corporate United States, Britain, and France in the Railway
Bankruptcy Law in England and the United States. Age. New York: Cambridge University Press.
New York: Oxford University Press. DuBois, Armand B. 1938. The English Business
Chandler, Alfred Dupont. 1962. Strategy and Company after the Bubble Act, 1720–1800. New
Structure: Chapters in the History of Industrial York: The Commonwealth Fund.
Enterprise. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Erikson, Emily and Peter Bearman. 2006.
———. 1977. The Visible Hand: The Managerial “Malfeasance and the Foundations for Global
Revolution in American Business. Cambridge, Trade: The Structure of English Trade in the East
MA: Harvard University Press. Indies, 1601–1833.” American Journal of
Chibber, Vivek. 2003. Locked in Place: State Building Sociology 112:195–230.
and Late Industrialization in India. Princeton, NJ: Evans, George H., Jr. 1948. Business Incorporations
Princeton University Press. in the United States, 1800–1943. New York:
Clemens, Elisabeth S. 1997. The People’s Lobby: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Organizational Innovation and the Rise of Interest Evans, Peter. 1995. Embedded Autonomy: States and
Group Politics in the United States, 1890–1925. Industrial Transformation. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. University Press.
Clemens, Elisabeth S. and James M. Cook. 1999. Fenstermaker, J. Van. 1965. The Development of
“Politics and Institutionalism: Explaining American Commercial Banking: 1782–1837. Kent,
Durability and Change.” Annual Review of OH: Bureau of Economic and Business Research.
Sociology 25:441–66. Fligstein, Neil. 1990. The Transformation of
Coase, Ronald H. 1937. “The Nature of the Firm.” Corporate Control. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
Economica 4:386–405. University Press.
Cohn, Henry S. 1988. “Connecticut Constitutional ———. 2001. The Architecture of Markets: An
History, 1636–1776.” Connecticut State Library, Economic Sociology of Twenty-First Century
retrieved November 15, 2004 (http://www. Capitalist Societies. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
cslib.org/cts4cc.htm). University Press.
Coleman, James S. 1982. The Asymmetric Society. Friedland, Roger and Robert R. Alford. 1991.
Syracuse, NY: Syracuse University Press. “Bringing Society Back In: Symbols, Practices,
Conley, Patrick T. 1977. Democracy in Decline: and Institutional Contradictions.” Pp. 232–63 in
Rhode Island’s Constitutional Development, The New Institutionalism in Organizational
1776–1841. Providence, RI: Rhode Island Analysis, edited by W. W. Powell and P. J.
Historical Society. DiMaggio. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago
Creighton, Andrew L. 1990. The Emergence of Press.
Incorporation as a Legal Form for Organizations. Frost, J. William. 1990. A Perfect Freedom: Religious
PhD dissertation, Department of Sociology, Liberty in Pennsylvania. New York: Cambridge
Stanford University, Palo Alto, CA. University Press.
Cushing, Harry A. 1896. History of the Transition Hall, Peter Dobkin. 1992. Inventing the Nonprofit
from Provincial to Commonwealth Government Sector and Other Essays on Philanthropy,
in Massachusetts. Masters thesis, Department of Voluntarism, and Nonprofit Organizations.
Political Science, Columbia University, New York. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Dana, Samuel Whittelsey. 1784. Yale-College Subject Hammond, Bray. 1957. Banks and Politics in
to the General Assembly: The Right of the General America: From the Revolution to the Civil War.
Assembly to Inspect, Regulate and Reform the Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Corporation of Yale-College in New-Haven, Handlin, Oscar and Mary F. Handlin. 1945. “Origins
Considered on Principles of Law and equity. of the American Business Corporation.” Journal
Reprinted in Early American Imprints, First Series, of Economic History 5(1):1–23.
no. 18434. New Haven, CT: Thomas and Samuel ———. 1969. Commonwealth: A Study of the Role
Green. of Government in the American Economy,
Davis, Andrew McFarland. 1894. Corporations in the 1774–1861. Rev. ed. Cambridge, MA: Belknap
Days of the Colony. Cambridge: John Wilson and Press.
Son. Hartog, Hendrik. 1983. Public Property and Private
424—–AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

Power: The Corporation of the City of New York in Kent, James. [1826] 1871. Commentaries on
American Law, 1730–1870. Ithaca, NY: Cornell American Law. New York: Da Capo Press.
University Press. Lamoreaux, Naomi R. 1997. “The Partnership Form
Hartz, Louis. 1948. Economic Policy and Democratic of Organization: Its Popularity in Early-Nineteenth-
Thought: Pennsylvania, 1776–1860. Cambridge, Century Boston.” Pp. 269–95 in Entrepreneurs:
MA: Harvard University Press. The Boston Business Community, 1700–1850, edit-
Herbst, Jurgen. 1982. From Crisis to Crisis: American ed by C. E. Wright and K. P. Viens. Boston, MA:
College Government, 1636–1819. Cambridge, Massachusetts Historical Society.
MA: Harvard University Press. Lipset, Seymour Martin. 1973. The First New Nation:
Hoffer, Peter Charles. 1992. Law and People in The United States in Historical and Comparative
Colonial America. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins History. New York: Norton.
University Press. Maier, Pauline. 1972. From Resistance to Revolution:
Hofstadter, Richard. 1955. Academic Freedom in the Colonial Radicals and the Development of
Age of the College. New York: Columbia American Opposition to Britain, 1765–1776. New
University Press. York: Knopf.
Horwitz, Morton J. 1971. “The Emergence of an ———. 1992. “The Debate Over Incorporations:
Instrumental Conception of American Law, Massachusetts in the Early Republic.” Pp. 73–117
1780–1820.” Pp. 287–326 in Perspectives in in Massachusetts and the New Nation, edited by
American History: Law in American History, edit- C. E. Wright. Boston, MA: Massachusetts
ed by D. Fleming and B. Bailyn. Cambridge, MA: Historical Society.
Charles Warren Center for Studies in American ———. 1993. “The Revolutionary Origins of the
History. American Corporation.” William and Mary
———. 1977. The Transformation of American Quarterly 3d series, Vol. L., 1:51–84.
Law, 1780–1860. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Maitland, Frederic W. 2003. State, Trust, and
University Press. Corporation. Edited by D. Runciman and M. Ryan.
Huntington, Samuel P. 1968. Political Order in Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Changing Societies. New Haven, CT: Yale Mann, Bruce H. 1987. Neighbors and Strangers:
University Press. Law and Community in Early Connecticut. Chapel
Hurst, James Willard. 1964. Law and Economic Hill, NC: University of North Carolina Press.
Growth: The Legal History of the Lumber Industry Martin, John Frederick. 1991. Profits in the
in Wisconsin, 1836–1875. Cambridge, MA: Wilderness: Entrepreneurship and the Founding of
Belknap Press. New England Towns in the Seventeenth Century.
———. 1970. The Legitimacy of the Business Chapel Hill, NC: University of North Carolina
Corporation in the Law of the United States, Press.
1780–1970. Charlottesville, VA: University of Mather, Increase. 1691. “A Brief Account Concerning
Virginia Press. Several of the Agents of New England, their
Innes, Stephen. 1995. Creating the Commonwealth: Negotiation at the Court of England, with some
The Economic Culture of Puritan New England. Remarks on the New Charter Granted to the
New York: W. W. Norton. Colony of Massachusets [sic], etc.” November 16.
Karsten, Peter. 1997. “Supervising the ‘Spoiled London, UK.
Children of Legislation’: Judicial Judgments McGouldrick, Paul F. 1968. New England Textiles in
Involving Quasi-Public Corporations in the the Nineteenth Century: Profits and Investment.
Nineteenth Century U.S.” American Journal of Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Legal History 41(3):315–67. McLoughlin, William G. 1971. New England Dissent,
———. 2002. Between Law and Custom: ‘High’ 1630–1833: The Baptists and the Separation of
and ‘Low’Legal Cultures in the Lands of the British Church and State. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
Diaspora: The United States, Canada, Australia, University Press.
and New Zealand, 1600–1900. Cambridge, UK: Meyer, John W. and Brian Rowan. 1977.
Cambridge University Press. “Institutionalized Organizations: Formal Structure
Kaufman, Jason. 1999. “Three Views of as Myth and Ceremony.” American Journal of
Associationalism in Nineteenth Century America: Sociology 83(2):340–63.
An Empirical Examination.” American Journal Mintz, Beth and Michael Schwartz. 1985. The Power
of Sociology 104(5):1296–1345. Structure of American Business. Chicago, IL:
———. 2002. For The Common Good? American University of Chicago Press.
Civic Life and the Golden Age of Fraternity. New Mizruchi, Mark. 1982. The American Corporate
York: Oxford University Press. Network, 1904–1974. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage.
———. Forthcoming. The Origins of Canadian Morison, Samuel Eliot. 1936. Harvard College in the
and American Political Differences. Cambridge, Seventeenth Century. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
MA: Harvard University Press. University Press.
CORPORATE LAW AND THE SOVEREIGNTY OF STATES—–425

Nelson, William E. 1994. Americanization of the Scranton, Philip. 1983. Proprietary Capitalism: The
Common Law: The Impact of Legal Change on Textile Manufacture at Philadelphia, 1800–1885.
Massachusetts Society, 1760–1830. Athens, GA: New York: Cambridge University Press.
University of Georgia Press. Seavoy, Ronald E. 1982. The Origins of the American
Newmyer, R. Kent. 1976. “Justice Joseph Story’s
Doctrine of ‘Public and Private Corporations’ and Business Corporation, 1784–1855. Westport, CT:
the Rise of the American Business Corporation.” Greenwood.
DePaul Law Review 25:825–41. Shelton, Cynthia. 1986. The Mills of Manayunk:
North, Douglass C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Industrialization and Social Conflict in the
Change, and Economic Performance. Cambridge, Philadelphia Region, 1787–1837. Baltimore, MD:
UK: Cambridge University Press. Johns Hopkins University Press.
Novak, William J. 2001. “The American Law of Shirley, John M. [1895] 1971. The Dartmouth College
Association: The Legal-Political Construction of
Civil Society.” Studies in American Political Causes and the Supreme Court of the United
Development 15:163–88. States. New York: Da Capo Press.
Osgood, Herbert L. 1896. “The Corporation as a Skocpol, Theda. 2003. Diminished Democracy: From
Form of Colonial Government,” parts 1–3. Political Membership to Management in American Civic
Science Quarterly 11(2–4):259–77, 502–33, Life. Norman, OK: University of Oklahoma Press.
694–715. Teaford, Jon. 1965. The Municipal Revolution in
Paskoff, Paul. 1983. Industrial Evolution: America. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
Organization, Structure, and Growth of the
Pennsylvania Iron Industry, 1750–1860. Baltimore, Thelen, Kathleen. 2003. “How Institutions Evolve:
MD: Johns Hopkins University Press. Insights From Comparative Historical Analysis.”
Perrow, Charles. 2002. Organizing America: Wealth, Pp. 208–40 in Comparative Historical Analysis in
Power, and the Origins of Corporate Capitalism. the Social Sciences, edited by J. Mahoney and D.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Rueschemeyer. New York: Cambridge University
Pierson, Paul. 2004. Politics in Time: History, Press.
Institutions, and Social Analysis. Princeton, NJ: Tocqueville, Alexis de. 1988. Democracy in America.
Princeton University Press.
Private and Special Statutes of the Commonwealth Translated by G. Lawrence. New York: Harper &
of Massachusetts, from the Year 1780 to the Close Row.
of the Session of the General Court, Begun and Tomlins, Christopher and Bruce H. Mann, eds. 2001.
Held on the Last Wednesday in May, A. D. 1805. The Many Legalities of Early America. Chapel
1805. Boston, MA: Manning & Loring. Hill, NC: University of North Carolina Press.
Province of the Massachusetts-Bay, Colonial Session Ware, Caroline F. 1931. The Early New England
Laws. N.d. Buffalo, NY: Hein Microf iche Cotton Manufacture: A Study in Industrial
Collection of State Session Laws.
Putnam, Robert D. 2000. Bowling Alone: The Beginnings. Boston, MA: Houghton Mifflin.
Collapse and Revival of American Community. Weber, Max. 1978. “Economy and Law (Sociology
New York: Simon & Schuster. of Law).” Economy and Society: An Outline of
Reid, John Phillip. 1987. Constitutional History of the Interpretive Sociology, edited by G. Roth and C.
American Revolution: The Authority to Tax. Wittich. Berkeley, CA: University of California
Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin Press. Press.
Richman, Irving Berdine. 1905. Rhode Island: A Williamson, Oliver E. 1981. “The Modern
Study in Separatism. Boston, MA: Houghton,
Mifflin. Corporation: Origins, Evolution, Attributes.”
Roy, William G. 1997. Socializing Capital: The Rise Journal of Economic Literature 19:1537–68.
of the Large Industrial Corporation in America. Zelizer, Viviana. 1994. The Social Meaning of Money.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. New York: Basic Books.

Вам также может понравиться