Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 36

Minority Presidents and Types of Government in Latin America

Gabriel L. Negretto
Centro de Investigación y Docencia Económicas (C.I.D.E)

Draft: March 2003

Prepared for delivery at the 2003 meeting of the Latin American Studies Association,
Dallas, Texas, March 27-29,2003
2

Abstract

A widely accepted argument among students of presidential regimes is that inter-


branch cooperation is impaired when the president´s party does not control a
majority of seats in congress. This argument, however, fails to take into account
three variables that should affect the performance of minority presidential
governments: the location of the president´s party in the policy space, the strength
of the executive veto and the formation of executive coalitions. Based on a new
typology of presidential regimes, I propose the hypothesis that the most conflictive
forms of minority government are those in which the president´s party does not
control the median legislator, the president lacks effective veto power, and a
majority or median minority executive coalition is not formed. Preliminary evidence
to sustain this hypothesis is provided with data on interrupted Latin American
presidencies in the period 1980-2002
3

Introduction

A rich literature on presidential regimes has repeatedly associated party fragmentation, and

its likely effect, minority presidents, with ineffective government, high levels of executive-

legislative conflict, and even democratic instability. So far, however, neither single-case

studies provide an accepted causal explanation of this association nor large-n statistical

studies prove beyond doubt that the relevant variables are significantly correlated. This

paper argues that the absence of conclusive theories or results is due to the lack of attention

to variables other than the share of seats of the president´s party in congress to explain the

different performance of minority presidential governments.

This paper proposes that there are several possible categories of minority government, not

all them in principle related to poor government performance. Using an analytic model of

executive-legislative relations, I argue that the most conflictive forms of minority

presidential government are those in which the president´s party does not control the

median legislator in congress, the president lacks effective veto power, and majority or

median minority executive coalitions are not formed. Preliminary evidence to sustain this

hypothesis is provided with data on interrupted Latin American presidencies in the period

1980-2002.

The argument is presented as follows. In section I, I critically review the literature on

minority presidential governments. Section II proposes a new typology of presidential

regimes and a series of hypotheses about inter-branch cooperation based on whether or not

the party of the president controls the pivotal legislators necessary to pass a bill or sustain a

veto. Section III analyzes the frequency at which majority coalitions or coalitions including
4

the median party in congress are formed in each type of government. In section IV, the

level of inter-branch conflict in new Latin American democracies is tested using data on the

early termination of a presidential term. I conclude by indicating the lines of research that

should follow from this study.

Presidentialism and minority government

The separate origin and survival of presidents and assemblies has been the source of

several hypotheses about the comparative performance of presidential democracies. The

most radical of them was initially proposed by Linz (1990, 1994) and other ‘critics’ of

presidentialism (Valenzuela 1994; Skach and Stepan 1994; Linz and Stepan 1996), who

argued that separate elections and fix terms induce inter-institutional conflict and make

difficult if not impossible the resolution of political crises. According to this view, the

‘fusion’ of powers induced by the logic of parliamentary constitutions is, under all political

conditions, a much better formula to foster effective and stable democracies.

In response to Linz and his colleagues, a new literature originated in the work of Shugart

and Carey (1992) and followed by a series of influential studies (Mainwaring 1993; Jones

1995: Mainwaring and Shugart 1997) proposed that not all presidential regimes are equally

problematic from the point of view of good governance. In particular, the so-called

‘defenders’ of presidentialism proposed that presidents should be able to govern effectively

when the ‘right’ electoral system, by containing party fragmentation, provides them with

partisan majorities in congress.1 For this literature, then, the problem is not presidentialism

per se but the ‘difficult’ combination of presidentialism and multipartysm that breeds weak

1
From this perspective, the ‘right’ combination of electoral variables is a president elected by plurality rule,
legislators elected by party-list PR with moderate district magnitudes and concurrent electoral cycles for the
election of presidents and assemblies. See Shugart and Carey (1992), Jones (1995), and Mainwaring and
Shugart (1997).
5

and ineffective minority presidents. From this perspective, parliamentarism is not

necessarily a better option than presidentialism, at least not than the majority type.

A new turn in the study of the comparative performance of constitutional regimes took

place after the large statistical study developed by Przewroski et al. (2000), which showed

that presidential regimes are indeed more vulnerable than parliamentary ones to democratic

breakdown. This means that there might be something wrong either with separation of

powers as such or with some (non-structural) institutional characteristic that presidential

regimes frequently present.

However, neither this study nor those that followed from it (Cheibub 2002; Cheibub and

Limongi 2002, Cheibub, Przeworski, and Saiegh 2002 ) provide much more than a list of

‘negative’ findings to explain the relatively low survival of presidential regimes. On the one

hand, Cheibub (2002) challenges the conventional wisdom that presidentialism and

multipartym is the worst combination for democratic stability by showing that minority

presidencies, even when they present conditions for deadlock, do not affect the survival of

democracy. 2 On the other hand, Cheibub, Przeworski, and Saiegh (2002) show that single-

party minority governments are not less effective than majority or minority coalition

governments and that the survival of presidential democracies is not affected by whether or

not presidents fail to generate coalitions. So far, the only explanations advanced for the

instability of presidential democracy are three, rather disparate hypotheses: the existence of

three relatively equal political parties, the frequency of presidential term limits, and

decentralized decision-making processes (Cheibub 2002; Cheibub and Limongi 2002).

2
He also indicates, however, that the survival of presidential democracies may be correlated with moderate
rather than with extreme levels of party fractionalization.
6

In spite of the significant progress made during the last decade, the main problem with the

current research on presidential regimes is that it still uses too crude a measure, namely the

share of seats of the president´s party in congress, to conceptualize different types of

presidential government and make predictions about their performance. The most glaring

example of this problem is the notion of minority or divided government. According to

almost all definitions, presidential government is ‘unified’ when the president´s party holds

more and ‘divided’ when it holds less than 50 percent of seats in congress (or in one

chamber, for bicameral assemblies).3 But while the concept of unified presidential

government is unambiguous, a number of substantially different situations can take place

once presidents fail to obtain majority support in the legislature.

One could expect, for instance, that if the president´s party is centrally located in the policy

space and a single dimension prevails, presidential proposals would be supported by a

legislative majority even if that party controls only a minority of congressional seats. In

other words, although opposition parties formally control the legislative process they may

be unable to agree on a policy different from the one proposed by the executive. A second

possible situation is that of a non-median minority president, but with an effective veto.

This reactive power could be skillfully used to forge tacit legislative coalitions on different

pieces of legislation that neither the president´s nor opposition parties have the power to

approve without mutual support. Finally, a non-median minority president, even without a

veto, may still be able to govern with relative effectiveness through an executive coalition

holding a majority of seats or including the median party in congress. Obviously enough,

one cannot derive the same consequences from all these forms of government.

3
Perhaps only Shugart (1995) departs from this conventional definition to restrict the term ‘ divided’
government to situations in which a party different from the president´s control more than 50 percent of the
seats in congress. As we will see later, this corresponds to the notion of ‘unified congressional’ government
that I propose below.
7

Since the size of the president´s party in congress is related to the number of parties holding

seats in congress, different authors also use the effective number of congressional parties to

explain the dynamics of minority governments. The typical statement here is that as

fractionalization increases, the size of the president´s party decreases thus making more

difficult to induce legislative support either by ad hoc negotiations with congress or by

making and maintaining majority executive coalitions (Mainwaring 1993, Jones 1995).

This association, however, does not amount to a real explanation of the relation between

fractionalization and executive-legislative conflict and/or regime stability. To see this,

compare two situations, one where a few large parties hold most of legislative seats and

another where many small parties hold a relatively equal share of seats.

Suppose that in the first situation the party of the president is located at the extreme left,

holding 40 percent of the seats, and that the main opposition party is a center-right party

holding 50 percent of the seats, followed by a small rightist party, with 10 percent of the

seats. The effective number of legislative parties here is 2.4. In the second situation, while

the party of the president is a centrist party holding 30 percent of the seats the 3 opposition

parties are distributed as follows: one in the center-left, holding 25 percent, one in the

center-right also with 25 percent, and one in the right with 20 percent. The effective

number of parties here is 3.9. Clearly enough, inter-branch cooperation should be extremely

more difficult in the first situation, even though the level of fractionalization is low.

This analysis indicates that any hypothesis or explanation about the consequences of

minority presidential government should start by taking into account not only the share of

seats of the president´s party in congress or the effective number of legislative parties but

also the location of the former in the policy space. I turn to this task in the next section.
8

Pivotal politics and types of presidential government

Using a modified version of Krehbiel´s model of pivotal politics (1996, 1998), it is possible

to create a typology of presidential governments according to the particular location of

three decisive actors: the president´s party (PP), the veto party (VP) and the median party

(MP) in congress (Colomer and Negretto 2003). PP is the party that controls the executive

office, VP is the party that controls the legislator whose support is crucial to override a

possible presidential veto, and MP is the party that controls the median legislator, that is,

the legislator whose proposals gather the support of a legislative majority. The central

assumptions of this model are 1) a unidimensional policy space, 2) single-peaked

preferences, 3) disciplined parties, and 4) absence of agenda-setters.

The central or single dimension of policy is assumed to be here the position of parties

regarding state intervention in the economy and the adoption of redistributive social

policies, where parties on the left support more and parties on the right support less state

intervention and redistributive policies, with parties on the center advocating a moderate

position. That preferences are single-peaked means that each player has an ideal point in

the policy space so that utility never increases as policies move away (in any direction)

from the player’s ideal point. The assumption of disciplined parties, in turn, means that the

median and veto legislators are expected to vote according to the policy position of the

party they represent in the legislature. The absence of an agenda-setter means, in turn, that

no special procedures give any player an advantage to get his or her proposals approved. I

will later show the different predictions one can obtain by changing this assumption.

Following this model, one can distinguish three basic forms of government in separation-

of-powers systems: presidential, divided, and congressional. As shown in Figure 1,

‘presidential’ government occurs whenever the president's party has the support of both the
9

veto and the median legislator. This form of government logically includes two possible

situations. One, which can properly be defined as ‘unified’ presidential government, derives

from an election in which the president´s party obtained more than 50 percent of the seats

in the assembly. The other, which can be labeled ‘median’ presidential government, takes

place whenever the president's party, even with less than 50 percent of legislative seats, is

appropriately located around the 'center' of the policy space.

While unified presidential government is usually the result of plurality formulas to elect

presidents and concurrent electoral cycles (Mainwaring and Shugart 1997), there is in

principle no institutional variable that guarantee that the president´s party, short of a

legislative majority, will be the median party in congress.4 The effective number of

legislative parties (ENP), which may be affected by electoral rules, is obviously related to

the location of presidential governments in one or the other category. While unified

presidential government is more likely when the effective number of legislative parties

approach a two-party setting (e.g. ENP 1.8-2.4), median presidential government is more

likely at a moderate level of multipartism (e. g. ENP 2.5-3.9).

[Figure 1 here]

Turning to hypotheses of government effectiveness and executive-legislative conflict, there

is no doubt that, other things being equal, a president whose party controls by itself a

majority of legislators should be more able than minority presidents to implement most of

4
According to Colomer (2001) and Colomer and Negretto (2003), majority runoff elections for president
result in the selection of median candidates in a higher proportion than in plurality elections. This does not
mean, however, that the party of the president would be in those cases the median party in congress. The
reason is that there may be more parties competing in the congressional election than parties presenting
candidates in the presidential election so that the medians in both election do not necessarily coincide.
10

his agenda with very little cost in terms of inter-branch negotiation. Thus the allure of

unified presidential government among many scholars. Nevertheless, if the analytic model

here presented holds, one should expect a minority president whose party is centrally

located in the policy space to be also more effective and face less executive-legislative

conflict than any other minority president.

A median minority president may be in this sense equivalent to the phenomenon of

minority governments in parliamentary regimes (Strom 1990; Laver and Schofield 1990).

As Laver and Schofield point out (1990: 80), even in a regime that by definition requires

majority legislative support to remain in power, a single-party minority government can be

a viable government if there is no majority coalition of opposition parties which can defeat

its proposals. If we apply this logic to presidential regimes, it is possible to argue that a

median presidential government should have a record of legislative success and democratic

stability not so different from unified presidential government.

Figure 2 shows what in strict sense we can call ´divided’ presidential government, that is, a

situation where the president´s party controls the veto legislator but a party other than the

president´s has the support of the median legislator in congress. Whenever elections are not

decisive in the sense of providing the same party with control over the presidency and the

legislature, the occurrence of divided government is determined by the effective number of

parties in the legislature and by the majorities required to override a presidential veto. In

particular, the probability of having a divided government should increase as the effective

number of legislative parties is equal or above 3 and the president can sustain a veto with

the support of relatively few legislators, such as one-third in a unicameral assembly or in

any of the two chambers in a bicameral assembly.


11

[Figure 2 here]

This definition of divided government is closely associated to the notion of ´deadlock’ that

many authors use (Przeworski et al; Cheibub 2002). This is so because it is precisely in this

type of government that a party (or parties) other than the president´s may gather a majority

to pass legislation and still be unable to change the status quo if the president prefers the

latter to the new policy and the legislative majority lacks the necessary votes to override his

veto. In other words, neither the president (who lacks a majority) nor the opposition parties

(who lack the votes to override a veto) are able to rule. The risk of a stalemate, of course,

is the reason why this type of presidential regime is often supposed to constitute the most

undecisive, costly, and conflictive form of minority government. But this association lacks

theoretical foundations.

The occurrence of gridlock under divided government depends on the location of the

legislative status quo and the policy preferences of the pivotal actors, in this case, the

president´s (or veto) party and the median party (Krehbiel 1998). If the initial status-quo

policy is located in between the preferences of the median party and the president with

effective veto, policy changes may be, in effect, impossible. The president will veto any

change approaching the outcome to the median party’s preference and moving it away from

the presidential one. It is for this reason that the policy space between the two decisive

actors defines the 'gridlock interval', that is, the set of policy decisions that will be stable in

spite of the existence of a legislative majority favoring policy change –as illustrated in

Figure 2.

But whenever the legislative status quo is outside the gridlock interval, policy change is

still possible. If the legislative status quo is located at a rather extreme position with respect
12

to the ideal points of the decisive actors, policy change may occur at exactly the ideal point

of the median party. This is so because the president will not veto proposals made by the

median party if they are closer to his preferences than the status quo is. In addition, if the

legislative status quo is outside the gridlock interval but closer to the preferences of the

president than the ideal point of the median party is, policy change is also possible if the

median party moderates its proposal to make the president at least indifferent between

using the veto or signing the bill. As Cameron (2000) point out, whenever the president

has an incentive to veto policy changes and congress knows it, the latter will anticipate the

veto and modify the content of the new policy to head it off.

In other words, policy immobilism is not a structural trait of divided government.

Presidents will support policy change when the new policy brings them more utility than

the status quo does and also when the legislative majority, anticipating a veto, modifies

legislation to induce the president to accept a new policy.

This does not mean, of course, that we should expect from divided government the same

level of government effectiveness and inter-branch cooperation as we can expect from

median presidential government. To the contrary, divided government is likely to produce

less legislative change and at higher cost than a minority but median presidential

government. In addition, we should expect divided government to produce gridlock from

time to time and, in the absence of perfect information among the players, inter-branch

conflict as well. The central point is simply that looking at divided government as the worst

possible situation for minority presidents may be looking at the wrong place.

Following the logic of this analysis, a third possible category of government in a

separation-of-powers system is that where a party different from the president´s controls

both the median and the veto legislator. To keep symmetry with the previous concepts we
13

can call this form of government ‘congressional’, which just like the ‘presidential’ one,

may include two possible situations. One, which we can call ‘unified congressional’, takes

place when a party different from the president´s controls not only 50 percent of the seats in

congress but also the number of seats necessary to override a presidential veto. This form of

government is likely to occur in two-party systems with a low veto override, usually an

absolute majority.5 A second situation, which we can call ‘median congressional’, is that

where the policy position of an opposition party allows it to control the veto and the median

legislator, even without having a majority of its own. This form of government is more

likely in multiparty presidential systems, also with a low veto override.

[Figure 3 here]

Congressional government is in principle the most complex form of government in a

separation-of-powers system. Not only the president has no control over the medial

legislator but he also lacks an effective veto. For this reason, everything else being equal,

one should expect congressional government to be less decisive and more conflictive than

both median presidential and divided government.

In Table I, I have listed the types of government that according to this classification have

existed in 18 Latin American countries since the last inauguration of a democratic regime.

Within each country, presidencies are classified according to the legislative share of the

president´s party and its policy location vis-à-vis the location of the median and the veto

party on a left-right scale. Whenever a nonconcurrent congressional election changed any

5
As we will see, the only two cases of unified congressional government in Latin America since the
beginning of the transition to democracy were the presidencies of Betancourt from 1982-86 and Pastrana from
1998-2002 in Colombia, a country that gathers the two characteristics just mentioned.
14

of these relative positions, the correspondent years of the presidency are counted as a

different case. According to this methodology, the table gathers 97 cases, of which 33

correspond to unified presidential government, 22 to median presidential government, 22 to

divided government and 21 to congressional government. The total number of minority

presidencies located in the median, divided, and congressional category represents a clear

majority of 64 cases, or 66 percent of the sample.

[Table I here]

It is important to note how this classification of presidential regimes, and the predictions

one can obtain from it, differs from the conventional analysis based on the levels of party

fragmentation. In the first place, as I noted before, it is not simply the ENP but the veto

override rule what matters to classify certain kinds of minority governments.

Both Chile under Alwyn (1989-94) and Perú under Fujimori I (1990-92) had an ENP in the

Lower House above 5. However, while the Chilean constitution requires 2/3 of the vote in

each chamber to override a presidential veto, in Perú congress could override a veto with

only a majority of votes in each chamber. Thus the classification of Chile´s Alwyn as

divided and Perú´s Fujimori I as congressional government. On the other hand, Colombia

under Betancourt (1982-86), and Pastrana (1998-2002) had an ENP in the Lower Chamber

of 1.97 and 2.09, respectively. However, since the president´s party did not reach a majority

of seats and the constitution required a majority of votes to override a veto, a party different

from the president´s was able to control the law-making process thus creating a unified

congressional government. Table II shows the relation between ENP, veto strength and

presidential types of government.


15

[Table II here]

Perhaps more important is the fact that even if we hold constant the ENP and veto override

rules within one country, presidencies may still differ according to the policy location of

the decisive players. Bolivia is the case in point. Both during the presidencies of Paz

Estenssoro and Siles Suazo the ENP in the Lower Chamber was above 4 and the

constitution required 2/3 of a joint session of congress to override a presidential veto.

Nevertheless, while Paz Estenssoro´s MNR occupied the position of the median party in

congress, Siles Suazo´s UDP had a rather extreme location in the policy space and

possessed only a veto to negotiate with the opposition. Logically, one cannot expect the

same consequences from these two very different cases of presidential governance.

Minority presidents and coalition-making

In the previous section I have argued that, other things being equal, congressional

government should be expected to be the least decisive and most conflictive form of

minority government. Yet, congressional government opens up different possibilities, not

all them implying the same negative consequences for democratic governance.

A non-median minority president who also lacks an effective veto has two basic options:

either to accept or to challenge congressional rule. Acquiescence to congressional rule

would usually take the form of a coalitional government in which non-median presidents

may try to overcome their disadvantage in congress by creating a majority executive

coalition or a minority coalition including the median party in congress. Defiance to

congressional rule, instead, would usually take the form of unilateral presidential
16

government, either by using powers granted by the constitution, like decrees, or by extra-

constitutional actions, like the usurpation of legislative powers or the irregular dissolution

of congress. Clearly enough, it is only when presidents prefer to challenge congressional

rule that congressional government should be the most problematic form of government in

a separation-of-powers system.

In order to explain this choice, we need to take a step back and look more closely at the

more general problem of coalition-making under presidential regimes.6 The separate origin

and survival of presidents and assemblies creates several structural differences between the

process of coalition-making in multiparty presidential and multiparty parliamentary

regimes. In the first place, whereas in a presidential regime the constitution establishes that

the president is the formateur regardless of the representation of his party in congress and

its policy location, in a parliamentary regime the formateur is usually the largest and/or the

median legislative party (Laver and Schofield 1990). In addition, while the autonomy of

presidents in terms of government formation is subject to variations, in a parliamentary

regime cabinets are strictly dependent on legislative support to obtain investiture and win

confidence votes. These differences, should and do make coalition governments a more

frequent event under parliamentarism than under presidentialism (Samuels and Eaton 2002;

Cheibub, Przeworski, and Saiegh 2002).

Within presidential regimes, however, one should expect variations in the frequency and

nature of coalitions depending on the type of government. Table III shows these variations

according to whether an executive coalition is formed, whether the party members of the

coalition hold together a majority of seats in congress, and whether a minority coalition

6
On cabinet coalitions in presidential regimes, see Deheza (1997), Amorim Neto (1998), Altman (2001),
Chasquetti (2001), and Amorim Neto (2001).
17

includes the median party in congress.7 An executive (or government) coalition is defined

here as the set of legislators belonging to parties that hold cabinet positions. This coalition

is considered to be a majority coalition only if the parties holding cabinet posts gather a

majority of seats in one chamber for unicameral assemblies or in both chambers for

bicameral assemblies.

[Table III here]

As one would expect, Table III shows that the frequency of executive coalition formation is

the lowest in unified presidential government (.22). The reason is that in this category,

obviously, presidents do not need outside support to accomplish their agendas. One of the

frequent reasons why presidents form coalitions in spite of the fact that their parties have

majorities in congress is the intention to integrate a ‘National Unity’ government in the

context of power-sharing agreements, as did Betancourt (1958-63) in Venezuela and the

Colombian presidents who continued the practice initiated with the National Front (1958-

74) until president Barco abandoned it (1986-90).

Among the different categories of ‘minority’ presidents, the lowest percentage of coalitions

in general (.28) and of majority coalitions in particular (.00) corresponds to divided

governments. In 2 out of 18 cases (.11), the presidencies of Alwyn (1989-94) and Frei

(1994-200) in Chile minority coalitions included the median party, but only for the

Chamber of Deputies.8 This case is not immediately intuitive but it may fit the logic of

divided government explained above. Since in this situation minority presidents have a

7
The presidencies of Pérez Balladares and Moscoso in Panamá were excluded due to the absence of
information.
8
The median position in the senate has been consistently occupied since 1989 by the RN, which for obvious
ideological reasons can never be part of a center-left executive coalition.
18

weapon (the veto) to force concessions from legislative majorities, they might not need an

executive coalition to influence policy. At the same time, it may be the case that in divided

government opposition parties also lack the incentives to give explicit support to the

government by joining an executive coalition. Since party fragmentation is on average

moderate in divided government, the median party (by definition the party whose support is

necessary to provide the president with the support of a legislative majority) may be one of

the main opposition parties which needs to differentiate its position from the government in

order to compete in coming presidential elections.

In median presidential governments coalitions are formed with a relatively high frequency

of 52 percent for coalitions in general and 38 percent for majority coalitions. A minority

president whose party controls the median legislator in congress may form a single-party

government and still be able to obtain majority support in congress. For the same reason,

however, a median president has nothing to lose in terms of policy and may actually obtain

some electoral benefit (in terms of public image, for instance) by incorporating outside

parties to the executive coalition. Opposition parties, in turn, may derive some utility from

office by supporting policies that they would approve anyway. This is precisely the

argument used in parliamentary regimes to explain why a median minority party, knowing

it will be dominant in policy terms, may either chose to form a single-party government, a

minimal winning or a surplus majority coalition (Laver and Schofield 1990).

Congressional government, in turn, is the minority government with the highest number of

coalitions. In 20 out 23 cases (.87) presidents in this category ruled through executive

coalitions. Given that congressional government on average occurs at relatively high levels

of party fragmentation, this result clearly shows that, against a previously held belief in the

literature, neither coalitions are rare in minority governments nor party fragmentation
19

makes coalition-making more difficult.9 The incentives of presidents to form executive

coalitions seem clear in the case of congressional government: neither their parties have a

pivotal role in policy-making nor they have an instrument, like the veto, to shape

legislation. At the same time, given the presence of many small parties in this type of

government it may be that parties in the opposition also have an interest in joining the

government either because they have no chance of winning coming presidential elections or

because even if they win, they will not be able to govern alone.

Yet, although most minority presidents in this category managed to incorporate outside

parties in the cabinet, not all them forged coalitions that would make congressional

government viable in policy terms. Of the 23 cases, only 9 (.39) presidents managed to

form a majority coalition. In addition, in 1 case (.04), the presidency of Lagos (2000-06) in

Chile, a minority coalition included the median party, but only in the Chamber of

Deputies. The obvious question, then, is why some presidents in congressional government

did while others did not form viable coalitions.

One possible answer is that not all presidents in this situation (regardless of the incentives

of opposition parties) may have the same incentives to rely on outside support to govern.

One of the assumptions of the pivotal model of decision-making outlined above was that no

player has special agenda-setting powers. In reality, however, many presidents do have

these powers and they can used them to change legislation without sufficient legislative

support. This is the case, in particular, with the ability of presidents to issue decrees of

legislative content. These powers may allow non-median minority presidents to change the

legislative status quo and impose a new policy if the median party in congress prefers the

latter to the reversionary outcome, that is, the outcome that would result from rejecting the

9
Cheibub, Przewroski and Saiegh (2002) show a similar finding.
20

decree after it produced effects (Figueiredo and Limongi 1998; Negretto forthcoming). If

this is the case, then, a president invested with these powers may not feel the need to rely

on a majority coalition as much as a president without them.

At the same time, the incentives of presidents to make viable coalitions may also be

determined by their degree of autonomy in terms of the formation and maintenance of

cabinets. In spite of the separate origin of presidents and assemblies that characterizes

presidential regimes, there is wide range of variation in terms of congressional control over

cabinets (Shugart and Carey 1992; Colomer and Negretto 2003). A president who has the

formal power to appoint and remove cabinet members may be in fact restricted in his

degree of autonomy if legislators are able to vote a binding censure or impeach ministers

by majority vote. The same could happen if in the absence of majority winners in a

presidential election, congress regularly intervenes in the final selection of presidents,

somewhat resembling the investiture vote in a parliamentary system.

With these elements in mind, we can make sense of the choice that minority presidents in a

congressional form of government have. The incentives to accept congressional rule by

building a portfolio coalition large enough to muster majority support in congress should be

greater when presidents are subject to congressional control and have no decree powers

than when they face no congressional control and/or have decree powers.10 Table IV lists

the information about coalition-making in congressional government along with the

relevant institutional variables for each case. A president was considered to have decree

powers if the constitution explicitly grants him the authority to initiate policy by decree

(constitutional decree authority or CDA) or when general emergency provisions include the

capacity of presidents to make law and regulate rights by decree. A congress was
10
Amorim Neto and Tafner (2002) and Amorim Neto (2002) show that there is a relation between the use and
existence of decree powers and coalition-making strategies.
21

considered to have control over cabinets when presidents are selected by congress or when

legislators from opposition parties had the necessary votes established by the constitution to

propose and decide a binding censure and/or impeach ministers.11

[Table IV here]

According to this table, a large majority of 18, out of 23 presidents in the category of

congressional government had the capacity to issue decrees of legislative content. Only 6

(.26) of these presidents formed policy viable coalitions while 13 of them (.56) either did

not form coalitions or formed a non-median minority coalition. In addition, while 13

presidents were subject to congressional control, only in 3 cases ( 2 in Bolivia and 1 in

Uruguay) presidents were both subject to congressional control and had no decree powers.

In these 3 cases presidents formed majority executive coalitions.

This analysis cannot conclusive since too many presidents in this category hold explicit or

residual decree powers. In fact, there may be a causal relation between minority presidents

in congressional governments and strong proactive powers.12 Whatever the reason,

however, it may be the frequent presence of decree powers what explains why if the

number of coalitions is so high in congressional government so few of them hold a majority

of seats in congress or have the support of the median party in congress.

To sum up, not all minority presidents inevitably need a majority coalition to influence

policy and secure a minimum of inter-branch cooperation. Some minority presidents can

11
Opposition parties usually reach the necessary votes to control cabinets when the constitution requires a
vote by absolute majority in congress but congressional control could also exist with a requirement of two-
thirds if the president lacks the support of more than one-third of legislators.
12
The existence of a correlation between CDA and separation of purpose in presidential regimes has been
indicated by Shugart (1998) and Shugart and Haggard (2001).
22

compensate their lack of majority support with their control over the median legislator in

congress or with their veto power. Coalition-making, however, may be crucial for minority

presidents in congressional government and those who fail to do so in this category are

expected to be the most problematic of all minority presidencies.

Interrupted presidencies in Latin America

There are several possible indicators to test the hypothesis that minority presidencies are

different in nature and present different potential for government effectiveness and

executive-legislative conflict. For government effectiveness, the percentage of bills

initiated by presidents and approved by congress is one possible indicator (Saiegh 2002).

For executive-legislative conflict, one could construct an index to measure the number of

conflicts that each presidency experienced in terms of legislation and inter-institutional

conflict (Jones 1995). However, in the absence of these data for all the presidencies within

the period under consideration I will provisionally rely on a more crude but nonetheless

significant indicator of presidential performance: the regular termination of the

constitutionally defined presidential term.

Presidents may end their constitutional terms prematurely either because they are ousted

from office after a successful impeachment process, because they are forced to resign after

the emergence of widespread social mobilizations against the government or a coup, or

because they decide to dissolve congress as a way to govern effectively in the face of a

particular crisis. Within the third wave of democracy in Latin America, there are 11 cases

of interrupted presidencies. Table V provides a list of these presidencies indicating the

president, year and reason for termination.


23

[Table V here]

In 4 cases (Collor, Pérez, Bucaram, and Cubas), presidencies were terminated in the context

of a process of impeachment either initiated or concluded by congress, and in 1 case

(Suazo) in the context of a series of executive-legislative conflicts that included the threat

of impeachment. In 3 cases presidents resigned or abandoned the office, 2 times (Alfonsín

and De la Rúa) due to social mobilizations against the government and 1 time (Mahuad)

due to an attempted coup. Finally, in 3 cases (Fujimori, Serrano and Chávez) presidents

terminated their terms by their own decision to rule without the existing congress, although

in 1 case (Serrano) the president failed in his attempt.

In spite of these variations, the premature termination of a presidential term signals the

breakdown of cooperation between presidents and congresses. Whatever the nature of the

crisis that presidents and legislators had to face, it seems clear that either congress or the

president saw the potential solution in the elimination of the other. From this perspective,

the forced resignation or impeachment of presidents, on the one hand, or the dissolution of

congress by presidents, on the other, are two possible non-cooperative outcomes of a

bargaining game between executives and legislators.

According to the hypothesis presented in this paper presidential regimes can be located in a

continuum that goes from a maximum to a minimum of expected cooperation between

separate branches of government. The maximum corresponds to unified presidential

governments and the minimum to congressional governments without majority (or median

minority) executive coalitions. The intermediate categories are median presidential,

divided, and coalitional congressional government. In order to support this hypothesis, one

should see some correlation between expected levels of cooperation and the number of
24

interrupted presidencies in each category. Table VI shows the existence of such a

correlation.

[Table VI here]

As expected, unified presidential government has the lowest (.03) and minority

congressional government the highest (.38) percentage of interrupted presidencies. Also as

expected, median presidential governments indicate a lower percentage of inter-branch

conflicts than divided governments. Coalitional congressional governments, in turn, have

no cases of interruption of presidential terms.

This does not necessarily mean that coalitional congressional government is free from

conflicts but, rather, that the difference between having or not the support of a majority or

median coalition is crucial when the president does not have a veto or control the median

legislator in congress. So crucial, indeed, that it may turn the most problematic form of

minority presidential government into a successful one.

It is suggestive to note that most minority congressional governments in which presidents

did finish their terms in office also presented high levels of executive-legislative conflict

that could have ended in the same way as those who did not. The presidencies of Febres

Cordero, Borja (for the period 1990-92), and Durán-Ballén in Ecuador are all well-known

cases of government infectiveness and executive-legislative conflict.

All of these presidents intended to alleviate Ecuador´s fiscal crisis and debt problems by

means of austerity policies that were paralyzed or watered-down in congress. In addition,

and as a demonstration of congressional reaction to massive social protests generated by

those policies, opposition legislators continuously harassed the president through the
25

impeachment of his ministers (Conaghan 1995: 452-53; Isaacs 1996). In fact, in the last

year of Borja´s presidency, congress formally requested the Supreme Court to initiate

impeachment procedures against the president himself and in 1995 (after the censure of

several of his ministers) congress impeached Durán-Ballén’s vice-president. Durán-Ballén

responded with a failed attempt to call a constitutional reform to strengthen the powers of

the president vis-á-vis the congress.

Other presidencies in this category also present similar indicators of conflict. President

Pastrana, á la Chávez, intended but failed to call a referendum on constitutional reform that

included cutting the number of congressional seats by half and calling new congressional

elections. During Wasmosy’s presidency in Paraguay, executive and legislators were

engaged in a bitter conflict that included a threat by congress to impeach the president.

Finally, both terms of Caldera became a symbol of problematic presidencies in Venezuela.

During his first presidency, Caldera faced permanent obstruction from congress and

institutional attacks that eventually led to a constitutional crisis when the opposition

approved a law depriving the president from his participation in the nomination of judges

(Coppedge 1994: 339).13 In his second presidency, Caldera decided to face the deep

economic crisis affecting the country by suspending economic rights and implementing

economic measures by decree (Crisp 2000). Once congress attempted to restore those

rights, it was forced to back down by Caldera’s threat to call a referendum on a proposal of

constitutional reform which would have enabled him to dissolve congress.14

In other words, if we were to measure the performance of presidential democracies under

less dramatic measures of conflict than the early termination of a constitutional term, we

13
Accodring to Coppedge (1994: 339), those institutional attacks included at one point AD´s attempt to
change the presidential regime into a parliamentary one.
14
See Latin America Weekly Report, 11/08/94
26

would probably find that the number of critical cases within minority congressional

government is much larger than the one presented here. This calls, of course, for a

continuation of this research with more exhaustive tests.

Conclusions

Since the early 1990’s, the idea that presidential regimes are inherently unstable has been

replaced by the hypothesis that it is not presidentialism but the combination of

presidentialism, multipartysm, and low levels of party discipline what affects government´s

effectiveness and democratic survival in separation-of-powers systems. As a consequence,

most research on presidentialism has focused since then on the electoral variables that are

supposed to contain party fragmentation, grant the president substantive congressional

support and secure at least moderate levels of party discipline.

The ‘difficult combination’ hypothesis is today under attack by a series of studies that

question the correlation between multipartysm, legislative effectiveness and democratic

survival and point out to other variables, such as presidential term limits or the degree of

centralization of decision-making to explain the performance of presidential regimes. To

date, however, no study has provided a plausible and theoretically grounded explanation of

the causal mechanisms that foster or hinder cooperation between executives and legislators

in minority presidential governments.

This paper is a first attempt to elaborate such an explanation. I have argued that different

forms of presidential government should be distinguished taking into account not only the

size of the president´s party in congress but also its location in the policy space and its

relation with two pivotal actors: the median and the veto legislator. Following this logic, I

proposed that there is a continuum from more to less expected cooperation between
27

presidents and assemblies that goes from unified presidential to congressional government,

with minority median and divided government in between. I have also suggested that

congressional government is the least effective and most conflictive form of minority

government only when presidents fail or do not attempt to build executive coalitions

holding a majority of seats or including the median party in congress.

In order to test this hypothesis, I used the constitutional (impeachment, forced resignation)

or unconstitutional (coups) interruption of a presidential term as an indicator of terminal

institutional conflict between presidents and assemblies and found that the hypothesis,

although not probed, is at least plausible. Of the 11 presidents that left office before the

term specified in the constitution, the largest percentage corresponded to the predicted most

conflictive category. Although the number of cases was small, no constitutional term was

interrupted when presidents in congressional governments formed majority coalitions

suggesting that coalition-making may indeed be a key variable to explain government

survival under difficult circumstances.

The analysis provided in this paper suggests that research on presidential democracies

should shift from its exclusive focus on electoral variables affecting the effective number of

parties to the electoral and institutional variables that make cooperation between branches

possible in the absence of a legislative majority supporting the president in congress. In this

respect, a new research agenda should pay attention to the electoral formulas that make

more likely than others the selection of presidents whose parties occupy a median position

in congress, the influence of presidential vetoes on policy output, and the interaction

between the proactive legislative powers of presidents and congressional control over

cabinets over the likelihood of majority coalition formation.


28

Decisive actors in Congress

Figure 1. Presidential government

Outcome

President’s party

President Veto Median


legislator legislator
Figure 2. Divided government

Gridlock interval

President’s party Median party

President Veto Median


legislator legislator

Figure 3. Congressional government

Outcome

President’s party Median party

President Veto Median


legislator legislator
29

Table I. Types of Government in Latin America

Presidential Divided Congressional


Unified Unified
Argentina 1995-97 (Menem II) Argentina 1983-89 (Alfonsín) Colombia 1982-86 (Betancourt)
Colombia 1974-78 (L: Michelsen) Bolivia 1980-85 (S. Suazo) Colombia 1998-2002 (Pastrana)
Colombia 1978-82 (Turbay) Chile 1989-94 (Alwyn) Median
Colombia 1986-90 (Barco) Chile 1994-2000 (Frei) Argentina 1999-2001 (De la Rua)
Colombia 1990-94 (Gaviria) Costa Rica 1966-70 (T. Fernandez) Bolivia 1989-93 (P. Zamora)
Colombia 1994-98 (Samper) Costa Rica 1978-82 (C. Odio) Bolivia 1997-2001 (Bánzer)
Costa Rica 1953-58 (Figueres I) Costa Rica 2002-06 (Pacheco E.) Brazil 1985-90 (Sarney)
Costa Rica 1962-66 (Orlich) Dom. Rep. 1986-90 (Balaguer) Brazil 1990-92 (Collor)
Costa Rica 1970-74 (Figueres II) Dom. Rep. 1990-94 (Balaguer) Brazil 1992-94 (Franco)
Costa Rica 1982-86 (Monge A.) Dom. Rep. 1994-96 (Balaguer) Brazil 1994-98 (Cardozo I)
Costa Rica 1986-90 (Arias S.) Dom. Rep. 1998-2000 (F. Reyna) Brazil 1998-2002 (Cardozo II)
Costa Rica 1990-94 (Calderón F.) Dom. Rep. 2002-04 (H. Mejía) Chile 2000-06 (Lagos)
Costa Rica 1998-2002 (Rodriguez) Ecuador 1998-2002 (Mahuad) Ecuador 1984-88 (F. Cordero)
Dom. Rep. 2000-02 (Hipólito M.D.) El Salvador 1988-89 (Duarte) Ecuador 1990-1992 (Borja)
El Salvador 1985-88 (Duarte) El Salvador 1991-94 (Cristiani) Ecuador 1992-96(Durán-Ballén)
El Salvador 1989-91 (Cristiani) El Salvador 1994-99 (Calderón) Guatemala 1991-95 (Serrano)
Guatemala 1986-91 (Cerezo) El Salvador 1999-2002 (Flores) Paraguay 1993-98 (Wasmosy)
Guatemala 1995-99 (Arzú) Mexico 2000-2003 (Fox) Perú 1990-92 (Fujimori I)
Guatemala 1999-2003 (Portillo) Panamá 1999-2004 (Moscoso) Uruguay 1989-94 (Lacalle)
Honduras 1981-85 (Suazo Córdoba) Total divided=19 Venezuela 1968-73 (Caldera I)
Honduras 1985-89 (Azcona) Venezuela 1978-83 (H. Campins)
Honduras 1989-93 (Callejas) Venezuela 1993-98 (Caldera II)
Honduras 1993-97 (Reina) Venezuela 1998-2000 (Chávez I)
Honduras 1997-2001 (Flores) Venezuela 2000-2006 (Chávez II)
Nicaragua 1990-96 (Barrios) Total congressional=23
Nicaragua 2001-06 (Bolaños)
Paraguay 1989-93 (Rodriguez)
Paraguay 1998-2002 (Cubas/ G. M)
Perú 1985-90 (Alan García)
Perú 1995-2000 (Fujimori II)
Venezuela 1958-63 (Betancourt)
Venezuela 1973-78 (Andres Pérez I)
Venezuela 1983-88 (Lusinchi)
30

Table I (cont.)
Median
Argentina 1989-95 (Menem I)
Argentina 1997-99 (Menem II)
Bolivia 1985-89 (P- Estenssoro)
Bolivia 1993-97 (S. De Lozada)
Costa Rica 1958-62 (Echandi)
Costa Rica 1974-78 (Oduber Q.)
Costa Rica 1994-98 (Figueras)
Dom. Rep. 1996-98 (F. Reyna)
Ecuador 1979-84 (Roldós/Hurtado)
Ecuador 1988-90 (R. Borja)
Ecuador 1992-96 (A. Bucaram)
Honduras 2001-05 (Maduro)
Mexico 1997-2000 (Zedillo)
Nicaragua 1996-2001 (Alemán)
Panamá 1994-99 (P. Balladares)
Perú 1980-85 (Belaúnde)
Perú 2000-05 (Toledo)
Uruguay 1984-89 (Sanguinetti)
Uruguay 1994-99 (Sanguinetti)
Uruguay 1999-2004(Battle)
Venezuela 1963-68 (Leoni)
Venezuela 1988-93 (Andrés Pérez II)
Total presidential= 55

Source: elaborated by the author, in collaboration with Josep Colomer, based on “Elections
around the world”(URL:http://www.electionworld.org),and Jorge A. Schiavon
(URL:http://www.cide.edu/investigadores/jorge_schiavon/electoral.html),for electoral data,
and Coppedge (1997), for party policy positions
31

Table II: ENP, Veto Strength and Type of Governme nt

Average ENP Range ENP % strong veto Type of government


2.33 1.89-2.98 59 Unified presidential
3.32 2.29-5.0 54 Median presidential
3.5 2.1-6.5 100 Divided
4.8 1.97-8.68 25 Congressional

Table III. Frequency and Type of Executive Coalitions

Type of Government Executive coalitions Majority coalitions Median coalitions


Unified presidential .21 - -
Median presidential .52 .38 -
Divided .28 .00 .11
Congressional .87 .39 .04

Table IV. Coalition-Making in Congressional Governments


Presidency Coalition Majority Median Decree powers Congressional control
De la Rúa Yes No No Yes (CDA) Yes
Paz Zamora Yes Yes No No Yes
Bánzer Suarez Yes Yes No No Yes
Sarney Yes Yes Yes Yes (CDA) No
Collor Yes No No Yes (CDA) No
Franco Yes Yes Yes Yes (CDA) No
Cardoso I Yes Yes Yes Yes (CDA) No
Cardoso II Yes Yes Yes Yes (CDA) No
Lagos Yes No Yes No* No
Betancourt Yes Yes Yes Yes (CDA) No
Pastrana Yes No No Yes (CDA) Yes
Febres Cordero No - - Yes (CDA) Yes
Rodrigo Borja Yes No No Yes (CDA) Yes
Durán-Ballén Yes No No Yes (CDA) Yes
Serrano Yes No No Yes (emergency) Yes
Wasmosy No - - No No
Fujimori I Yes No No Yes (emergency) Yes
Lacalle Yes Yes Yes No Yes
Caldera I Yes No No Yes (emergency) Yes
H. Campins No - - Yes (emergency) No
Caldera II Yes No No Yes (emergency) Yes
Chávez I Yes No No Yes (emergency) Yes
Chávez II Yes Yes Yes Yes (emergency) No

Source: Elaborated by the author based on Zucco (2002) and Cidob.com for coalitions, and Political Data
Base of the Americas for decree powers and congressional control
*CDA restricted to budget
Total cases=23
Cases with executive coalition= 20
Cases with majority or median minority coalition=10
32

Table V. Interrupted presidencies in Latin America 1980-2001

President Month/Year Motive


Siles Suazo November/1984 Forced resignation in the context of an
economic crisis, social upheaval, threat of a
coup, and executive-legislative conflicts,
including a threat of impeachment
Alfonsín July/1989 Forced resignation in the midst of an
economic crisis and social upheaval
Fujimori April/1992 Dissolution of congress by president with
support of the military after a series of
executive-legislative conflicts on the
powers of the president to rule by decree on
the areas of economic management and
terrorism
Collor August/1992 Impeachment by congress due to charges of
corruption in the midst of an economic
crisis, social upheaval and a long series of
executive-legislative conflicts
Serrano May/ 1993 Forced resignation after a failed attempt to
dissolve congress and rule with support of
the military
Andrés Pérez II August/1993 Destitution by congress due to charges of
corruption initiated after a violent social
upheaval against the president´s economic
policy and a failed coup
Bucarám February/1997 Destitution by congress under the charges
of mental incapacity initiated after social
social mobilizations against the president´s
economic policy and the alleged corruption
of the government
Cubas March /1999 Resignation after impeachment process
initiated by the chamber of deputies
Chávez April/1999 Convocation of an irregular constituent
assembly that terminated the previous
constitutional period and replaced existing
congress
Mahuad January/2000 Abandonment of presidency after social
upheaval and an attempted coup
De la Rúa December/2001 Forced resignation due to social
mobilization against De la Rúa´s economic
policy and after the opposition in congress
rejected the possibility of a national union
coalition to support the government
33

Table VI. Interrupted presidencies per type of government

Type Cases Interrupted presidencies Percentage


Unified presidential 33 1 .03
Median presidential 22 2 .09
Divided 19 3 .16
Coalitional congressional 10 0 .00
Minority congressional 13 5 .38
34

Bibliography

Amorim Neto, Octavio.1998. “Of Presidents, Parties and Ministers: Cabinet Formation and
Legislative Decision-Making Under Separation of Powers.” Unpublished PhD
dissertation, University of California, San Diego
_____________________.2002.”Presidential Policy-Making Strategies and Cabinet
Formation in Latin America´s Presidential Democracies, 1946-1995. Paper
presented at the conference on “El Gobierno Dividido en México: Riesgos y
Oportunidades,”May 6-7. 2002, C.I.D.E, Mexico City
Amorim Neto, Octavio y Paulo Tafner. (2002). “Governos de Coalizao e Mecanismos de Alarme e
Incendio no Controle Legislativo das Medidas Provisorias.” Dados, 45 (1), 5-38
Cameron, Charles M. 2000. Veto Bargaining. Presidents and the Politics of Negative
Powers. Nueva York: Cambridge University Press.
Carey, John y Matthew S. Shugart. 1998 eds. Executive Decree Authority. Nueva York:
Cambridge University Press.
Chasquetti, Daniel. 2001. “Democracia, Multipartidismo, y Coaliciones en América Latina:
Evaluando la Difícil Combinación.”In Jorge Lanzaro (ed.), Tipos de
Presidencialismo y Coaliciones Políticas en América Latina. Buenos Aires:
CLACSO.
Cheibub, José Antonio.2002. “Minority Presidents, Deadlock Situations, and the Survival
of Presidential Democracies.”Unpublished manuscript, Yale University.
Cheibub, José Antonio, Adam Przeworski, and Sebastían Saiegh. 2002. “Government
Coalitions and Legislative Effectiveness Under Presidentialism and
Parliamentarism, unpublished manuscript.
Cheibub, José Antonio, and Fernando Limongi. 2002. “Modes of Government Formation
and the Survival of Presidential Regimes: Presidentialism and Parliamentarism
Reconsidered.”Annual Review of Political Science.
Colomer, Josep and Gabriel Negretto. 2003. “Governanza con Poderes Divididos en
América Latina.” Política y Gobierno, January-March.
Conaghan, Catherine M. 1995. “Politicians Against Parties: Discord and Disconnection in
Ecuador’s Party System.” In Scott Mainwaring and Timothy Scully. Building
Democratic Institutions: Party Systems in Latin America, Stanford: Stanford
University Press.
Coppedge, Michael. 1994. “Venezuela: Democratic despite Presidentialism,” in Juan Linz
and Arturo Valenzuela (eds.). The Failure of Presidential Democracy. Baltimore:
The Johns Hopkins University Press.
______________ 1997. “A Classification of Latin American Political Parties.” Working
Paper #244, Kellog Institute, University of Notre Dame.
Crisp, Brian. 2000. Democratic Institutional Design: The Powers and Incentives of
Venezuelan Politicians and Interest Groups. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Deheza, Grace Ivana. 1998. “Gobiernos de coalición en el sistema presidencial: America
del Sur,” in Dieter Nohlen and Mario Fernández (eds.). El presidencialismo
renovado: Institucionalismo y cambio político en America Latina. Caracas: nueva
Sociedad: 151-169.
35

Figueiredo, Argelina Chebub, y Feranado Limongi. 1998. “Institutional legacies and


accountability: executive decrees in Brazil and Italy.” Paper presented at the
Conference on Institutional Legacies, Buenos Aires.
Isaacs, Anita. 1996. “Ecuador: Democracy Standing the Test of Time?”. In Jorge
Domínguez and Abraham Lowenthal (eds.), Constructing Democratic Governance:
South America in the 1990s. Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press.
Jones, Mark P. 1995. Electoral Laws and the Survival of Presidential Democracies. Notre
Dame, Ind.: University of Notre Dame Press.
Krehbiel, Keith. 1996. “Institutional and Partisan Sources of Gridlock: A Theory of
Divided and Unified Government', Journal of Theoretical Politics, 8: 7-40.
-- 1998. Pivotal Politics: A Theory of U.S. Lawmaking. Chicago: The University of
Chicago Press.
Lanzaro, Jorge ed. 2001. Tipos de presidencialismo y coaliciones políticas en América
Latina. Buenos Aires: CLACSO.
Laver, Michael y Kenneth Shepsle. 1991. “Divided Government: America Is Not
Exceptional”, Governance, 4, 3, 250-69.
Linz, Juan J. 1990a. “The Perils of Presidentialism”, Journal of Democracy, 1, 1: 51- 69.
-- 1990b. 'The Virtues or Parliamentarism,” Journal of Democracy, 1, 4: 84-91.
Linz, Juan y Arturo Valenzuela eds. 1994. The Failure of Presidential Democracy.
Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press.
Mainwaring, Scott. 1993. “Presidentialism, Mutipartism, and Democracy: The Difficult
Combination”, Comparative Political Studies, 26: 198- 228.
Mainwaring, Scott, and Timothy Scully (eds.). 1995. Building Democratic Institutions:
Party Systems in Latin America, Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Mainwaring, Scott y Matthew S. Shugart eds. 1997. Presidentialism and Democracy in
Latin America. Nueva York: Cambridge University Press.
Negretto, Gabriel., forthcoming. ´Government Capacities and Policy-Making by Decree in
Latin America: The Cases of Brazil and Argentina´, Comparative Political Studies.
Nohlen, Dieter y Mario Fernández B. eds. 1998. El presidencialismo renovado. Caracas:
Nueva Sociedad.
Przeworski, Adam, Michael E. Alvarez, José A. Cheibub y Fernando Limogi. 2000.
Democracy and Development. Nueva York: Cambridge University Press.
Shugart, Mattthew. 1995. “The Electoral Cycle and Institutional Sources of Divided
Government.” American Political Science Review 89 (2): 327-43
Saiegh. Sebastían. 2002. “Coalition-Formation, Cross-Voting and Legislative Success: A
Model of Presidential Policymaking with Application to Argentina. Paper presented
at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Boston,
August 29-September 1, 2002
Samuels, David, and Kent Eaton. “Presidentialism And, Or, and Versus Parliamentarism:
The State of the Literature and an Agenda for Future Research. Paper presented at
the Conference on Consequences of Political Institutions in Democracy, Duke
University, April-5-7, 2002.
Shugart, Matthew S. y John M. Carey. 1992. Presidents and Assemblies. Constitutional
Design and Electoral Dynamics. Nueva York: Cambridge University Press.
Shugar, Matthew. 1998. “The Inverse Relation Between Party Strength and Executive
Strength: A Theory of Politicians’ Constitutional Choices.” British Journal of
Political Science, 28, 1-29.
36

Strom, Kaare. 1990. Minority Government and Majority Rule. Cambridge, Mass.:
Cambridge University Press.

Вам также может понравиться