Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 2

692 IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON POWER SYSTEMS VOL. 19, NO.

1, FEBRUARY 2004

paper], may contain flat regions. This is consequence of the fact that REFERENCES
each generating unit is supposed to have a constant marginal cost; this [1] J. Villar and H. Rudnick, “Hydrothermal market simulator using game
implies that the offer curve of the price-taker firms contains flat regions. theory: Assessment of market power,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 18,
As a result, the residual demand curve will also contain flat regions; pp. 91–98, Feb. 2003.
[2] R. Palma, O. Moya, and H. Rudnick, “Fondecyt Research Project
therefore, the demand curve faced by each unit (in the game by units) 1 020 801,” Interim Rep., Santiago, Chile, Mar. 2003.
or by each firm (in the game by firms) will also present them.
The problem is that these flat regions imply discontinuities in the
marginal benefit curve faced by each agent (unit or firm). For a given
unit or firm, this may mean the existence of multiple local maximum.
However, this is not a problem by itself, since the solution methods
used for the decoupled problems in both game strategies assure that Discussion of “Unbundled Reactive Support Service: Key
the global maximum benefit for the unit or firm is obtained as a result.1
Characteristics and Dominant Cost Component”
Nevertheless, this fact may still lead to multiple equilibria. This is
because small variations in the generation of other units or firms may P. Marannino and F. Zanellini
result that one of them, in particular, reacts with comparatively large
jumps in its own production.
The authors [1] have to be congratulated for the very interesting paper
It must be remembered that this problem arises due to the attempt
where they clearly outline the key characteristics of the reactive power
of explicitly modeling the discontinuities of the functions of the price-
support service in the emerging competitive electricity market environ-
taker firms; a problem that is often ignored in most of the studies on
ment. The incoming liberalization is pushing power system engineers
the matter, including those that consider supply curve models instead
to develop new methodologies for the evaluation of the contributions of
of Cournot models. There is not a manageable form to consider this
different reactive power sources to the system security and stability [2].
aspect in supply function models. Therefore, it is possible to eliminate
Voltage and reactive power control played a very important role in the
this problem by making simplifications with respect to the behavior of
vertically integrated electric systems, aimed to minimize real power
the price-taker firms or, simply, forgetting their existence and assuming
losses, to maintain adequate voltage profiles, even in the presence of
that all of the firms act strategically.
system component outages, and to avoid voltage collapse or instability
Experience has demonstrated that in those cases where market power
phenomena. In the new deregulated and unbundled structure, the reac-
is potentially more intensive, usually the cases where the price-taker
tive support is a fundamental ancillary service at disposal of the ISO,
firms have a small effect in the price, the multiple equilibria problem
responsible of the maintenance of the security and quality levels im-
is not present in the Cournot model. This is precisely the situation of
posed by the central government authority. In addition, the particular
the study case, the Chilean Central Interconnected System, where the
characteristics of the service need to save a certain degree of centralized
price-taker firms are comparatively very small, and the potential of ex-
management with a reduced possibility of a system-wide competitive
ercising market power on the part of the other market players seems
market due to the local nature of reactive power. In the paper the anal-
very important. This phenomenon is consistent with the fact that when
ysis on the reactive support cost is addressed to specify the so-called
these firms are small, the flat regions of the demand curves are smaller,
“dominant component” of variable cost. It is the opportunity cost con-
and the jumps that take place in the offers of the generators are not so
sequent to the obligation given by the ISO to the producer to curtail
meaningful.
part of the real power production (revenue losses) when the generator
Therefore, in the Chilean case, it is better not to make simplifications
hits the capability limits in order to satisfy additional reactive power
in the treatment of the price-taker firms, because of their small size and
requirements. The authors put in evidence the dominant position of the
because the multiple equilibria problem does not seem to arise; at least it
ISO in posting decision consequent to his definition of the system op-
was not evident in the multiple simulations and revisions that were made.
erating security constraints.
However, it should be recognized that the obtained results represent,
Our comments are related to the role of the ISO in the voltage and
in general, one of potentially several equilibria. Nevertheless, it is prac-
reactive power control and to the computational tools it can employ
tically sure that the equilibrium with higher prices is the most beneficial
for the definition of a nondiscriminatory reactive support. Considering
for each strategic firm. In a repetitive exercise such as this, it is rea-
only the support given by the synchronous generators, the control
sonable to expect that the firms will move toward the most beneficial
schema adopted assumes a paramount importance. The decision
break-even point (of the possible equilibria). The experience of several
making variables are the terminal voltages of the generators, if only
researchers that have analyzed the multiple equilibria in the Cournot
the primary voltage regulation is active, the voltage setting points of
model seems to indicate that the equilibrium obtained with an iterative
the so-called “pilot nodes” and the area reactive levels, if the secondary
algorithm ([1], Figs. 1 and 2) is that of the higher price of all the pos-
and the tertiary voltage regulation are present [3]. The settlement of
sible multiple equilibria (first reference in the paper [1]).
the allowable voltage levels in the different busses of the system, as
Thanks again to Dr. Hogan and Dr. Barroso for their contribution to
shown in the paper, has a deep impact on reactive power output of the
this research.
generators. It has to be determined in order to maintain the system at
1In the case of the game strategy by units, the price ranges where demand the needed security level, avoiding the risk of hard interventions of
faced by each unit does not contain flat regions are analyzed separately; there- the ISO, like the curtailment of specified transactions. In the opinion
fore, discontinuities in the marginal benefit function do not appear. Thus, all of of the discussers the use of a Security Constrained Optimal Reactive
the local optimum can be found analytically and the global optimum may be se-
lected by comparison. In the case of the game strategy by firms, as the decoupled
problems are very complex because of the high number of variables (real and
integer), a search method by computational inspection was used; it also assures Manuscript received April 25, 2002.
to find the global optimum. This is based on the fact that the solution is sought The authors are with the Department of Electrical Engineering, Università
proving a discreet number, but sufficiently large, of possible clearing prices; degli Studi di Pavia, Pavia 27100, Italy (e-mail: mara210@unipv.it).
then the price that implies the greater benefit is selected (global optimum). Digital Object Identifier 10.1109/TPWRS.2002.804965

0885-8950/04$20.00 © 2004 IEEE


IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON POWER SYSTEMS VOL. 19, NO. 1, FEBRUARY 2004 693

Power Flow (SCORPF) procedure should be recommended for the the reactive support service. The discussers refer to a Security Con-
solution of the problem. Besides the constraint settlement, the choice strained Optimal Reactive Power Flow (SCORPF) procedure as a pos-
of the objective function is a point of needed discussion. sible tool for this purpose. They state that such a tool will be useful in
The maximization of the loadability margin [4] to maintain adequate “the definition of reactive power support costs (paying attention also
reactive reserves for additional transactions but also the traditional min- to the nondominant terms).” Unfortunately, we do not share the view
imization of real power losses to reduce the transmission service rates expressed in this statement since the SCORPF tool has, in reality, no
are still now proposed [5]. The SCORPF solution gives important indi- capability to provide cost information. The OPF may provide appro-
cations, by means of the Lagrange multipliers of the active constraints, priate pricing signals when the economics of the situation are properly
on the possible pricing of the reactive support at operation level and represented. But, the discussion on OPF application requires that a few
on an efficient allocation of new reactive resources at planning level. aspects of OPF be clarified.
Combining technical and economical requirements, SCORPF seems to The OPF is a powerful centralized decision-making tool developed
be able to give information also on the nondominant component of the for the vertically integrated utility (VIU) structure. Its effective applica-
variable cost. The discussers would like to know the opinions of the au- tion in the competitive environment requires the appropriate represen-
thors about the suitability of the use of the OPF tools for the definition tation of market economics and the introduction of meaningful metrics
of reactive power support costs (paying attention also to the nondomi- [2], [3]. A key complication in the OPF formulation lies in the arbi-
nant terms). trariness of the optimum due to the wide discretionary powers of the
IGO in the formulation of the constraint set and the definition of the
REFERENCES set point values of certain control variables [2]. These considerations
make the choice of an appropriate objective very challenging since the
[1] G. Gross, S. Tao, E. Bompard, and G. Chicco, “Unbundled reactive sup-
port service: Key characteristics and dominant cost component,” IEEE economics of the situation must be appropriately reflected.
Trans. Power Syst., vol. 17, pp. 283–289, May 2002. The OPF framework provides the setting for the evaluation of dual
[2] W. Xu, Y. Zhang, C. P. da Silva, P. Kundur, and A. Warrack, “Valuation variables that have the economic interpretation of prices. For example,
of dynamic reactive power support services for transmission access,”
IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 16, pp. 719–728, Nov. 2001. the relatively simple model for the reactive loads used in [4] can pro-
[3] S. Corsi, P. Marannino, N. Losignore, G. Moreschini, and G. Piccini, vide effective price signals for congestion relief. The OPF framework
“Coordination between the reactive power scheduling and the hierar- permits the incorporation of contingencies; however, in the presence
chical voltage control of the EHV enel system,” IEEE Trans. Power
Syst., vol. 10, pp. 602–608, May 1995. of contingencies, the value—not the cost—of reserves must be explic-
[4] P. Marannino, F. Zanellini, M. Merlo, S. Corsi, M. Pozzi, and G. itly represented. This value is linked to the effective limit of a reactive
Dell’Olio, “Evaluation of load margins with respect to voltage collapse power source, which depends on the amount of reactive power that can
in presence of secondary and tertiary voltage regulation,” in Bulk
Power System Dynamics and Control—V, Onomichi City, Japan, Aug. be actually provided under specified system conditions [5]. This effec-
26–31, 2001. tive reactive limit is different than the generator reactive power limit
[5] K. Bhattacharya and J. Zhong, “Reactive power as an ancillary service,” since the system conditions under one of the specified contingencies
IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 16, pp. 294–300, May 2001.
may prevent the generator from reaching its reactive power limit.
This brief discussion leads to the conclusion that the deployment
of an OPF tool for the reactive power support service acquisition and
pricing requires the careful consideration and addressing of some very
challenging issues. Two issues are particularly critical. These are de-
tailed below.
Closure on “Unbundled Reactive Support Service: Key
1) As correctly pointed out by the discussers, the selection of the
Characteristics and Dominant Cost Component” objective function for an OPF tool is not a straightforward issue.
Due to the local nature of reactive power, the optimization to
George Gross, Shu Tao, Ettore Bompard, and Gianfranco Chicco
minimize the total costs of reactive power support services based
on the price bids submitted by the generators is unfortunately
We thank Prof. Marannino and Mr. Zanellini for their interest in and not appropriate. Moreover, the local monopoly power of certain
discussion of, our paper [1]. We appreciate their complimentary and generators makes a centralized IGO-operated structure for
insightful comments on the paper and are most pleased that they share reactive support both impractical and unsuitable for competi-
our views on the key physical characteristics and the dominant cost tion. This has been clearly illustrated and strongly emphasized
component of the generator-based reactive support as an unbundled in the paper. The discussers refer to the maximization of the
ancillary service in the restructured electricity industry. loadability margin to maintain adequate reactive reserves for
The discussion raises issues concerning the role of the Independent additional transactions and the traditional minimization of
Grid Operator (IGO) in voltage support and reactive power control and real power losses as two possible candidates for the objective
the computational tools deployable for the acquisition and pricing of function. While the loadability margin maximization and the
loss minimization can be thought of as a common good enjoyed
by all the market participants, i.e., all the transmission network
customers, such objective functions may conflict with each
individual generator’s self interest. Moreover, since these ob-
Manuscript received May 28, 2002.
G. Gross is with the Department of Electrical and Computer Engineering, jective functions do not involve either the costs incurred by the
University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, Urbana, IL 61801 USA (e-mail: individual generators or the values to the transmission customers
gross@uiuc.edu). in providing/acquiring the reactive support requirements, they
S. Tao is with the ABB Energy Information Systems, Santa Clara, CA 95050 are unable to provide a direct and clear price signal for reactive
USA (e-mail: shu.tao@us.abb.com). support services to individual generators. The lack of such a
E. Bompard and G. Chicco are with the Dipartimento di Ingegneria Elettrica
Industriale, Politecnico di Torino, corso Duca degli Abruzzi 24, 10129 Torino, price signal results in no appropriate incentive to the generators
Italy (e-mail: bompard@polito.it; chicco@polito.it). to supply the necessary reactive support services. Thus, while
Digital Object Identifier 10.1109/TPWRS.2002.804966 these objective functions may be appropriate choices in the VIU

0885-8950/04$20.00 © 2004 IEEE

Вам также может понравиться