Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 26

Going to work

4
Once young people are in the labor mar- reintegrate the most vulnerable will allow
ket, they begin to reap the benefits of ear- youth to gain productive employment.
lier investment in education and health, and The chapter starts by documenting the
chapter continue to develop the skills needed for a challenges youth are facing in their transi-
productive livelihood. A successful transi- tion to work along with their consequences
tion to work for today’s many young people in the short and long terms. The next sec-
can accelerate poverty reduction through tion shows why general policies will not
better allocation of their labor, and boost solve all the constraints youth face so that
economic growth. Some youth, however, a youth-specific approach is needed in the
encounter roadblocks: some go to work too labor market. The last three sections discuss
early, others cannot enter the work force, still the policy options that could support the
others get stuck in low productivity work. opportunity, capability, and second-chance
Because most learning occurs at the pillars of the Report’s policy framework in
beginning of the work life, initial experiences the transition to work.
can have long-lasting effects. Difficulties in
entering the labor market can persist and
be very costly to mitigate. Poverty and slow Youth challenges
economic growth can exacerbate poor youth in the labor market
outcomes such as child labor, school drop- By age 24, almost all youth in developing
out rates, and joblessness. The lack of access countries have left school and entered a new
to insurance and information and the unin- stage in life—some to begin wage work,
tended consequences of some labor market some to engage in home enterprise, some
policies magnify the impact of household to form households and raise families, and
poverty and slow economic growth. some to do combinations of these activi-
Correcting for these failures requires ties. Over the past 30 years, the age of leaving
the right mix of policies to ensure that school has risen in every region in the world
enough opportunities are available for except Africa.1 The increased educational
young people, that their skills match attainment associated with this should have
employment opportunities, and that sec- improved the transition to work and led to
ond-chance options protect those who fall greater success once employed. Indeed it has,
behind. Some policies, such as improving but too many youth still face significant chal-
the investment climate or enhancing the lenges in their path to work. The main obsta-
functioning of the labor market, are not cles are starting too early, failing to enter the
youth specific, but have a disproportion- labor market, and having difficulties moving
ate impact on youth. Other interventions across jobs and up the skill chain. The effect
are youth specific and should be designed of these obstacles on skill accumulation,
to fit the country context. In most middle- future performance in the labor market, and
income countries, the priority is to reform economic development are long lasting.
labor market institutions and to build
more bridges between school and work Starting too early
to better accommodate new entrants. In Some young people never attend school,
most low-income countries building on and many others begin working at very
basic skills and providing a springboard to young ages. An average of 14 percent of
96
Going to work 97

Figure 4.1 Child labor is highest in Africa

Percentage of children economically active


80

70

60
Regional average
50

40
Grand average
30

20

10

0
Africa East Europe & Latin America Middle South
Asia & Central & the Caribbean East & Asia
Pacific Asia North
Africa
Source: Fares and Raju (2006).
Note: Regional (dotted horizontal lines) and grand (solid horizontal line) means are calculated by weighting country child economic activity
rates by country child population (7–14 years).

the population ages 10–30 in 82 develop- percent of working children were estimated
ing countries have never attended school. to be attending school.
Child labor is prevalent among this group, About 70 percent of child laborers are
but it is also common among those who in agriculture, predominantly in unpaid
entered school. The International Labour family work. Fewer than 10 percent are in
Organization (ILO) estimates that despite manufacturing.4 For many poor families,
an 11 percent drop in the incidence of child child labor represents a significant share of
labor between 2000 and 2004, 218 million household income. For example, in Brazil-
are still trapped in child labor.2 In 65 coun- ian households in which children work,
tries, about 21 percent of children under child labor represents 17 percent of urban
age 15 are economically active (figure 4.1). household income and 22 percent of rural
The estimate likely understates child work household income. The unfortunate trade-
because it is difficult to measure work out- off is that children who sacrifice schooling
side the market and because child labor when young are likely to be poor as adults.5
is characterized by short spells missed by Recently completed research has
surveys.3 The highest reported rates are in improved our understanding of the deter-
Sub-Saharan Africa, averaging 35 percent. minants and consequences of child labor.6
In seven of 29 African countries, more that Many adolescents work while in school, but
half the children between ages 7 and 14 are the effect of doing so is unclear (chapter
working (figure 4.1). 3). For young adults, working may enable
A consensus against the very visible and them to finance upper secondary and ter-
worst form of child labor is reflected in the tiary education that would otherwise be
large number of countries ratifying ILO unaffordable. The problem is with younger
convention 182 on the Worst Form of Child people—work appears to be more damag-
Labor. However, the majority of children ing to school attainment because prema-
are not working under such harsh visible turely dropping out of school reduces the
conditions. The reality is quite complicated. amount that youth learn while in school.
Many working children combine school A negative association between work and
with work. In 29 countries in Sub-Saharan the test scores of 8th graders is found in a
Africa, an estimated 52 percent of children majority of countries. 7 Poorer schooling
working were also attending school, while in outcomes also lead to poorer earnings later
19 countries in Latin America as many as 78 in life. In Brazil, boys who entered the work
98 WORLD DEVELOPMENT REPORT 2007

force before age 12 earned 20 percent less only to urban male youth, but to women
per hour and were 8 percent more likely to and rural youth as well.
be in the lowest income quintile than boys Children of parents who worked as
who started working after age 12.8 children are more likely to work at young
Leaving school too early is costly for ages, holding other household attributes
later productivity. The forgone earnings constant, suggesting that child labor recurs
and the lack of skill accumulation can across generations and may be a means by
make it much more difficult to escape pov- which poverty is passed on from parent to
erty as an adult. In 61 countries, the esti- child.10 Child labor can also have temporary
mated average return per year of schooling or permanent adverse health consequences
was 7.3 percent for men and 9.8 percent for that can hinder future earning capacity.11
women.9 The returns are highly correlated
within countries, so markets that reward Failing to enter the labor market
schooling for men also reward women, and Many young males and females face signifi-
markets that reward urban residents also cant difficulties entering the labor market.
reward those in rural areas. These returns This employment difficulty can be mea-
suggest that across a wide array of coun- sured differently depending on the country
tries at all stages of development, educa- context and youth characteristics (box 4.1).
tion offers substantial wage returns—not According to most measures, youth are more

BOX 4.1 Measuring youth activity in the transition to work


Conclusions about youth labor market out- force that is unemployed. The employment rate the caveats of each indicator and suggests
comes differ depending on how youth time is the share of the population that is employed. alternatives:
allocations are measured. For example, youth Two other measures are used in developing-
• The unemployment rate is a measure of dif-
who are not employed in the formal market may country settings: the proportion of the popula-
ficulty of finding work. In middle-income
be spending time productively in school or in tion neither in the labor force nor in school, and
countries the ratio of youth to adult unem-
informal production activities or they may also the proportion of the population neither work-
ployment rate is telling, but short-term and
be actively seeking work (see figure below). ing nor in school (the jobless rate).
long-term unemployment need to be distin-
The standard labor market indicators in No one measure provides a complete pic-
guished. In low-income countries, the youth
developed countries are the unemployment ture of the labor market for youth, so multiple
unemployment rate is very low, and relevant
rate, the employment rate, and the labor measures are needed to analyze youth labor
only for the more educated and better off
force participation rate. Youth are considered markets in developing economies. For a sample
portion of the population.
employed if they work at least one hour for a of 91 developing countries, these indicators
wage in the weeks prior to the survey but also are not perfectly correlated. There is an inverse • The employment rate for youth does not
if they work in unpaid labor for an enterprise correlation between the unemployment rate account for school enrollment and the type
owned by their households. To be consid- and the employment rate, and a weaker inverse of work. Using the population out of school as
ered unemployed, an individual must be not correlation between the unemployment rate a reference group allows for better compara-
employed but actively seeking work. The labor and the labor force participation rate. According bility with adults, while looking at the sector
force participation rate is the share of the popu- to the level of country development and the of work, hours of work, and measures of earn-
lation either employed or unemployed, and the gender and education of youth, the relevant ing shed light on the quality of employment
unemployment rate is the share of the labor indicator could vary. The following list indicates and underemployment.
• “Out of school and out of work” is a measure
of unused human capital but not for girls
involved in household activities. The relative
ratio for males in this group indicates the
An illustration of youth time use
extent of discouraged youth who withdrew
from the work force.
In the labor force Not in the labor force
• Youth employment is considered informal
if the job is unpaid or if the job includes no
Employed Not in the labor force and not in school
benefits such as participation in the country’s
Formal market social security system. High rates of informal-
ity are a signal that youth are finding less
Informal Enrolled in school permanent, low-quality jobs.
market Working Not working • Combining school and work is potentially
harmful for the very young, and could be an
Unemployed
indicator of the risk of early school exit.
Source: Fares, Montenegro, and Orazem (2006a).
Going to work 99

likely to be unemployed than adults. Sig- Figure 4.2 Unemployment is higher for youths than
for adults
nificant variation in unemployment exists
between urban and rural sectors, between Youth unemployment rate (percent)
developed and developing countries, as well 40
2:1
as between poor and rich households. Young
females are more likely than young males to 3:1

stay out of the labor force. Early difficul- 30


ties in finding employment can have long- 1:1
lasting effects on employment later in life.
Young people have a hard time finding 20
employment. Survey data from 60 devel-
oping countries suggest that, after leaving
school, youth spend an average of 1.4 years 10
in temporary or intermittent work and spells
of joblessness before permanently entering
stable employment.12 This estimated dura-
0
tion varies widely between countries and 0 10 20 30 40
estimation methodologies, but could reach Adult unemployment rate (percent)
above four years in some instances. In many Source: Fares, Montenegro, and Orazem (2006a).
countries in Eastern Europe, Latin America, Note: The 1:1 line represents the cases in which the estimated
unemployment among youth and adults is identical. The 2:1 (and
and the former Soviet Union, youth enter- 3:1) lines represent cases in which estimated youth unemployment
ing the labor market experienced long spells is twice (three times) as high as adult unemployment. Each data
point in the graph represents one country.
of unemployment.13 Initial failure in finding
a job can lead to persistent joblessness for
young people, especially in weak economies. In most countries, the less skilled youth
In every region the difficulty youth face are more likely to face difficulties in finding
in entering the labor market is evident work compared with more skilled youth.
in higher unemployment rates for young However, in some developing countries
men and women than for older workers. the unemployment rate is very high even
Youth make up 25 percent of the working- among educated youth, a great concern
age population worldwide, but 47 percent to many countries in the Middle East and
of the unemployed. The estimated global North Africa. In Tunisia, where the unem-
unemployment rate for youth increased ployment rate for 20- to 24-year-olds is
steadily from 11.7 percent in 1993 to 14.4 more than three times higher than the rate
percent in 2003. It varies widely across for those over 40, it is more than 40 percent
regions, from a low of 7.0 percent in East for youth with higher education compared
Asia to 13.4 percent in industrial economies to about 25 percent for those with primary
to a high of 25.0 percent in the Middle East education.17 The disadvantage faced by the
and North Africa.14 Across all markets the most educated persists over several years
youth unemployment rate is two to three after entry into the labor force. The cross-
times higher than the adult unemploy- sectional pattern implies that it takes an esti-
ment rate, regardless of the level of aggre- mated 10 years for the unemployment rate
gate unemployment (figure 4.2). The high for Tunisians with postsecondary education
unemployment rate among youth in some to drop below that of the less educated.
countries has made unemployment in these Unemployment is only one symptom of
countries a youth problem. In the Arab problems in the labor market. Within poor
Republic of Egypt, Indonesia, Qatar, and countries, youth unemployment is concen-
the Syrian Arab Republic, youth make up trated among those who are educated and
more than 60 percent of the unemployed.15 from high-income families. Other dimen-
In most developing countries, the youth sions in the labor market must be examined
unemployment rate is higher in urban than to assess the ease or the difficulty for young
in rural areas, and is estimated to be higher people to integrate themselves in the labor
for young women than for young men.16 market. Some youth are neither working
100 WORLD DEVELOPMENT REPORT 2007

nor in school (box 4.2); other poor young Figure 4.3 Where young people cannot afford to
be unemployed, youth unemployment is low and
people cannot afford to stay unemployed, employment is high
most have to work. So the incidence of
unemployment may be low, although youth Employment /unemployment rate (percent)
50
are still mired in poverty. In the poor-
est countries, youth unemployment rates Youth unemployment
40 Youth employment
are very low and employment rates are
very high (figure 4.3). As country income
increases the incidence of unemployment 30

among youth also increases—a likely reflec-


tion of available alternative income sources 20
and safety nets that make it possible to be
unemployed. Youth employment rates also 10
fall as per capita income increases because
youth devote more time to schooling. 0
Low-income Lower- Upper- High-income
countries middle- middle- countries
The effects of these difficulties are lasting. income income
countries countries
An initial period of unstable employment
upon leaving school is common and not Source: Fares, Montenegro, and Orazem (2006a).

of great concern if young people eventually


move into more stable jobs, but this is not always the case. The duration of unemploy-
ment for some is very high. For example, in
2000, more than an estimated 60 percent of
unemployed youth remained unemployed
BOX 4.2 Some youths are neither in the for more than six months in the Czech
labor force nor studying Republic, Hungary, and the Slovak Repub-
lic.18 In both Brazil and Chile, youth cohorts
In many countries, the proportion of youth The incidence of young females neither in
who are neither in the labor force nor in the labor force nor studying is higher than that entered the labor market during reces-
school is too large to dismiss as a problem for young males, which is higher than for sions faced an atypically high likelihood of
of measurement or as a temporary phe- adult males unemployment during the recession and
nomenon. A cross-country comparison of
young men and women reveals important Youth neither in labor force nor studying persistently high unemployment for several
differences in these proportions across gen- (percent) more years even after recovery began.19 In
der and relative to adults (see the figure): 80 Bosnia and Herzegovina, youth’s difficult
Males
• Differences in levels. Female observations Females entry into the labor market led to low future
almost always lie to the right of male 60 earnings (box 4.3).
observations, implying a higher incidence Long spells of unemployment can dis-
for females relative to males.
40 courage youth from remaining in the labor
• Differences in ratios. Most observations for
men lie above the 45 degree line, where force, leading to a high incidence of youth
the estimated incidences for youth and out of school and work (see box 4.2). The
20
adults are identical, implying that young delays in finding work are important at this
men are systematically more likely to fall
in this group than adult men. The pattern
age because young people need the early
0
is not replicated for females. 0 20 40 60 80 experience to build on their basic education
Some of the high estimates may be Adults neither in labor force nor and to continue to acquire skills relevant to
attributable to measurement problems, par- studying (percent) the labor market. Being either unemployed
ticularly for young women working in their Source: Fares, Montenegro, and Orazem (2006a). or out of the workforce for a long time can
households. In Tanzania, the main reason Note: The 45 degree line represents the cases in limit the accumulation of human capital
young women said they were not looking which the estimated incidence of neither working
for work was their household responsibili- nor studying among young and adults are identical. young people need to get better integrated
Each data point in the graph represents one country.
ties. For young men, it was the lack of mar- into the workplace and find productive
ket work. nonmarket activities. Youth who are neither employment.
The data reveal important differ- attaining marketable skills in school nor During repeated spells of unemployment,
ences between males and females in this using those skills in productive work are a
group—males are predominately discour- wasted resource in the economy, so mecha- young men and women in Canada and the
aged workers, while females are engaged in nisms need to be found to tap that resource. United States increase their uptake of train-
ing, stay longer in school, delay marriage,
Going to work 101

BOX 4.3 Early unemployment persists in Bosnia and Herzegovina


In Bosnia and Herzegovina, despite the end of the labor market. Among those 15–24 who were period were also found to have faced a greater
the civil conflict in the late 1990s, youth have had unemployed in 2001, 77 percent were jobless one likelihood of unemployment or joblessness
significant difficulties entering the labor market year later, and 58 percent were still jobless three (both inactivity and unemployment) in 2004.
and experienced excessive instability in their early years later. Even among youth employed in 2001, Among young workers, the experience of job-
years of the transition to work. In 2004, the unem- a third of them were jobless in 2002, and a quarter lessness is associated with about 11 percent
ployment rate was 62 percent for those between of them were still jobless in 2004. 20 greater probability of unemployment and 30
15 and 19 years old, and 37 percent for those Controlling for young workers’ character- percent greater probability of joblessness. The
between 20 and 24 years old, compared to 22 per- istics (for example, gender, education, marital effect on earnings is also significant. For all
cent for adults in the same year. These outcomes status), those who suffered a spell of unemploy- workers in Bosnia and Herzegovina, a spell of
persist in the first few years of youth experience in ment or inactivity at any point over the 2001–02 joblessness is associated with lower wages.

Poor transition probabilities in Bosnia and Herzegovina, 2001–04 (percent)


Employment status in 2002 Employment status in 2004
Inactive Unemployed Employed Inactive Unemployed Employed
Employment Status in 2001
All
Inactive 73 12 14 63 15 21
Unemployed 32 34 34 30 27 43
All employed 13 07 81 13 08 79
Ages 15–24
Inactive 71 17 12 53 21 26
Unemployed 36 41 23 26 32 42
All employed 22 12 66 11 15 74
Source: Fares and Tiongson (2006).
Note: "Inactive" is defined as being out of school and out of the labor force.

and continue to live with their parents.21 Not youth are less likely to be employed com-
all these options are available in developing pared to older men and women. Even after
countries. When productive options are not adjusting for school enrollment, the differ-
available for jobless youth, there is a greater ence between youths’ and adults’ employ-
likelihood that they will enter activities dam- ment rates persists. Among youth, the
aging to themselves and society. Youth diffi- employment rate for young men is always
culties in the labor market increased crime higher than the employment rate for young
rates in France, and increased the probabil- women, partly reflecting a stronger attach- “I am positive for my future. I’m
ity of incarceration in the United States.22 ment to the labor force among males—but sure I will find a job sooner or later
Similarly, in Sri Lanka, where the proportion also reflecting the additional difficulties and the first job doesn’t mean a job
of long-term unemployed young people many young women face in going to work that I will do my whole life. The
exceeds that of adults, high youth unem- and the greater proportion of them engaged most important thing for me is to
ployment was cited as the main cause for in home production, not included in mea- improve myself.”
large-scale unrest of Sinhalese youth from sured employment.
Xiangju, university student,
the rural south. The second insurgency from When working, youth often are found
China
1987–91 brought the country to the verge in low-paying jobs or unpaid family work.
December 2005
of collapse and left 40,000–60,000 dead or For 74 developing countries with data, only
missing, most of them youth.23 25 percent of working youth in low-income
countries are in paid work, with the pro-
Getting stuck in jobs that portion rising with country income, to 57
do not build human capital percent for the middle-income group and
Youth and adult employment are posi- 74 percent for the high-income group. Even
tively correlated—as adult employment those who are paid are less likely to have
rises, youth employment also increases. But access to social security compared with
102 WORLD DEVELOPMENT REPORT 2007

older workers. In these 74 countries, it is Figure 4.4 Returns to experience are highest for
the young
not uncommon to find the incidence of
unpaid work to be two to four times higher Percent return to one year of additional experience
for youths than adults (chapter 1). 7
Starting in a low-paying job, or being Burkina Faso
Brazil
mismatched early on with the wrong type 6 Chile
of employment, would not have severe con- Indonesia
Mexico
sequences if youth can move to more pro- Pakistan
ductive opportunities. Indeed, during the 5 Slovenia
early transition to work, youth are expected Thailand
Uganda
to be experimenting with different types of
4
employment, and evidence indicates that
such early turnover will enhance subsequent
job matches, reflected in higher productivity 3
and higher earnings for youth.24 However,
not all youth are mobile. In Burkina Faso,
2
more than 90 percent of teenagers between
15 and 19 with no education started working
as family helpers in 1993, falling only to about 1
80 percent five years later.25 Higher educa-
tion does increase mobility. More than 80
percent of teenagers between 15 and 19 with 0
20 30 40
some secondary education started working Age
as family helpers in 1993, and this share fell Source: Fares, Montenegro, and Orazem (2006b).
to about 40 percent five years later. While ini-
tial differences were not as large, those with
higher education moved out to find better On entering the labor market, youth may
productive work much more quickly. have the opportunity to obtain formal and
Does starting in informal or unpaid on-the-job training, with a large impact
work rather than formal-sector work lead to on their eventual earnings. Young workers
different employment and wage outcomes? have the fastest wage increases during this
Where informality is widespread, the infor- period of learning on the job, and the rate
mal sector is an important stepping stone in slows as workers age (figure 4.4). Returns
the transition from school to work for those to an additional one year of experience at
who have the choice. In Latin America the age 20 increase earnings by up to 6 percent.
vast majority of apprenticeship occurs in However, holding everything else constant,
the informal sector, and new entrants might an additional year of experience at age 40
choose the informal sector to acquire the increases earnings by less than 3 percent.
skills needed for the labor market.26 In Alba- The more skills acquired in the early work
nia, Argentina, Georgia, Hungary, Poland, career, the more the worker can earn later
Russia, Ukraine, and República Bolivariana on. In more than four-fifths of the coun-
de Venezuela, youth gain substantially when tries analyzed, earnings peaked after age 40,
they move from the informal to the formal with an average peak in earnings at age 47.
sector.27 The wage gains from the move At the peak, earnings were on average 2.5
are significantly greater for youths than times the starting wage, indicating consider-
for older workers. Youths also benefit from able skill development after leaving school,
faster wage growth once in the formal sec- most of it in the first few years on the job.
tor, both in comparison with older workers Youth who lose the chance to acquire these
and in comparison with their counterparts skills after leaving school because of early
in the informal sector. Some, however, labor market difficulties may face a career
become stuck in informal low-paying jobs of lower skills and poorer pay. Indeed, in
that offer no opportunity to further develop Hungary, initial career success drives later
their human capital. labor market outcomes.28
Going to work 103

The effect on poverty and social outcomes PETI (Program to Eradicate Child Labor) in
should not be understated. In many countries, Brazil were shown to be successful already in
some households with working youth are reducing child labor incidence by providing
still poor, even after factoring in youth earn- support to income-constrained families con-
ings. Because the most abundant asset of the ditional on their children attending school
poor is labor, if poor households are unable to and after-school programs.
escape poverty even when their youth work, it Young people suffer disproportionately
is unlikely that they will do so through other from weakening labor markets. Cross-coun-
means. This puts the policy issues for poverty try analyses from developed and developing
alleviation in stark focus. The overwhelming countries show that increased labor demand
evidence is that better schooling helps youth always improves employment and increases
make an easier transition from school to labor force participation among youth.30 In
work and enjoy greater success. More stable Brazil in the 1980s and 1990s, employment
employment and earnings also ease the next rates for adults during economic downturns
transition into marriage and household for- and expansions varied only slightly from the
mation. However, the poorest households trend, but movements were much greater for
cannot meet their current consumption needs young males and females.31 The differences
without the income earned through their in employment fluctuations are even more
children’s labor, so their children’s schooling apparent in Chile. The employment rate for
and potential escape from poverty is sacrificed young males is consistently below that of
for current subsistence. adults, partly because a large share of those
between 15 and 24 years old are enrolled in
school and also because of the greater diffi-
What makes youth vulnerable culties youth face in their transition to work.
in the labor market? However, the difference is not constant and
Youth labor market outcomes are affected varies widely over time. During the economic
by general trends in poverty and economic slowdowns of 1974, 1982, and 1998, the
growth. Because of the severe income con- employment rate for young males, adjusted
straints in low-income countries, house- for school attendance, declined at least twice
holds may have no choice but to send as much as that for adult males (figure 4.5).
children to work, while in slow-growing What is contributing to the vulnerability
economies, youth have significant difficul- of youth in the labor market? Four factors:
ties in finding work.
The incidence of child labor is high in the • In some countries, large cohorts of new
entrants and higher female participation
Sub-Saharan Africa and South Asia regions,
rates will continue to add pressure on
characterized mostly by low-income coun-
the youth labor market.
tries (see figure 4.1). This relationship, how-
ever, is not linear and indicates that at very
low levels of income, the effect of changes in Figure 4.5 In Chile employment is more responsive
to demand fluctuations for young males than for adults
per capita income on the incidence of child
labor is the highest. Significant variation also Employment rate (percent)
occurs in the incidence of child labor even at 100
Males ages 25–49
similar levels of income, which indicates that
90
factors other than poverty could increase or
reduce the incidence of child labor. Some 80
families and children have low perceived
returns to education, while others face bor- 70

rowing (and other) constraints to finance 60 Males ages 15–24


their children’s schooling. Microanalysis for
Burkina Faso and Guatemala shows that the 50
1961 1966 1971 1976 1981 1986 1991 1996 2001 2006
incidence of child labor increases when poor
families are faced with income shocks.29 Source: Fares and Montenegro (2006).
Note: Shaded portions represent periods of economic slowdown.
Conditional cash transfer programs such as Employment series are adjusted for school enrollment.
104 WORLD DEVELOPMENT REPORT 2007

• Poor access to information and credit Lack of access to information


leads to premature exit from school, per- and credit
petuating skill mismatches. Leaving school to start work before acquir-
• Policy failures have unintended con- ing the relevant skills limits the ability of
sequences on youth employment and youth to take advantage of future work
widen the gaps between youth and adults opportunities (chapter 3). Poor households
in the labor market. with limited access to credit, facing income
• Social institutions hinder the full partici- or health shocks, might have no option but
pation of many youth, particularly girls, to withdraw their children from school
in skill acquisition and work. and send them to work. Low expected
returns to education might also cause early
Large youth cohorts school dropout and entry to work. Because
of information failures, households may
Several developing countries around the
undervalue the potential returns from
world are experiencing larger youth cohorts
schooling, particularly when jobs requiring
(see spotlight on differing demographics
education are in urban areas and the house-
following chapter 1). In some, particularly
hold is rural. These information failures are
in Sub-Saharan Africa, the share of youth
greatest in households with poorly educated
in the population will continue to rise for
parents.
the next few decades, adding pressure on
Another reason for low expected returns
the youth labor market. Indeed, earlier baby
is that policies restrict youth from moving
booms in developed countries increased
easily from one job to another, from one area
youth unemployment (see spotlight on
to another, or from one industry to another.
baby booms following chapter 4).
The Heritage Foundation Economic Freedom
In 32 developing and transition coun-
Index measures how a country’s economic
tries, a 10 percent increase in the youth
institutions allow people to work, produce,
share of the population increased youth
consume, and invest in the ways they feel
unemployment by an estimated 6 percent
are most productive.36 Returns to schooling
between 1980 and 2000.32 In Ethiopia, local
average 9.9 percent in the group of develop-
labor markets with the largest share of youth
ing countries where workers are freer to seek
in the population had the lowest youth
economic advantage, but 6.4 percent in the
employment rates, with the effect more
less mobile group (figure 4.6). This is consis-
pronounced among uneducated youth.33
tent with theoretical work that ties returns to
Thus, countries with rising youth cohorts
human capital to economic mobility across
will face increasing challenges in absorbing
alternative sectors and occupations.
youth in jobs.
Lack of access to information reduces
Even where the youth share of the popu-
the effectiveness of job search and prolongs
lation is decreasing, the underlying increase
joblessness among youth. Not knowing the
in female participation rates will limit the
available opportunities in the labor market
impact of slower population growth as
and how to prepare for them reduce the like-
larger shares of young females in these
lihood of youth developing the right skills
cohorts look for employment in the labor
and finding the appropriate job for their
market.34 Rising educational attainment has
skills. The information asymmetry makes
had a particularly important effect on the
employers less confident in hiring new
labor supply choices for women. As women
entrants because they are not certain about
acquire more education, they increasingly
their productivity. It also increases turnover
move out of traditional household or agri-
as youth and employers learn more about the
cultural production activities and enter
quality of their employment relationship.
wage work. Rising female education levels
and the associated rise in female participa-
tion in wage work have another effect—they Restrictive labor market institutions
are strongly inversely correlated with coun- Labor market institutions—such as unem-
try fertility rates.35 ployment insurance, employment protec-
Going to work 105

Figure 4.6 Returns to education are higher for ment rates for young workers.40 The adverse
workers who are more mobile
impact of such regulations on young work-
Return to education (percent) ers’ employment rates was more than twice
20 that on prime-age male workers in 15 Latin
15 American and Caribbean countries and 28
More mobile Organisation for Economic Co-operation
10
Less mobile and Development (OECD) countries in the
5
1980s and 1990s.41
0 Because youth are more likely to be at the “Young people are deprived of secure
–5 bottom of the wage distribution, changes jobs; their unemployment rate is
–10 in the minimum wage will naturally have a well above the national average.”
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 larger impact (positive or negative) on them.
Years of schooling
Jérémie, law student, France
In Brazil, an increase in the minimum wage
Source: Fares, Montenegro, and Orazem (2006b). led to greater job loss for female, young, and
Note: “More mobile” countries have an average return to educa-
tion of 9.9 percent; “less mobile” countries have an average return low-skilled workers whose wages were clus-
to education of 6.4 percent. Countries are classified as “more tered around the minimum. In Chile, mini-
mobile” and “less mobile” according to the Heritage Foundation
Economic Freedom Index. Each data point in the graph represents mum wages reduced the overall employment
one country.
probabilities of youth, particularly the
unskilled.42 Even when the informal sector is
tion laws, and the minimum wage—came large, as in Latin America, minimum wages
into being in response to the suffering of in the formal sector spill over into wages
the unemployed and the exploitation of in the informal sector.43 As a consequence,
workers. Despite good intentions, those youth in the informal sector are also affected
institutions are less than optimal in many by changes in the minimum wage.
countries. Their design might have been When public sector wages and benefits
poor to start with, circumstances and are more generous than private sector com-
the economic environment might have pensation, a strong incentive arises for young
changed, and political considerations might (usually educated) school leavers to queue
have given institutions a life and shape of for government jobs and stay unemployed
their own. Reforming these institutions has for some time after graduation. Substantial
long been on the agenda in many coun- wage premiums in the public sector—cou-
tries.37 Some of these institutions have a pled with job security, tenure, prestige, and
disproportionate effect on youth. other nonwage benefits—influence the deci-
Employment protection laws are effective sion to voluntarily hold out until a public
in protecting jobs and preventing job loss, sector job opportunity opens. In Morocco,
but also raise hiring costs, putting young peo- the starting hourly wage in the public sec-
ple at a disadvantage.38 World Development tor is 42.5 percent higher than in the private
Report 2005 and Doing Business 2006 show sector.44 This leads to a strong preference for
that employment regulations can be more public employment among highly educated
stringent in developing countries than in young Moroccans. In Tunisia, the public
industrial countries. High firing costs reduce sector wage premium is 18 percent, again
layoffs as well as job creation in firms and leading the young to queue for jobs in the
limit the entry of new firms, disproportion- public sector rather than accept less attrac-
ately burdening youth in the labor market.39 tive private sector jobs.45 In Ethiopia, a large
Furthermore, reduced turnover increases share of the unemployed youth aspired to
the duration of unemployment. This effect, work in the public sector because of the
combined with the lasting impact of long, perceived high benefits.46
early unemployment spells, impairs youth These results are not unique to Ethiopia,
outcomes and future prospects. In Chile, Morocco, and Tunisia. Earnings regressions
where job security provisions depend on for 39 developing countries reveal a public
job tenure, employment was biased against wage premium in 25 countries, on average
young workers. Stricter employment protec- about 26 percent, controlling for individual
tion laws meant lower wages and employ- characteristics. For other countries such as
106 WORLD DEVELOPMENT REPORT 2007

Cambodia and Vietnam, the public wage ket institutions is a priority. In low-income
premium is negative.47 In Latin America the countries, with large informal sectors and
public wage premium is much higher for dominance of the rural economy, reforming
women than men. In several countries in institutions will have limited impact. Thus,
Latin America and in Indonesia, the public expanding alternatives in the rural sector,
wage premium also varies with skill levels.48 promoting sectoral and regional mobility,
and reducing child labor are most urgent.
Inhibiting social institutions,
especially for young females Improving the investment climate
In all regions over the past three decades, Economic growth and job creation benefit
labor force participation rates have risen most participants in the labor market, youth
for young women, coincident with rising included. When labor demand is strong,
female educational attainment and falling youth employment and labor force partici-
fertility rates. In some regions, however, ris- pation for both males and females increases
ing female education levels have not trans- while the unemployment rate for youth goes
lated into dramatic increases in labor force down.51 Because the private sector should
participation rates for young women. Social lead in job creation, a good investment cli-
institutions and norms could be a reason. mate is needed to allow firms to form and
A simple cross-country regression for 128 expand. World Development Report 2005
countries shows that religion alone can argued that governments should create a
explain about one-third of the variation in better investment climate by tackling unjus-
female participation rates.49 tified costs, risks, and barriers to competi-
Social norms can also affect whether tion. They can do this by ensuring political
young women succeed in the labor market. stability and security, improving the regula-
In Egypt, women, whose average education tory and tax climate for investment, provid-
level has increased enormously, stay close ing needed infrastructure, and improving
to home and refrain from driving—limit- information on vacancies for job seekers.
ing their job mobility. While young males Expanding world trade has shifted pro-
increased their commuting distance to work duction around the world. Because the
between 1988 and 1998, young women did young are the most able to respond to the
not, limiting their access to paid employ- growing demand for labor, these shifts favor
ment outside government. The least edu- young workers. In Indonesia, industries with
cated women are the most disadvantaged, youth employment shares more than twice
confined either to domestic work or to non- the national average are concentrated in
wage work in home-based enterprises and electronics and textile manufacturing, heav-
subsistence agriculture.50 ily engaged in exporting. The young workers
in these youth-intensive exporting sectors
are disproportionately well-educated—
Broadening labor 47 percent have completed secondary
market opportunities schooling, compared with 11 percent of
In all countries, a good investment cli- other employed youth. Similarly, in Viet-
mate lets the private sector expand, helps nam 20 percent of the young workers in
trade flourish, and allows the country to those sectors have completed secondary
attract foreign direct investment, all needed school, compared with 8 percent in other
for job creation. Youth can contribute to sectors, and in Brazil 41 percent, compared
the growth of these sectors, but steps are with 15 percent.
needed to mitigate the effect of market and Youth-intensive exporting sectors seem
policy failures that disproportionately affect to target young female workers, who make
youth. The steps will differ depending on a up 74 percent of employed youth in those
country’s level of development. In middle- sectors in Indonesia and Vietnam, com-
income countries and countries where labor pared with 46–50 percent in other sectors.
market institutions are more binding and Young workers in exporting firms are bet-
likely to be enforced, reforming labor mar- ter paid than their counterparts elsewhere.
Going to work 107

Figure 4.7 Productivity and earnings increased faster for youth relative to older workers in Slovenia during the
transition, (1992–2001)

Relative productivity differential Relative wage differential


Percent Percent
120 120
Ages 40–49
100 100
Ages 40–49

80 Ages 18–29 80

Ages 18–29
60 60

40 40
1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001

Source: Vodopivec (2005).


Note: The figures show relative productivity and earnings of different age groups compared to a reference group of people ages 50 and
above, whose productivity and earnings were normalized to 100 percent.

In Indonesia, young workers in the export cated labor force able to adapt to new technol-
sector were paid 30 percent more than ogy with appropriate knowledge, skills, and
young workers in other sectors and 20 per- behavior. In several Latin American countries,
cent more than young workers in other this has boosted high-skilled wages.54 The
manufacturing. Young workers may also be experiences of Thailand and Malaysia sug-
attracted to exporting firms and those with gest that government has a role to play in
at least some foreign ownership, because of reducing the negative production externali-
the greater likelihood of training.52 ties caused by accelerating wage increases,
The young may be particularly attractive in turn caused by shortages in quality
to firms in the new and growing sectors of labor.55 Evidence suggests that opportuni-
the economy because they are more adapt- ties in export-oriented sectors can provide
able than older workers to new production incentives for youth to acquire more skills.
methods. During the Estonian transition, Among 48 developing countries, increases
the relative share of employment and the in apparel and shoe exports as a share of
returns to experience rose faster for the GDP were found to be positively associated
young.53 In Slovenia, wages and labor pro- with subsequent upturns in both male and
ductivity rose faster for the youngest work- female secondary school enrollment. For
ers (figure 4.7). In the early 1990s, younger the average country, a doubling of apparel
workers were the least productive age and footwear exports as a share of GDP
group in the labor market. The productiv- raises female secondary school attendance
ity of those between 18 and 29 years old by 20–25 percent.56
was about 70 percent of the productivity
of those 50 years and older. Around 1996, Reforming institutions
young workers’ productivity caught up with World Development Report 2006 discusses
that of 40- to 49-year-olds, and by 2001 why governments intervene in the labor mar-
youth had become the most productive. At ket and how poorly designed or inappropri-
the same time, earnings rose at a pace faster ate policies can make conditions worse for
for the young than for older workers, clos- equity and efficiency. As shown earlier, these
ing significantly the gap in earnings with policies disproportionately affect youth.
older workers. In high-income countries, the result is a
Industrial growth led by foreign direct reduction in the employment rate for young
investment was initiated partly due to the people and an increase in the incidence and
availability of cheaper young labor. However, duration of unemployment (see spotlight
the dynamic growth process increased the on baby booms following chapter 4). In low-
demand for a highly skilled and highly edu- and middle-income countries, the result is a
108 WORLD DEVELOPMENT REPORT 2007

BOX 4.4 Reforming part of the labor market has been no substitute for comprehensive
reform in Spain and France
Spain and France have suffered from high costs proved to be effective in reducing overall the introduction of the fixed duration contract,
unemployment among youth over the last two unemployment, particularly for the young. the Contrat à Durée Déterminée, CDD, a par-
decades. Both governments have experimented Youth unemployment decreased from about 40 tial reform in 1979. The proportion of those
with partial labor market reforms as a means to percent in 1995 to 20 percent in 2000. employed under the CDD rose from 3 percent
reduce the youth unemployment problem. In France, youth unemployment rates have in 1983 to 17 percent in 2000. This substantially
In Spain, the initial reform in the early remained above 20 percent since the 1990s. In increased turnover without a reduction in
1990s was intended to increase employment 2006, the government proposed a contract for first unemployment duration.
flows among youth by making it less costly for employment (Contrat Première Embauche, CPE) The lesson: Because partial reform, as in
firms to hire young workers. Lowering the fir- that would have allowed employers to fire workers Spain in the early 1990s, tends to reinforce
ing costs for entry level jobs without changing under 26 within a two-year trial period without market segmentation, it is a poor substitute
the costs for regular jobs may have increased giving a reason. It was hoped that employers for broad reform, and its public support and
firms’ willingness to hire new workers but also would be more likely to recruit young people if effectiveness are limited. Another alternative,
made them reluctant to retain these workers. they knew they could be fired readily and that this suggested by analysts in France, could be a
The result of this policy was a systematic rise would reduce youth unemployment. Students, more gradual approach that deemphasizes
in the use of temporary contracts for young with the support of workers’ unions and opposi- the segmented labor market for different age
workers, without an increase in permanent and tion parties, demonstrated against the new law groups—perhaps a progressive contract in
stable employment. Over 30 percent of employ- and forced a showdown with the government, which protection gradually increases as a
ment became temporary, while unemployment leading to the withdrawal of the proposed law. worker’s tenure rises.
remained as high as 24 percent. Spain had Some decried the lack of consultation. Sources: Blanchard (2006); Blanchard and Landier
to move to broader reforms in 1997. Policies Analysts also argued that the CPE reinforced (2001); Cahuc and Carcillo (2006); Kugler (2004); and
such as reductions of payroll tax and dismissal the market segmentation already in place since Kugler, Jimeno, and Henanz (2003).

segmented labor market—one comprising a and train young inexperienced workers.


small number of workers who benefit from Analysts advise against jumps in protec-
greater employment and income security tion from one type of employment to
and another comprising a large number of another—jumps likely to segment the mar-
young workers alternating between short ket (box 4.4). A more progressive contract
spells of employment and joblessness, with is preferred, where protection increases
little access to security and opportunities to gradually with tenure with no large discrete
develop their human capital.57 changes in protection.59 Such contracts pro-
vide incentives for firms to invest in young
Broad, not piecemeal, labor market reform. workers as their productivity increases with
To protect those currently employed, some longer tenure.
governments have experimented with mod- A similar approach applies to the mini-
est labor market reforms, but because partial mum wage, intended to protect workers’
reforms tend to reinforce market segmen- wages from falling to very low levels. In
tation, the results were not favorable (box many developing countries, however, the
4.4). For policy makers, a move from partial minimum wage is high. In Chile, Colom-
reform toward more general and comprehen- bia, Costa Rica, Nicaragua, Panama, Peru,
sive reform will benefit employment creation and República Bolivariana de Venezuela,
with a disproportionate effect on youth. The it exceeded 50 percent of the median wage
level of protection has to be balanced with for workers ages 26–40 between 1980 and
the flexibility needed to encourage job cre- 2000.60 Yet many workers receive much less
ation. In 1990, Colombia introduced a labor than the minimum wage because of weak
market reform that substantially reduced enforcement. Young workers’ wages tend to
the costs of dismissing workers. The reform be concentrated at the lower end of the wage
increased turnover for formal sector workers distribution anyway. For example, in Russia
relative to nonformal but also reduced the the share of young workers with labor mar-
length of unemployment spells, particularly ket earnings below 30 percent of the median
for youth and for more educated workers.58 wage is estimated at 38 percent for 2002, in
At any general level of protection, firms Indonesia at 35 percent for 2003, and in
will need additional incentives to employ Ghana at 52 percent for 1998.61
Going to work 109

Several countries have differentiated Better design of wage subsidies and bet-
the minimum wage by age to mitigate the ter targeting are needed to ensure that young
effects on youth employment. Setting a hires do not gain employment at the expense
lower minimum wage for youth reduces of other employees, and that the subsidy
the disemployment effects by keeping it goes to those employers who would not
profitable for firms to hire and train young have hired young workers in the absence of
inexperienced workers.62 Below-minimum this additional financial incentive. Evidence
apprenticeship wages significantly increased from the Czech Republic, Hungary, and
the job opportunities for young graduates in Poland demonstrates that youth-specific
Chile.63 Lower wages should be intended to wage subsidies can be of particular benefit if
subsidize on-the-job training so youth can they are well targeted to the most disadvan-
develop the skills needed to increase their taged, with females with lower educational
productivity and future earnings. attainment benefiting the most. In OECD
In many countries where the public sec- countries, wage subsidies work best for
tor offers higher wages and more generous unemployed youth, especially those from
benefits and employment security, educated more disadvantaged backgrounds.66
youth remain out of work while waiting for Differences in the target group, eligibility
openings in the public sector. Closing the criteria, assignment to participation, type of
gap in pay and benefits between the public jobs, and duration and amount of subsidies
and the private sector, or at least reducing the will play a role in the effectiveness of these
incentive to wait for a public sector opening, programs. These programs exhibit large
will reduce youth unemployment among the variations. In Belgium, the “employment
most educated. Closing the gap in informa- plan” offers two-year subsidies for employ-
tion, promoting opportunities in the private ers through a reduction in social insur-
sector, and aligning higher education more ance contribution, of up to 25 percent of
with labor market demands will shorten the the gross wage in the first year and around
long queues of young men and women wait- 17 percent of the gross wage in the second
ing for public sector jobs. Governments also year of the subsidy. In Sweden, a program
have to signal a willingness to move from targeting the long-term unemployed offers
job guarantees (explicit or implicit) to a employment subsidies for six months. In
more competitive process for entry into the the Slovak Republic, two-year subsidies were
public sector, perhaps by making the appli- offered both in the public and private sector.
cation process merit based. In Turkey, the Because wage subsidies are costly and less
requirement of passing a set of examinations effective in economies with large informal
to apply for a government post shortened sectors, their applicability is limited mostly
the queue for public sector jobs and shifted to middle-income countries. Even in mid-
graduates to the pursuit of other careers. dle-income countries, however, the financial
constraints mean that programs have to be
Direct employment creation. Wage subsi- well-targeted and be of limited duration.67
dies to private firms have sometimes encour-
aged employers to hire new entrants.64 In a Expanding rural opportunities
world where wages cannot adjust to com- In many developing countries, many youth “[Working in government] is stable,
pensate for the risks firms might perceive still live in rural areas. For rural youth, with higher social status and more
from hiring inexperienced young workers, employment opportunities are not only space for future development as a
subsidies will have an effect on hiring and in agriculture but also off farm. Includ- government official.”
dismissal policies of employers. Several eval- ing rural towns, the rural nonfarm sector
Jingxiao, university student,
uations of wage subsidy schemes in European accounts for about 40 percent of full-time
China
countries are available. Almost all studies find rural employment in Asia and Latin Amer-
December 2005
a large beneficial impact on employment.65 ica and 20 percent in Sub-Saharan Africa.68
While encouraging, these findings do not The history of economic development has
usually take into account potential displace- shown that development of the nonfarm
ment effects or deadweight loss that may be sector is tied to improved productivity on
associated with wage subsidy schemes. the farm. As technological innovations raise
110 WORLD DEVELOPMENT REPORT 2007

including those in other countries (see chap-


BOX 4.5 Off-farm opportunities for youth ter 8). So policies to develop the nonfarm
in Palanpur, India sector will have a particularly pronounced
effect on youth, even if not targeted at them.73
The nonfarm economy has expanded hard work and, in some cases, exposure to For example, the promotion of small and
greatly in the North Indian village of Palan- health hazards.
pur in the past decades. In the mid-1980s, Although employment outside Palan- medium rural enterprises that use imported
more than a third of village income came pur is highly valued by villagers, particularly technologies could have a differential impact
from nonagricultural activities, and more the young eager to venture beyond the vil- on youth, given their advantage in using new
than 70 villagers were employed regularly lage, access remains limited. Why? Because
technologies, as with Taiwan, China’s promo-
or semi-regularly in the nonfarm sector (of a of social status (proxied by caste and educa-
working-age male population of about 250). tion levels), wealth (bribes need to be paid), tion of rural manufacturing. As subcontrac-
Visits to the village in the 1990s and in 2005 and outside contacts (a “recommendation” tors, rural firms can acquire inputs, technical
indicate that the expansion of nonfarm is often required). know-how, and links to external markets,
occupations has not abated. Palanpur is located in socially con-
increasing their attractiveness to young
Many young male villagers from Palan- servative rural Uttar Pradesh, and outside
pur hold semi-regular jobs in industrial employment opportunities are generally workers.74 As education levels for rural youth
workshops and bakeries in the nearby confined to males. Elsewhere, nonfarm jobs improve, they can enter a broader range of
towns of Chandausi and Moradabad. are also accessible to women. nonagricultural occupations. In rural India
Employment contracts are often piecework,
offering fairly high incomes in return for
and in Brazil, better educated youth have a
Source: Lanjouw and Stern (2006).
higher likelihood of moving into highly pro-
ductive nonfarm work.75 Some of these new
productivity on the farm, labor is freed up off-farm opportunities involve physically
to move to the nonfarm sector.69 demanding and hazardous work (box 4.5).
The range of opportunities in rural As transportation and economic integration
areas is far wider than might be apparent reach the small towns scattered throughout
at first glance. The rural nonfarm economy rural areas, rural youth gain better access
generates 30–50 percent of rural incomes to urban opportunities without the need to
throughout the developing world, shares migrate.
that continue to grow.70 In some instances,
the high share is a result of crop failures Facilitating mobility
or other adverse shocks to the farm sector. For 29 developing countries with data, youth
In most cases, however, rising productiv- are 40 percent more likely than older people
ity growth in the agriculture sector raises to move from rural to urban areas or to
farm income and hence the demand for move across urban areas. Those who move
goods produced outside agriculture. Rising have better employment outcomes, with
agriculture labor productivity also frees up mobility correlated negatively with youth
labor to work off farm. unemployment and positively with employ-
The rural nonfarm economy, extremely ment and labor force participation.76
heterogeneous, provides an important The Chinese rural-urban migration typ-
source of youth employment throughout ifies the pattern.77 Rural migrants tend to be
the developing world. In Latin America, younger than 35. Two-thirds are male. Half
about half the youth population ages 15–24 are single. Female migrants are younger and
in rural areas, and more than 65 percent of less likely to be married. Rural migrants are
those ages 25–34, work in nonagricultural more educated than rural residents who did
activities. In 15 countries in this region, the not migrate: 66 percent had a lower second-
higher share of youth employment in sev- ary school education, compared with 40 per-
eral nonagricultural sectors compared to cent of rural residents who did not migrate.
employment in agriculture bears out the Rural migrants are less educated than urban
importance of the rural nonfarm econ- residents, and so tend to fill the least skilled
omy.71 In rural India, the likelihood of mov- jobs available in cities. Even so, the incen-
ing into nonfarm casual occupations peaks tives to migrate are clearly economic. Per
at age 22, and in Brazil at around 33.72 capita urban incomes are more than three
Because young people are the most times those in rural areas, and the gap is ris-
mobile, they are the most likely to switch sec- ing. Even though rural migrants are paid
tors to take advantage of new opportunities, half of what similarly skilled urban resi-
Going to work 111

dents are paid, their pay is still well above Those who want to work on their own need
that of workers in rural areas. Many rural information, mentoring, and credit.
migrants send money back to their relatives
in rural areas, representing 13 percent of Skill development beyond schools
Chinese rural income in 2003. In middle-income countries with growing
Rural migrants nevertheless face real industrial sectors, the bridges between school
disadvantages relative to urban workers. and work, meant to address youth’s lack of
In China, migrant workers have little legal work experience and severe skill mismatches,
recourse to compel payment, few receive take the form of formal apprenticeships or
health insurance or pensions, and few have bringing work experience into the school
good access to social services. China makes context. In low-income countries with lim-
this explicit by the restriction on establish- ited formal schooling, traditional apprentice-
ing legal residency in urban areas. These ships are more widespread and more likely to
restrictions imply that total employment in provide the initial experience and skills youth
the city is artificially smaller than its most need. In all countries, training systems must
efficient size. Allowing employment to grow not only prepare youths for entry to work,
to its peak efficient level could raise pro- but provide pathways for continual learning
duction by as much as 35 percent.78 Rural over a lifetime in response to changing tech-
migrants without residency permits have to nologies and global economic requirements.
pay significantly more for education, health, Increasing the incentives for firms to train
and other public services.79 The govern- and to reform training systems is essential.
ment clearly recognized these issues, and is
making policy changes to gradually delink Formal apprenticeship schemes. Germany’s
the residency permit system from its welfare “dual system” combines part-time schooling
program, and to strengthen enforcement of with work and apprenticeship. Employer
labor regulations.80 involvement ensures that the skills offered fit
Restrictions on rural-urban migration, the needs of employers, reducing the likeli-
not unique to China, show up in various hood of skill mismatches. The program has
guises in many countries. Such restrictions wide coverage: more than half of all youth “Lack of experience is the main
tend to depress wages in rural areas relative undertake an apprenticeship. As in Germany, barrier that young people face while
to urban areas, whereas allowing population alternative school-based paths to qualifica- seeking employment, because most
flows out of rural areas tends to raise wages tions in France, the United Kingdom, and employers prefer a few years of work
for those remaining in rural villages, and the United States are associated with rather experience.”
benefits the country as a whole by improving selective improvements in early labor market
efficient allocation of labor.81 Many youth experience.82 Overall, the strongest evidence
Rahat, 24, Bangladesh
also pursue opportunities to work overseas, favoring formal apprenticeships is the posi-
whether they are from rural or urban areas. tive impact on employment for young men,
Issues of international migration, including and on earnings for young women.
country policies, are taken up in chapter 8. Do apprenticeships apply to developing
countries? Probably not, in their current for-
mat, because of the small share of employment
Choosing to work and
in the modern wage sector, the slow growth of
developing the skills to do so wage employment and jobs for new appren-
Young people around the world ask, when tices, and the weakness of institutions.83 Some
should I start to work? What kind of job developing countries have tried the dual sys-
do I want? How do I look for it? How do tem, but with no clear pattern of success. The
I get ready for work? Preparing youth for Mubarak-Kohl initiative in Egypt, launched to
employment starts with general education introduce the dual system in 1995, illustrates
that provides the foundation for later acqui- the challenges to starting such initiatives. Early
sition of vocational skills. These vocational reports from the ILO indicated resistance in
skills are acquired in the formal education the public education system and the absence
system and beyond—in apprenticeship, of private sector umbrella organizations to
work experience, and nonformal training. manage joint training courses.84
112 WORLD DEVELOPMENT REPORT 2007

To succeed, these programs need to move ing the quality and relevance of the training
beyond the traditional craft and technical they could offer apprentices.89 The vouch-
trades and provide more general content ers helped create a market for training that
as a foundation for occupational special- encouraged new sources of supply and com-
ization. This could reduce mismatches in petition. Providing literacy and basic educa-
growing sectors, promote adaptability, and tion for apprentices and certifying their skills
reduce gender bias. The United Kingdom’s on completion also improve outcomes.
Modern Apprenticeship program offers
apprenticeships in nontraditional trades in Training by employers. Bringing work
business administration, retailing, catering, experience into the schooling context can
personal care, and information technology; improve the youth transition to work (chap-
women constitute nearly half the appren- ter 3); at the same time employers provide
tices. Australia’s New Apprenticeships com- and finance training on and off the job long
bine practical work and structured training, after youth exit school. As a source of skills
leading to nationally recognized qualifica- for youths, employers are often overlooked
tion in more than 500 occupations. It is not in favor of public training programs. Sur-
clear how well these types of programs will veys conducted by the World Bank in 37
perform in low-income countries.85 countries covering 18,217 manufacturing
firms show that enterprises are active train-
Traditional apprenticeships in low-income ers.90 Nearly 60 percent of firms in East Asia
countries. Formal apprenticeships in the and the Pacific provide training with the
modern wage sector may be less relevant share falling to just under 20 percent in the
in many developing countries, where self- Middle East and North Africa.
employment and the growth of microenter- Leaving training to enterprises does not,
prises in the informal sector have accounted however, ensure access for all to training.
for an expanded share of employment over Enterprises often are less likely to invest in
the past three decades. In Ghana, 80–90 per- skills widely used by other enterprises for
cent of all basic skills training comes from fear of losing trained workers and their
traditional apprenticeships, compared with investment. Thus, not all firms will train,
5–10 percent from public training institutions nor will all workers in enterprises be trained.
and 10–15 percent from nongovernment In Colombia, Indonesia, Malaysia, Mexico,
sources.86 Across West Africa, it is common to and Taiwan, China, large manufacturing
find more apprentices than wage employees firms are more likely to train than smaller
in informal sector firms.87 The strengths of ones.91 Kenya, Zambia, and Zimbabwe
traditional apprenticeships, while not care- show a similar pattern, with manufacturing
fully evaluated, are their practical orienta- firms employing 151 or more workers being
“To avoid jobs like house servants tion, self-regulation, and self-financing. They twice as likely to invest in external train-
and cleaners, youth programs can cater to individuals who lack the educational ing for their workers as those employing
include training in other jobs like requirements for formal training (rural and 51 to 150, and more than 10 times as likely
catering, carpentry, and building.” urban poor), and they are generally cost- as those with firms of 10 or fewer workers.
effective. However, they favor young men, Firms with a higher likelihood of training
Jack, 16, Zambia
screen out applicants from very poor house- are those that export, have foreign invest-
holds, perpetuate traditional technologies, ment, and adopt new technologies—and
and lack standards and quality assurance.88 they are more likely to train workers with
Steps to strengthen traditional apprentice- more education.92 Other firms will need
ship include improving literacy and the basic financial incentives to train young inexpe-
education of apprentices, opening access to rienced workers. Policies can also condition
new technologies, improving the pedagogi- the participation in other programs (like
cal and technical skills of master craftsmen, wage subsidies for new entrants) on the
and certifying skills attained. In Kenya’s Jua provision of training for young workers.
Kali, the informal sector, vouchers enhanced
the access of master craftsmen to new tech- Technical and vocational education and
nologies and upgraded their skills, improv- training. Because not all firms can pro-
Going to work 113

vide training and because not all young employers and competency-based delivery
workers benefit from employer training, by a mixture of public and private provi-
public interventions are needed. Training sion, measuring performance in terms of
offered by employers is relevant and effec- job placement and increased worker pro-
tive, but that provided by the public sector ductivity. Curricula developed in a modu-
is subject to question. Rigid, low-quality lar fashion promote flexible entry and exit
training systems disconnected from labor for training consistent with a lifelong learn-
markets have led many countries to reform ing model. Sound monitoring and evalu-
their programs. Nonformal training sys- ation programs are important in guiding
tems outside formal education are changing reforms, policy development, and market
the way providers are governed, managed, operations.
and financed (chapter 3). China, Chile, the
Islamic Republic of Iran, the Republic of Starting work on their own:
Korea, Malaysia, Mozambique, and Singa- Self-employment and
pore, recognizing the fiscal limits of public youth entrepreneurs
provision, have opened the doors to public- Many young people in the labor market
private partnerships to diversify financ- work in businesses they have started on
ing for training, promote sustainability, their own.95 Some are entrepreneurs by
and improve access and relevance. In Latin necessity, others by opportunity.96 In Latin
America, but also other regions, the roles America, 13 percent of those 16–24 are in
of government as financier and provider of entrepreneurial activities, the great majority
training (Servicio Nacional de Aprendizaje (12 percent) self-employed; only 1 percent
or SENA, for example) are being reassessed are employers. The self-employed are gener-
for national training agencies.93 Specialized ally less educated and poorer than employ-
training agencies, responsible for train- ers. Women make up about one-third of
ing policies and strategies, are assuming a the self-employed entrepreneurs and about
larger role in policy development and man- one-quarter of the employers.
agement of training expenditures instead Of the unemployed in Peru in 1998, 18
of provision. These are also opening more percent became self-employed by 2001,
competition between public and private compared with only 6 percent in Nicaragua
providers to improve quality and relevance (table 4.1). The higher self-employment in
of the training offered. Peru explains part of the lower persistence
In Mauritius, the Industrial Vocational of joblessness in Peru. About half the young
Training Board has split the financing and
provision of training and adopted a compet- Table 4.1 Employment transitions for youth (ages 16–30)
itive model for procuring training services.
Status in 2001
Argentina and Chile have similar national
bodies. In Chile, the Servicio Nacional de Unemployed or Employee (%) Self-employed Employer (%)
Status in 1998 inactive (%) (%)
Capacitación y Empleo (SENCE), a spe-
Peru
cialized agency of the Ministry of Labor,
maintains no capacity for the provision of Unemployed or 33 24 18 2
inactive
training and instead procures training ser-
Employee 7 28 13 1
vices from other public and private provid-
ers for target groups. Competition promotes Self-employed 13 25 52 1
efficiency in delivery and more closely links Employer 9 9 55 27
training to market demands, shifting the Nicaragua
financing model for training from supply- Unemployed or 60 18 7 0
driven to demand-driven.94 inactive
Overall, training systems are moving Employee 25 59 23 17
away from a narrow focus on inputs for Self-employed 11 23 45 9
training, with more instructors, workshops,
Employer 3 17 40 31
and equipment—to a focus on outcomes,
Source: Llisteri and others (2006).
with attention to skills standards set by Note: Not included in the table are students and those in unpaid family work.
114 WORLD DEVELOPMENT REPORT 2007

people self-employed in 1998 were still self- entrepreneurs with high-growth potential,
employed three years later. Nine percent of frequently founded by young middle-class
the self-employed in Nicaragua had become people. Universities, business schools, pri-
employers within three years, but only 1 per- vate foundations, incubators, angel inves-
cent in Peru. And only a third of employers tor networks, and, more recently, some
in 1998 continued to be employers in 2001, governments provide direct support to the
“I do not want to be a babshahi the majority becoming self-employed or entrepreneur—networking, incubation,
[Bengali word for businessman, paid employed. All in all, these patterns sug- mentoring, and financing. For example,
implying small businessman]. I gest that self-employment is a faster route Endeavor (a program in Argentina, Brazil,
want to be a bijnizman [after the to paid employment, but if it persists over Chile, Mexico, and Uruguay) helps young
English word, implying large scale the medium term, it is not likely to create ventures in a second round of growth
business].” additional jobs. mainly through networking (with private
In Latin American countries, about half investors) and mentoring.
Male young person, Bangladesh of entrepreneurs felt motivated to strike out The public sector in some countries has
on their own just after secondary and tertiary started to support entrepreneurs close to or
school and during their first labor experi- just after start-up. The Umsobomvu Youth
ence, using the knowledge, skills, and con- Fund is a development fund in South Africa
tacts they had acquired.97 They come mainly created by the government to support access
from middle- or upper-middle-class families, to information, skills development, and
about half of them from families with at least financial support for people under age 35.
one entrepreneurial parent. More than half Softex in Brazil, a public-private partnership,
are graduates starting their business within targets university students in software, pro-
two years of leaving university. This small viding training courses, technical assistance,
group is responsible for a disproportionate and networking support. In Chile, a seed cap-
part of the jobs created by new companies. In ital program led by CORFO (Corporación de
Argentina, for instance, five years after their Fomento de la Producción) provides finance
creation, about 6 percent of the new firms and technical assistance to entrepreneurs,
are responsible for 60 percent of the jobs in operating a public-private partnership with
survivor firms from that cohort.98 universities and incubators to identify and
These entrepreneurs face several con- evaluate the most promising ventures and
straints to creating and growing a venture: prepare them for seed capital. This program
access to financing, to formal networks, and was replicated by the Buenos Aires Emprende
to clients, suppliers, and skilled workers. The 1 and scaled up by Emprende 2 by large pub-
Global Entrepreneurship Monitor indicates lic universities and trade chambers fostering
only a very small share of these entrepre- software entrepreneurs.
neurships are able to succeed. Young Latin
American entrepreneurs face higher trans-
action costs than those in East Asia. Most Providing a springboard to
of them use their networks (mainly pro- reintegrate the most vulnerable
duction networks of clients and suppliers Vulnerable young people—those who
and social networks of family and friends) started work too early, never attended
to overcome obstacles and make their ven- school, failed to acquire literacy, or never
tures grow. General policies that enhance made it to the workforce—need a second
the environment for doing business are not chance. Some disadvantaged youth—such
youth-specific but are needed to facilitate as those with disabilities, ethnic minori-
entrepreneurship in general. ties, and orphans—never had even a first
However, because youth lack the net- chance. Providing them with the relevant
works, experience, and collateral of adults, skills to enter or reenter the workforce
they face additional constraints. Several reduces inequities in the labor market and
new programs to promote entrepreneur- increases their productivity and ability to
ship have been initiated in Latin America, break out of poverty traps. Because second
but they are fairly new and have not been chances are costly, they have to be well-
formally evaluated. They are targeted to targeted, designed to increase youth skills,
Going to work 115

and geared to labor market needs. Because


young people in need of second chances BOX 4.6 Employing youth with disabilities
are usually vulnerable along several dimen-
In addition to the usual challenges youth Experience from low- and middle-income
sions, programs have to be comprehensive. face finding employment, disabled youth countries also demonstrates that disabled
face a lack of access to jobs and employ- youth can be integrated into the labor mar-
ment centers because of stigma and other ket. In Egypt, Ethiopia, and Uganda, organiza-
Second-chance programs barriers. In particular, disabled people have tions are empowering disabled youths and
are costly but needed often been denied an education: About one- their parents to plan for and pursue employ-
Policies and programs for second chances third of all children not in primary school ment. In Pakistan many disabled youth are
have a disability. In Brazil, while 55 percent employed at Independent Living Centers.
are typically costly and rarely successful. of 18- to 19-year-olds are employed, only 29 The Salva Vita Foundation in Hungary
Meager and Evans (1998) observe that “it is percent of physically disabled youths and has run a program since 1996 to integrate
rapidly becoming conventional wisdom in 24 percent of mentally disabled youths have the disabled into the general workforce:
jobs. This lack of education and employment
the policy evaluation literature that labor • The Supported Employment Service
sets them up for a lifetime of poverty. In Ser-
market training and re-training schemes for assists in job placement, offers training,
bia and Montenegro, 70 percent of disabled
and helps solve problems at work.
the unemployed have not lived up to expec- people are poor and only 13 percent have
access to employment. In Sri Lanka, over 80 • The Employees’ Club provides individual
tations.” A recent review of 19 programs, five and group follow-up for clients who have
percent of the disabled are unemployed.
of them in transition and developing coun- found employment through the Sup-
Evidence from OECD countries shows
tries, shows that training programs rarely that disabled youth can be quite productive ported Employment Service.
improve the employment and earnings of given the right attitudes and supports, dou- • The Work Experience Program integrates
young participants.99 The results underline bly important because disabled youth have employment into the school curriculum.
greater difficulty recovering from an unsuc-
the importance of having universal access to cessful school-to-work transition. Some
first-chance policies and programs. In some OECD countries have instituted national Sources: Bercovich (2004); World Bank (2004c);
cases, however, the costs of not intervening policies on school-to-work transition for Stapleton and Burkhauser (2003); Tudawe
are overwhelming, and if well designed, sec- disabled youth. (2001); and www.salvavita.hu.

ond chances could be cost effective.


An estimated 8.4 million children are
engaged in what international conventions
call the “unconditional worst” forms of guidance in selecting the right model.101
child labor, which include child trafficking, Experience suggests, however, that interven-
prostitution, and other forms of extremely tions need to require that youth are either
hazardous work. About 10–12 percent of working or actively searching for work, pro-
the population in developing countries is vide the skills relevant to integrate or rein-
estimated to be disabled, and some evidence tegrate them into work, and be delivered
suggests they are disproportionately poor.100 efficiently in response to local demand.
Young people with disabilities, as well as
Beneficiaries have to work or look for work. “Discrimination forms the biggest
youth from ethnic minority groups, invari-
Unlike other interventions, such as cash challenge given the social exclusion
ably face more difficulties finding employ-
transfers or unemployment insurance, of disabled persons from society.
ment, despite the evidence that they can be
interventions targeting youth need to Most of the disabled youth haven’t
productive given the right support (box 4.6).
include either work or active search as accomplished their education due
From an equity perspective, public interven-
conditions to benefit from the programs. to lack of support, hence they have
tion is needed to support the most vulner-
Programs in the public sector that focus on a skill deficit [relative to] the job
able and to offer them a second chance to
the provision of public works to produce market.”
reintegrate into the workplace. For the very
needed public goods and services pro-
young, some second-chance opportunities Frederick, 23, Kenya
vide good opportunities for young work-
could reintegrate them into the education
ers, particularly the low skilled and rural,
system (chapter 3). For the large pool of low-
to acquire initial work experience. Few
skilled unemployed youth, a second chance
evaluations have tested whether these pro-
could help them move into productive work.
grams improve the chances of participants
to enter the labor market and enhance
What might make employment in the private sector. One
for successful programs? positive example is Argentina’s Trabajar
Not enough evaluations of youth employ- program, which had a significant impact
ment interventions are available to provide on participants’ current income.102 There
116 WORLD DEVELOPMENT REPORT 2007

is also some evidence of lagged gains from private sector employment by 13 percent-
past participation. Among continuing par- age points. Interestingly, effects for older
ticipants in this program, about half felt cohorts were insignificant, so the successes
that it improved their chances of getting were confined to youth.
a job, two-thirds that it gave them a mar- Public employment services should also
ketable skill, and about one-third that it require youth to be active in job searching.
expanded their contacts.103 In Korea, the Philippines, and Thailand,
The African AGETIP (Agence d’Exécu- however, young people make little use of
tion des Travaux d’Intérêt Publique) pro- state labor offices.106 In those countries,
grams combine efforts to build public employment offices have been transformed
infrastructure such as roads, buildings, and into one-stop centers giving job seekers
sanitation systems, with efforts to provide access to job search assistance and place-
jobs and training for unemployed youth. ment in vocational training. In Korea, how-
Construction firms that get the contracts ever, only 5.8 percent of the unemployed
also agree to use relatively labor-intensive found jobs through the public employ-
practices to use local inexperienced youth ment services, and even that may overes-
who receive training funded by AGETIP. The timate the impact because there were no
youth are hired on a temporary basis, but the proper controls to measure the placement
training and work experience are important rate for people not using the service.
inroads to later, more permanent employ- An interesting recent example of private
ment. Because the public works projects are involvement from Brazil is the First Job
local, they can be targeted geographically to program started in Curitiba municipality,
assist relatively poor, uneducated, or unem- financed by the local government. It aims
ployed areas of the population. to link youth with firms in the municipal-
The evaluation of the first seven years ity (no evaluation is available yet). Another
of the AGETIP program in Senegal found promising public employment program is
that the number of engineering firms more JobsNet, a quickly growing job-matching
than tripled, the number of construc- agency in Sri Lanka.107
tion firms increased fivefold, and 35,000
person-years of employment were gener- Programs should provide the relevant
ated. Unfortunately, governance can be skills. Comprehensive programs that
an issue.104 Public works projects require provide training as part of a package that
transparency and oversight to ensure that includes basic education, employment ser-
the projects are targeted to the poor, that vices, and social services are more likely to
only worthy projects are funded, that the have better success. Entra 21, a global effort
money is used wisely, and that inexperi- intended to prepare 19,000 disadvantaged
enced youth are trained. youth for jobs requiring information and
Public works provide good targeting communication technology in 18 countries
for other youth interventions that could in Latin America, placed at least 40 percent
increase the likelihood of youth finding bet- of the targeted youth in employment. The
ter employment opportunities beyond the programs offer a complete range of services,
program. Argentina’s Proempleo experi- including not just technical and life-skills
ment in 1998–2002 tested mechanisms to training but also job placement services,
help participants in the public works pro- internships, and advice in developing self-
gram (Trabajar) find employment in the employment initiatives. A meta-analysis of
private sector. It assessed whether wage sub- six Entra 21 projects revealed a higher than
sidies and specialized training could assist expected job placement rate among 2,890
participants in the transition from workfare youths.108 Employment rates rose from
to regular work. The wage subsidy increased 15 percent at the start to 54 percent 6–12
the probability of becoming employed in months later. Most jobs were in the formal
the private sector by 9 percentage points sector, permanent, and paid the minimum
for young participants under 30.105 The wage or higher. Although most youth opted
wage subsidy and training programs raised for salaried employment, in several coun-
Going to work 117

BOX 4.7 Joven programs increased employment and earnings for some disadvantaged youths
The Joven programs offer comprehensive train- employment conditions before the program. In and adult females. In Chile one study showed a
ing to unemployed and economically disad- Argentina 83 percent of participants, and in Chile negative impact on wages of -8.8 percent, led
vantaged youths 16 to 29 years of age, aiming 57 percent were unemployed. Women were fairly by a reduction of wages in the formal sector.
to improve their human and social capital and equally represented in Chile, while Argentina Subsequent analyses found a positive impact
employability. The demand-driven model has had the lowest female participation (about 40 on earnings approaching 26 percent, strongly
been customized throughout Argentina, Chile, percent). Targeting focused on 16- to 24-year- significant for youths 21 and younger. In abso-
Colombia, the Dominican Republic, Panama, Par- olds, about 70 percent of all participants.109 lute terms the wage impact was higher for men,
aguay, Peru, and República Bolivariana de Ven- but in a comparison of pre- and postprogram
Employment
ezuela. Technical training and internship experi- earnings, women had a slightly higher increase
The programs increased the probability of ben-
ences with employers are combined with basic relative to men.
eficiaries finding employment upon graduation,
life skills and other support services to ensure
especially for women. In Argentina, the program Costs and benefits
social integration and job readiness (see table).
increased the probability of employment for With the given underlying cost per trainee and
Private and public institutions—contracted
young adult women (21 years and older) by the impact on employment and earnings, the
through public bidding mechanisms—provide
about 10 percentage points over a control net present value (NPV) of the program can
the training and organize the internships.
group. In Chile the program increased the prob- be calculated (given a discount rate, usually
The programs target the poor, and more
ability of employment 21 percentage points, assumed to be 5 percent). While costly, these
than 60 percent of participants come from low-
with strongly significant results for youths 21 programs in Argentina and Chile have positive
income families. The highest education level
and younger. NPVs, with a higher NPV in Chile compared
completed by beneficiaries was secondary, with
to Argentina. It is important to note that this
significant participation by school dropouts Earnings
calculation does not take into account the
(50 percent in Chile Joven). Other targeting In Argentina the program increased monthly
externalities from the program such as bet-
criteria, such as employment, gender, and age, wages by about 10 percent over a control group,
ter health outcomes and reductions in risky
also applied. Most beneficiaries had precarious with results more favorable for young males
behavior among participants. In this sense,
the estimates are likely to provide only a lower
Costs and impact of programs varies across countries bound of the NPV. It is also important to note
that with the exception of forgone earnings, the
Argentina Chile party incurring the direct costs (public funds)
Proyecto Joven Chile Joven is different from the party benefiting from the
program—the participants.
Coverage (people) 116,000 165,000
Cost per trainee ($) 2,000 730–930
Sources: Aedo and Nuñez (2001); Aedo and
Private benefits Pizarro Valdivia (2004); de Moura Castro (1999);
Impact on employment (percentage point increase) 10 21 Elias and others (2004); Inter-American Develop-
ment Bank (2005); and Santiago Consultores
Impact on earnings (percentage point increase) 10 26 Asociados (1999).

tries as many as a quarter set up their own advantaged youth (box 4.7). Their target-
micro businesses. ing of low-income youths has improved
Employers surveyed by Entra 21 value labor placement and earnings for their
the combination of life skills and techni- beneficiaries across Latin America. Criti-
cal skills developed by the program, rating cal to their success is the nature of the
youths’ life skills as satisfactory to highly sat- training—from technical to life skills and
isfactory in meeting their companies’ needs. from lectures to internships—and the
More than 70 percent of employers said the sound support services and course cer-
graduates’ potential as workers was equal to tifications that foster youth’s continuing
or greater than that of other employees in participation.
similar positions, and more than 90 percent
in four projects rated graduates’ overall per- Skill development should respond to local
formance as better than or equal to that of demand and promote competition among
workers in similar positions. providers. Among the important factors
In Argentina, Chile, Peru, and Uruguay behind the success of the Joven programs
the Joven programs have been widely are that the demand-oriented approach
recognized as successful in reaching dis- fosters private participation—and that
118 WORLD DEVELOPMENT REPORT 2007

Table 4.2 Summary of youth employment policy directions and examples of programs
Proven and successful Promising but unproven Unlikely to be successful
Opportunities
Creating jobs Trade openness: youth-intensive exporting Wage subsidies and private sector incentives, Schemes guaranteeing public sector jobs
sectors (Indonesia and Vietnam) targeted to unskilled and unemployed (Hungary, for the educated (Morocco, Egypt, Sri
Market-oriented reform (Slovenia and Poland, and the Czech Republic) Lanka, and Ethiopia)
Estonia) Wage-setting institutions that compress
General labor market reform (Colombia) wages (overly high minimum wages, Chile
and Brazil)
When minimum wages are too binding,
lowering youth minimum wage (Chile) Overly restrictive employment protection
laws (Chile, Latin American and Caribbean
countries, and OECD countries)
Partial labor market reform (reducing
employment protection for youth only,
or temporary contracts) increases youth
turnover, but segments the market (France
and Spain)
Reducing child Conditional cash transfers for children
labor vulnerable to child labor (PETI in Brazil,
PROGRESA in Mexico, and Human
Development Bond Project (BDH) in Ecuador)
Facilitating Support for rural nonfarm employment Restrictions on rural migrants
mobility (Taiwan, China’s promotion of rural
manufacturing)
Capabilities
Skills Apprenticeship programs: successful New apprenticeship programs (the United Slovenia’s capitalization program (for
development in Germany, unproven in developing Kingdom and Australia offering apprenticeships in entrepreneurs)
countries new service sectors)
Traditional apprenticeship with access to Traditional apprenticeships in the informal sector
new technologies for master craftsmen (mixed evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa)
(Kenya’s Jua Kali program) Jobs Net, Sri Lanka matching agency
Enterprise-based training (Ghana, Kenya, Training vouchers (Malaysia)
and Zimbabwe)
Reforming training institutes to introduce
competition among private and public providers
(Mauritius Industrial Vocational Training Board,
Chile Servicio National de Capacitación y Empleo)
Self-employment Self-employment assistance (Hungary and Poland)
Promotion of entrepreneurship (Endeavor program
in Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Mexico, and Uruguay)
Softex (Brazil) public-private partnership for
entrepreneurs
Chile CORFO and Buenos Aires Emprende 1 and 2
Empowering youth with disabilities (Pakistan’s
Independent Living Centers)
Second chances Bundled programs (comprehensive) Entra 21 programs including training, soft skills,
providing training, placement, mentoring, internship (18 countries in Latin America and the
and the like (U.S. Job Corps, Joven Caribbean)
programs in Argentina, Chile, Peru, and Reintegrating youth with disabilities into the
Uruguay) labor market (Hungary Salva Vita Foundation on
Public works programs (in low-income supported employment and work experience
countries targeted to the low-skilled and program)
unemployed youth) AGETIP (Senegal) public works targeting youth
Proempleo program in Argentina combines Colectivo integral de Desarrollo in Peru
public works and wage subsidies
Public employment services (Korea, the
Philippines, and Thailand)
Going to work 119

competition is promoted among training benefit more than adults. Other interventions
providers. Transferring the Joven model are youth-specific, designed to fit individual
to other developing countries requires country contexts:
strong institutions to manage a decentral-
ized program and to coordinate the goals • In middle-income countries, reform-
ing labor market institutions to better
and operations of training institutions and
accommodate new entrants and pro-
participating companies. It also requires
viding financial incentives for firms to
continual evaluation of the quality of the
hire young workers will broaden youth
courses and internships and the perfor-
opportunities. Building more bridges
mance of training institutions.
between school and work and increas-
ing access to information will enhance
In sum, roadblocks on the way to work have the ability of youth to take advantage of
implications for youth themselves and on these opportunities.
development and poverty reduction efforts. • In low-income countries, building on
Policy makers need to consider strategies to basic skills through better-designed
delay youth from going to work too early, formal and informal apprenticeship
to smooth the entry to the workforce, and will improve relevance to the needs of
to allow movement toward better quality a changing labor market and facilitate
work (table 4.2). In all countries, a bet- youth transition to work. A mix of public
ter investment climate, a well-functioning work programs, wage subsidies, intern-
labor market, and an expanding nonfarm ships, and training provides a spring-
rural sector broaden employment oppor- board to reintegrate the most vulnerable
tunities for everybody, and youth could back into productive employment.
s p o t l i g ht Do baby booms lead to employment busts?
Not in OECD countries

The post–World War II OECD baby boom offers lessons on how to absorb large youth cohorts into the labor market. What
groups are most affected? What policies help youth most? Do bad policy choices cause more damage to youth employment
prospects than large youth populations?

Youth unemployment in OECD unemployment rates in the G-7 countries cation, compounding disadvantages related
countries is due to weak have risen less than 2 percentage points. to discrimination in the labor market. In
demand and bad policy Youth unemployment rates did rise France, where government statistics do
and not the baby boom modestly as the baby boom cohort entered not recognize ethnicity, youth unemploy-
the labor market. However, the unemploy- ment rates in predominantly ethnic urban
One year after the end of World War II
ment rates are affected much more by the enclaves are around 40 percent, nearly twice
and for about 20 years thereafter, the G-7
overall strength of the labor market.1 Youth the already high French average.
countries experienced a surge in the birth
unemployment is extremely sensitive to
rate relative to periods before and since. As
the business cycle: youth benefit greatly High youth unemployment can
a result, an unusually large share of youth
when labor demand is increasing, but suf- cause youth and the country
entered the labor force from the mid-1960s
fer disproportionately when the economy is permanent harm
until the early 1980s, with the peak occur-
in recession or growing slowly. One lesson Does early unemployment cause perma-
ring between 1967 and 1973 (figure 1).
from the Organisation for Economic Co- nent scarring of youth, resulting in employ-
Since then, the youth share of the labor
operation and Development (OECD) coun- ment difficulties later in life? Answers vary.
market has fallen steadily.
tries is that even a modest deterioration in In the United States, most studies find that
One might expect that youth in the
the strength of labor demand, measured spells of unemployment after leaving school
baby boom cohorts would have had much
by the rising unemployment rate for older do not result in persistent unemployment
more difficulty finding work than would
workers in OECD countries, has increased later in life. This corresponds to fairly high
the relatively small youth cohorts entering
the difficulty in the transition from school transition rates from unemployment into
the labor market in the 1990s. The opposite
to work. employment: 46 percent of unemployed
is true, however: average youth unemploy-
ment rates across the G-7 countries are 7 youth are employed one month later.
The less educated and minority Corresponding transition rates in
percentage points higher than during the
peak of the baby boom. In contrast, adult
youth have the greatest problems France, Germany, and the United Kingdom
with unemployment are much lower, ranging from 4 to 14 per-
Are youth receiving too much education so cent, and more evidence indicates that early
Figure 1 Youth unemployment rates for the
that they become overqualified for the jobs unemployment results in persistent unem-
G-7 countries are higher now than during the
baby boom that are available? No. Evidence suggests ployment. One-third of the unemployed
that the least educated face the greatest mis- in France have been unemployed more
Unemployment rate Labor force match between skills and job vacancies. In than a year, compared with 8.5 percent in
(percent) ratio (percent) almost every industrial economy, average the United States. The persistent adverse
25 30
unemployment rates fall as years of school- effects of early unemployment on later
20 27
ing increase. employment stability can last seven years
Nor does job training tend to reduce in France, compared with two in the United
15 24 the disadvantage faced by the less educated. States.2 The degree of persistence appears
The gap in access to jobs continues as the to respond to business cycles, with less per-
10 21 cohorts age because the most educated get manent damage from early unemployment
the most job training. College graduates in economies experiencing job growth. In
5 18 in OECD countries are seven times more addition, the scarring effect of early unem-
likely to receive training than are high ployment tends to be greatest for the least
0 15
school dropouts. Similarly dramatic gaps in educated and for disadvantaged youth. 3
60
64
68
72
76
80
84
88
92
96
00
04
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
20
20

access to training exist between the highest Weak youth labor markets tend to delay
Unemployment rate: ages 15–19 (left axis) and lowest literacy groups. other transitions. In Europe, the average age
Unemployment rate: ages 20–24 (left axis) Unemployment rates are uniformly at which youth leave the home has increased,
Ratio of population ages 15–24 to
population ages 25–64 (right axis) higher for minority youth in OECD coun- especially in southern European countries.
tries. Such groups are atypically disadvan- In Italy, 80 percent of males ages 18–30 still
Source: Authors’ compilations based on data provided by taged by recessions and by policies that live with their parents, compared with 25
OECD Database on Labour Force Statistics.
Note: Shaded portion of the figure indicates peak baby
tend to limit new job creation. They are also percent in the United States. Across OECD
boom entry years. atypically disadvantaged in completing edu- countries, the average age of marriage has
Do baby booms lead to employment busts? 121

increased while the average number of chil- Figure 2 Employment protection hurt OECD ment protection, which protects their jobs
dren per household has fallen. youth, but not adults, in 2003 at the expense of youth and other outsid-
Weakening youth labor markets have ers. Perhaps that is why all but a few coun-
Unemployment rate (percent)
at least a partial role in explaining these 25
tries have found it so difficult to relax the
changes in life transitions. Youth tend to employment protection, even when their
delay leaving their parents’ homes dur- 20 youth unemployment rates are so high.
ing recessions. Differences in the relative
strength of country youth labor markets can 15 Efforts to fix the youth labor
explain observed differences across coun- market have mixed success
tries in the average age of home leaving.4 In 10 Youth
OECD countries have used various poli-
Germany and Spain, the likelihood of leav- cies to try to fix youth unemployment.
5
ing home increases significantly with youth Adults One option that appears unsuccessful is to
employment status and labor earnings.5 0 try to “make room” for youth employment
When youth face constraints in access 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4
by encouraging older workers to retire.
to legal employment, they may engage in OECD employment protection legislation
(EPL) index
The limited evidence suggests that older
illegal activities. Studies in the United States and younger workers may be complements
and the United Kingdom show that weak- Source: Authors’ compilations based on information pre- and not substitutes in production. Coun-
ening wages for low-skilled youth are cor- sented in OECD (2004).
Note: In the figure, youth are those ages 15–24; adults are tries with higher retirement ages for men
related with increases in criminal activity.6 those ages 25–54. Correlation with EPL index is 0.32 for and women have higher employment rates
Less consistent evidence links long-term youth and 0.27 for adults. Each data point in the graph rep-
resents one country. for male and female youth.11 Similarly,
youth unemployment with crime, although efforts in France to limit hours of work
discontent with high rates of youth unem- to force firms to hire additional workers
ployment in minority communities has younger workers (figure 2). In eras of both appear not to have resulted in appreciable
been cited as a contributing factor to unrest. large and small youth cohorts, stricter EPL job growth.
One recent study in France shows that cit- is correlated with higher youth unemploy- The average OECD country spends
ies with higher youth unemployment have ment rates. around 2 percent of GDP on active labor
higher rates of burglaries, thefts, and drug Similar findings hold for legislation market policies, with training being the
offenses.7 that diminishes wage flexibility, such as largest component of those expenditures.
high minimum wages or extending union- Public expenditures are only about one-
Efforts to protect job security do negotiated wages to nonunion workers. tenth of the total, however, and private
not help and may hinder youth Such policies reduce wage inequality across training is weighted heavily toward the
The youth unemployment problem appears workers, but risk making it too expensive to most educated. Private training is unlikely
to be exacerbated by policies aimed at pre- hire those lacking schooling or prior labor to offer a significant second-chance option
serving jobs. Many countries have enacted market experience. for those who failed to attain a sufficient
Employment Protection Legislation (EPL) Many of the countries with the stron- level of prior education. Publicly subsidized
that makes it more difficult or costly for gest youth labor market outcomes over training tends to have the greatest success
firms to lay off workers. These policies are the past 15 years (Ireland, the Nether- with more-educated recipients.
designed to insure workers against income lands, New Zealand, the United Kingdom, The experience of youth training pro-
loss from fluctuations in labor demand. the United States) have tended to be those grams in Europe suggests that they have
However, such legislation also makes it with rising wage inequality. The implica- improved the transition to employment
more costly for firms to hire workers, thus tion is that wage flexibility has helped these but that the impact on earnings is more
stricter EPL tends to depress the rate of new economies to adjust to shocks and to cre- mixed.12
job creation.8 ate new job opportunities for youth, but at Of other active labor market policies,
These adverse consequences of EPL a cost of increased income disparities in the job search assistance and wage subsidies
are borne mostly by groups that are dis- population.10 appear to be the most promising for raising
proportionately first-time job seekers, so Countries with stronger EPL have expe- employment rates of disadvantaged youth,
youth tend to be atypically disadvantaged.9 rienced growth in temporary and fixed- but public employment programs have not
Because EPL appears to retard new job cre- term jobs that are frequently exempt from worked. Evidence also suggests that youth
ation, it can also heighten the persistent firing restrictions. This allows new job are more successful in transitioning to
effects of early unemployment on employ- growth, but it creates dual labor markets employment in countries where unemploy-
ment prospects later in life. with protected jobs held predominantly by ment benefits are conditioned on active job
Stricter employment protection legisla- “insiders” (older male workers) and tem- search and willingness to accept jobs when
tion does not appear to create unemploy- porary jobs held by “outsiders” (women, offered.13
ment problems for older workers and may minorities, and youth). Insiders have an
even insulate them from competition with incentive to maintain and expand employ-

Вам также может понравиться