Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 23

Patterns, Trends and Predictions

in stock market indices


and foreign currency exchange rates

Marcel Ausloos1 and Kristinka Ivanova2


arXiv:cond-mat/0108013 v1 1 Aug 2001

1
SUPRAS & GRASP, B5, University of Liège, B-4000 Liège, Belgium
2
Pennsylvania State University, University Park PA 16802, USA

Summary. Specialized topics on financial data analysis from a numerical and


physical point of view are discussed. They pertain to the analysis of crash pre-
diction in stock market indices and to the persistence or not of coherent and ran-
dom sequences in fluctuations of foreign exchange currency rates. A brief historical
introduction to crashes is given, including recent observations on the DJIA and
the S&P500. Daily data of the DAX index are specifically used for illustration. The
method for visualizing the pattern thought to be the precursor signature of financial
crashes is outlined. The log-periodicity of the pattern is investigated. Comparison
of patterns before and after crash days is made through the power spectrum. The
corresponding fractal dimension of the signal looks like that of a percolation back-
bone. Next the fluctuations of exchange rates (XR) of currencies forming EU R
with respect to U SD are analyzed. The XR power spectra are calculated before
and after crashes. A detrended fluctuation analysis is performed. The characteris-
tic exponents β and α respectively, are compared, including the time dependence
of each α, found to be singular near crash dates.

1 An Introduction with Some Historical Notes as


”Symptoms”
The stock market crash on Monday Oct. 19, 1987 led to the October black
monday syndrome. On that day, the Dow Jones Industrial Average (DJIA)
lost 21.6 %. Other markets were shaken : the worst decline reached 45.8 % in
Hong Kong. The downturn was spread out over two or three days in different
European stock markets: the DAX lost 10 %. Nevertheless most markets
had been using for a long time breakers, i.e. periods of trading halts and/or
limitations of daily variations. This tends to suggest that the adoption of
circuit breakers at the very least do delay the crash process, and not much
more. In fact, Lauterbach and Ben-Zion [1] found that trading halts and
price limits had no impact on the overall decline of October 1987, but merely
smoothed return fluctuations in the neighborhood of the crash.
Another major characteristic of the crash of October 1987 is the phe-
nomenon of irresistible contagion. It is well accepted that the shock arose
first from Asian markets, except Japan, then propagated to the European
markets before reaching the American markets after, when Asian markets
2 M. Ausloos and K. Ivanova

were already closed [2]. A mapping of the Nikkei, DAX and DJIA daily sign
fluctuations has been made onto a 1/2 Ising spin chain as if there was a
continuous index calculated three times during 24 hours. This showed that
the spin cluster fluctuations are rather equivalent to random fluctuations, -
except during pre-crash periods in which (down − down − down) spin clus-
ters form with a higher probability than expected if the fluctuations are to
be considered independent of each other [3]. This has allowed to eliminate
all criticisms about the major responsibility of the derivative markets in the
United States on the Oct. 87 crash. Since then, the world-wide interdepen-
dence of the economy has been going on still more strongly. Thus if really
a speculative bubble is occurring on some financial markets, as commonly
observed in the recent years, the phenomenon of propagation to other stock
exchanges could be more important now. It is known that methods of negoti-
ation have widely changed on many financial places. Markets using electronic
systems of negotiation take advantage of recent improvement in their trans-
action capacity. It is easier today to face a substantial increase in transaction
volumes during a major crisis period. Moreover, the efficient use of the deriva-
tive markets could avoid useless pressures on the traditional market. These
financial factual observations should be turned into quantitative measures,
in order to, if necessary, avoid crashes.
Whence there is a need for techniques capable of rapidly following a bub-
ble explosion or preventing it. Notice that the drop of stock market indices
can not only spread out over two or three days but also over a much longer
period. The example of the Tokyo stock exchange at the beginning of the
1990’s is a prominent illustration. By comparison to the most famous crash
of 1929, the Oct. 87 crash was spread over 2 days: the Dow Jones sank 12.8 %
on October 28 and 11.7 % on the following day. (That was similar for the
DAX which dropped by 8.00 % and 7.00 % on Oct. 26 and 28, 1987 respec-
tively.) This shows that a stock market index decline does not necessarily
lead to a crash in one single day. Indeed, the decline can be slow and last
several days or even several months in what would be called not a crash, but
a long duration bear market.
In the present econophysics research context, it is of interest to examine
whether the evolution of quotations on the main stock exchange places have
similarities and whether crash symptoms can be found. Even if history gen-
erally tends to repeat, does it always do so in similar ways, and what are the
differences? A rise in quotations can be interpreted a posteriori as the result
of a speculative bubble but could be mere euphoria. How this does lead to
a rupture of the trend? Can the duration differences be interpreted? Can we
find universality classes?
Physics-like model of fracture or other phase transitions, including perco-
lation can be turned into some economic advantage. Along the same lines of
thought, the question was already touched upon in [4] within the sand pile
model. This allows not only a verbal analogy of index rupture in terms of
Patterns, Trends and Predictions in stock market 3

sand avalanches, but also some insight into the mechanisms. Through phys-
ical modeling and an understanding of parameters controlling the output,
as in the sand pile model, symptoms can be measured, whence to suggest
remedies is not impossible.
Another question raised below is the post-crash period. One might expect
from a physics point of view that if a crash looks like a phase transition, and
is characterized by scaling laws, as we will see it sometimes occurs [5,6], it
might be expected that a relation exists between amplitudes and laws on
both sides of the crash day [7]. As mentioned above, the crash might be
occurring on various days, with different breaks. It might be possible that
between drops some positive surge might be found. Thus some sorting of
behaviors into classes should be made as well. In fine, some discussion on
the foreign exchange market will be given in order to recall the detrended
fluctuation analysis method, so often used nowadays. It is applied below to
the U SD exchange rate vs. the (ten) currencies forming the EU R on Jan. 01,
2000, over a time interval including the most recent years. The observation
of the time variation of the power law scaling exponent of the DFA function
is shown to be correlated to crash time occurrence.

1.1 Tulipomania
In 1559, the first tulip bulb (TB) was brought to Holland from China by
Conrad Guenster [8]. In 1611, the tulip bulbs (TBs) were stocked and sold
on markets. In 1625, one tulip bulb was worth 5 dutch gulden (NLG). The
flower was considered so rare that wealthy aristocrats and merchants tripped
over themselves to buy the onions. Speculation ensued and the TBs became
wildly overvalued. The TBs were not necessarily planted, but were just stored
in the house salon. In 1635, 1 TB was worth 4 tons of wheat + 4 oxen + 8
tons rye + 8 pigs + one bed + 12 sheep + clothes + 2 wine casks + 4 tons
beer + 2 tons butter + 1000 pounds cheese + 1 silver drinking cup. In 1637, 1
TB was worth 550 NLG. One average house was worth 17 800 NLG, whence
about 30 TBs. However within 1637, over a 6 week time span the price of 1
TB went down 90 %.
In view of the shock, remedies had to be found and people called upon the
Amsterdam Parliament for legislation. It was decided that all contracts would
be void if they were dealt before Nov. 1636, and after that date the contracts
kept a 10 % value. Under some protest, people appealed to the Netherland
Supreme Court which ruled that this business of selling/buying TBs was mere
gambling, and no debt could be defined ”by law” nor ruled upon. Nowadays
one TB is worth 0.5 EUR. Too bad for long term investment strategies. The
TB became the classical example for illustrating the Extraordinary Popular
Delusions and the Madness of Crowds as described by Charles MacKay [9].
Just for the sake of physics history, let it be recalled that 1639 was the year
in which Galileo Galilei (Pisa, Feb. 15, 1564; Arcetri, Jan. 8, 1642) betrayed
science in saving his life.
4 M. Ausloos and K. Ivanova

1.2 Monopolymania
Another set of financial crises is that of the Compagnie du Mississipi [10] and
that of the South Sea Company [11,12]. In 1715, John Law, a scot gambler,
had persuaded Philippe, Regent of France, to consider a banking scheme
that promised to improve the financial condition of the kingdom. In theory a
private affair, the system was linked from the beginning with liquidating the
national debt. When the monopoly of the Louisiana trade was surrendered in
1717, Law created a trading company known as the Compagnie d’Occident (or
Compagnie du Mississipi) linked to the Royal Bank of France (first chartered
in 1716 as Banque Générale) and in which government bills were accepted
for the purchase of shares.
Law gained a monopoly on all French overseas trade. The result was a
huge wave of speculation as the value of a share went from its initial value,
i.e. 500 livres to 18 000 livres. When the paper money was presented at the
bank in exchange for gold, which was unavailable, panic ensued, and shares
felt by a factor of 2 in a matter of days.
In England, the Whigs represented the mercantile interests which had
profited from the War of the Spanish Succession War (1703-1711), and made
large profits by financing it, in doing so had created a National Debt which
had to be financed by further taxation. During the wars the government han-
dled more money than ever before in history, and they skimmed off a lot
through various methods, including the invention of the Bank of England in
1694. The South Sea Company was formed in 1711 by the Tory government
of Harley to trade with Spanish America, and to offset the financial support
which the Bank of England had provided for previous Whig governments.
They had in mind to establish a system like the Compagnie du Mississipi
Monopoly, [10] using the same sort of trading privileges and monopolies, those
granted to Britain after the Treaty of Utrecht. King George I of Great Britain
became governor of the company in 1718, creating confidence in the enter-
prise, which was soon paying 100 percent interest. In 1720 a bill was passed
enabling persons to whom the government owed portions of the national debt
to exchange their claims for shares in company stocks, and to become stock
holders. In the 1719-20 the England Public Debt went to South Sea Com-
pany stock holders, as approved by Parliament. On March 1 the stocks were
valued GBP 175, moved quickly to 200. Shortly the directors of the South
Sea Company had assumed three-fifths of the national debt. The company
expected to recoup itself from expanding trade, but chiefly from the foreseen
rise in the value of its shares. On June 1 the shares were valued 500 and
more than 1,000 in August 1720. Those unable to buy South Sea Company
stocks were inveigled by overly optimistic company promoters or downright
swindlers into unwise investments. Speculators took advantage of investors
to obtain subscriptions for sensibly unrealistic projects. By September 1720
however, the market had collapsed, and by December 1720 South Sea Com-
pany shares were down to 124, dragging others, including government stocks
Patterns, Trends and Predictions in stock market 5

with them. Many investors were ruined, and the House of Commons ordered
an inquiry, which showed that ministers had accepted bribes and speculated.
From a physics point of view let it be recalled that I. Newton (Woolsthorpe,
Dec. 25, 1642; London, March 20, 1727) invested in such South Sea Company
stocks and lost quite a bit of money [13].

1.3 WallStreetmania
In the years from 1925 to 1929 one could easily go to a broker and purchase
stocks on margin, i.e. instead of buying stocks with real cash money, one could
purchase them with some cash down and the rest on credit. The Coolidge
administration had a laissez-faire policy, i.e. a government policy of non-
intervention. It was almost la façon de vivre to play in the stock market [14].
That allowed a speculation bubble to grow unchecked. The Federal Reserve
powers on economic matters were not utilized as could be done nowadays.
Many successions of mini crashes and rallies began as early as March 1929.
The summer of 1929 hearkened somewhat of the good old days of optimism.
The market appeared to be stable. On Sept. 3, a bear market became firmly
established, and on Thursday Oct. 24, 1929 the famous 1929 crash occurred
(Fig. 1).

Fig. 1. Famous Wall Street Crashes : 1929, 1987, 1997; taken from color web site
http://www.lowrisk.com/crash/87vs97.htm; from top to bottom on day 201 : blue
(97), red (29), black (87); on day 700 : red (29), black(87), blue(97)

The 1987, 1997, and more recent 1999, 2000, 2001 crashes are reminis-
cent and even copies of the above ones (Fig. 1). The symptoms look similar :
artificially built euphoria, malingnantly established speculation, easy access
6 M. Ausloos and K. Ivanova

to market activities, including manipulated (or rather electronipulated) in-


formations ... Consider the buying frenzy on IPOs stocks at the end of the
1990’s in companies for which owners do not have a coherent business plan,
or are not going to make money, ... and yet see how we bought e-stocks.
Nothing has changed since 1600, 1700 nor 1929.

2 Econophysics of Stock Market Indices


Econophysics [15,16] aims to fill the huge gap separating ”empirical finance”
and ”econometric theories”. Various subjects have been approached like the
option pricing, stock market data analysis, market modelling and forecasting,
etc...The application of statistical physics ideas to the forecasting of stock
market behavior has been proposed earlier following the pioneer work of
physicists interested by economy laws [17,18,19,20,21,22,23].
Even though a stock market crash is considered as a highly unpredictable
event, it should be reemphasized that it takes place systematically during a
period of generalized anxiety spreading over the markets following a euphoria
time. The crash can be seen as a natural correction bringing the market to a
”normal state”. Three important facts should be underlined:
(i) The series of daily fluctuations, so called volatility, of the stock market
presents a huge clustering around the crash date, i.e. huge fluctuations are
grouped around the crash date. This is well illustrated in Fig. 2 for the case
of the DAX around 1987. The time span of this clustering is quite long: a few
years. This clustering indicates that larger and larger fluctuations take place
before crashes.
(ii) Collective effects are to be considered, be they stemming from macroe-
conomy informations, as a set of ”external fields”, and leading to a bear mar-
ket, or more intrinsically self − organized, as if microeconomic informations
(or interactions?) were triggering the non-equilibrium state evolution.
(iii) A third remark concerns the panic–correlations appearing before
crashes. This kind of collective behavior is commonly observed during a trad-
ing day. The market in Tokyo closes before London opens and thereafter New
York opens. During periods of panic, financial analysts are looking for the
results and evolution of the geographically preceding market. Strong correla-
tions are found in fluctuations of different market indices before crashes.
Of course, fluctuations and correlations are both ingredients which are
supposedly known to play an important role in phase transitions. Thus an
analogy can be derived (Fig.3) between phase transitions and crashes, defin-
ing the mean field (exponential-like) behavior, the time t∗ , corresponding to
the Ginzburg − Levanyuk temperature bounding the critical fluctuation re-
gion, the critical crash day tc , etc. [6]. The character of a thermodynamic
phase transition is characterized by critical exponents, following the scaling
law hypothesis, exponents which are thought to depend on the symmetry of
Patterns, Trends and Predictions in stock market 7

150

clustering
100

50
DAX volatility

−50

−100

−150
1985 1986 1987 1988 1989
date
Fig. 2. DAX volatility between Jan. 01, 85 and Dec. 31, 88

8000

7000

6000

5000
t*
DAX

4000
t
c
3000 t*
2000

1000 t
c

0
1980 1984 1988 1992 1996
date
Fig. 3. DAX evolution between Jan.01, 1980 and Dec.31, 1998 with the mean field
behavior, the time(s) t∗ , corresponding to the Ginzburg − Levanyuk temperature
bounding the critical fluctuation region, and the critical crash day(s) tc
8 M. Ausloos and K. Ivanova

the order parameter and the underlying lattice dimensionality[24]. Similar


considerations are looked for in financial crash studies.
In 1996, two independent works [25,26] have proposed that critical phe-
nomena would be possible scenarios for describing crashes. Those authors
are still debating about the subject [27,28]. More precisely, it has been pro-
posed that an economic index y(t) increases as a power law decorated with
a log-periodic oscillation, i.e.
 −m     
tc − t tc − t
y = A+B 1 + Csin ω ln +φ for t < tc (1)
tc tc
where tc is the crash-time or rupture point, A, B, m, C, ω and φ are free
parameters. This evolution y(t) is in fact the real part < of a power law
behavior at t = tc with a complex exponent m + iω, i.e.
( −m+iω )
tc − t
y∼< (2)
tc

The law for y(t) diverges at t = tc if m > 0. This evolution is decorated with
oscillations converging at the rupture point tc . This law is similar to that of
critical points, and generalizes the situation for cases in which a hierarchical
lattice structure exists, in other words a Discrete Scale Invariance (DSI) is
subjacent [29].
The relationship (1) has been proposed elsewhere in order to fit experi-
mental measurements of sound wave rate emissions prior to the rupture of
heterogeneous composite stressed up to failure [30]. The same type of com-
plex power law behavior has been also observed as a precursor of the Kobe
earthquake in Japan [31]. Such log-periodic corrections have been recently
reported in biased diffusion on random lattices [32].
As early as April 1997, Vandewalle and Ausloos performed a series of
investigations in order to emphasize crash precursors [33,34,35]. The closing
values of the Dow Jones Industrial Average (DJIA) and the Standard & Poor
500 (S&P500) were used for tests. A law slightly different from Eq.(1) was
proposed [33,36]. A strong indication of a so-called crash event or market
rupture point was numerically discovered [33,34,35,36]. Further data analysis
(in Aug. 97) [37] including a risk measure [38] indicated a crash to occur
in between the end of October 1997 and mid-November 1997. The crash
occurred effectively on Monday October 27th, 1997 [36] !
Eventhough the crash of October 1997 was predicted [36,37], the scientific
(physics or economy) [39,40] and media [35] community is actually divided
between those who believe in such a crash prediction and those who believe
that crashes are unpredictable events and such findings were mere luck or
at best accidental [27,28,41]. We discuss a little bit more the predictability
problem and findings in this paper going beyond a previous report [4].
Patterns, Trends and Predictions in stock market 9

2.1 Methodology and data analysis


In e.g. Refs.[4,42,43,44], the fact was underlined that there are strong physical
arguments stipulating that m in Eq. (1) could be or even should be taken
as ”universal”. The universal m = 0 value, i.e. a logarithmic divergence has
been proposed. The logarithmic divergence of the index y for t close to tc
reads
     
tc − t tc − t
y = A + B ln 1 + Csin ω ln +φ for t < tc .(3)
tc tc
One should remark that the full period [ti, tf ] for a meaningful fit should
contain the whole euphoric precursor. It has been found in [4,36,43,44] that
the log-divergence is closer to the real signal than any power law divergence
with m 6= 0.
The log-divergence in Eq.(3) contains 6 parameters. At first, it seems that
non-linear fits using only the simple log-divergent function
y = A + B ln (tc − t) (4)
with B < 0, thus with only 3 parameters can be performed. A good estimation
of tc can be obtained indeed following both Levenberg-Marquardt and Monte-
Carlo algorithms [45]. One has observed that the estimated tc points are close
to ”black” days for the first two periods [4,43,44].
Assuming that Eq.(4) is valid, one should also note that
dy −B
= (5)
dt (tc − t)
should be found in the daily fluctuation pattern (Fig. 2). This is consistent
with the volatility clustering discussed here above. However, Eq.(5) fits lead
to bad results with huge error bars.
The oscillating term of Eq.(3) has been quite criticized since no traditional
or economical argument supports the DSI theory at this time. However, the
hierarchical structure of the market has been suggested as a possible candi-
date for generating DSI patterns in [4,26,46,47],so is the price fixing ”tech-
niques” [48] and arbitrage methods. In order to prove that a log-periodic
pattern appears before crashes, the envelope of the index y is constructed
[42]. Two distinct curves are built: the upper envelope ymax and the lower
one ymin . The former represents the maximum of y in an interval [ti , t] and
the latter is the minimum of y in an interval [t, tf ]. One observes a remarkable
pattern made of a succession of thin and huge peaks [42].
When ymax − ymin = 0, it means that the index y reaches some value
never reached before at a time t and would never have reached if the time
axis had been reversed thereafter. This corresponds to time intervals during
which the value of the index y reaches new records. In fact, the pattern reflects
obviously an oscillatory precursor of the crash, thus through
ymax − ymin = (C1 + C2t)(1 − cos (ω ln (tc − t) + φ)) (6)
10 M. Ausloos and K. Ivanova

where C1 and C2 are parameters controlling the amplitude of the oscillations.


The above relationship allows us to measure the log-frequency ω [42]. More-
over it is found that the value of ω seems to be finite and almost constant,
ω ' [6, 10] for the major analyzed crashes. An analysis along similar lines of
thought, though emphasizing the no-divergence, thus m < 0 in Eqs. (1)-(2),
was discussed for the Nikkei [49,50] and NASDAQ April 2000 crash [51].
For illustrating the complexity of the frequency dependence of such fi-
nancial signals, one can also perform a Fourier transform of a reconstructed
signal. The evolution of the six strongest DAX crashes between Oct. 01, 1959
and Dec. 31, 1988 and the strongest DAX crashes in 1997, prior to the crash
day, are shown in Fig. 4; y0 denotes the index value at the closing of the crash
day. Power spectra of the DAX index measured from the index value at the
end of the crash day have been calculated for a time interval equal to 600
days, those prior to crashes. The 6 large DAX crash spectra for the period of
interest are shown in Fig. 5. The corresponding exponents β for the best fit
in the high frequency region are given in Table 1.

1
Oct 16, 89
Oct 19, 87
Aug 19, 91
Oct 26, 87
May 29, 62
Oct 28, 87
0.5
Oct 28, 97
y(i)/y(0) −1

−0.5

−1000 −100 −10 0


Time before the crash (days)
Fig. 4. The evolution of the six strongest DAX crashes between Oct. 01, 59 and
Dec. 31, 88, and the strongest DAX crash in 1997, prior to the crash day ; y0 denotes
the index value at the closing of the crash day
Patterns, Trends and Predictions in stock market 11

12 12
10 10
(a) Oct. 16, 89 (b) Oct. 19, 87
10 10
10 10

8 8
10 10
S(f)

S(f)
6 6
10 10

4 4
10 10

2 2
10 10

0 0
10 −3 −2 −1 0
10 −3 −2 −1 0
10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10
−1
f (days ) f (days−1)

12 12
10 10
(c) Aug. 19, 91 (d) Oct. 26, 87
10 10
10 10

8 8
10 10
S(f)

S(f)
6 6
10 10

4 4
10 10

2 2
10 10

0 0
10 −3 −2 −1 0
10 −3 −2 −1 0
10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10
−1 −1
f (days ) f (days )

12 12
10 10
(e) May 29, 62 (f) Oct. 28, 87
10 10
10 10

8 8
10 10
S(f)

S(f)

6 6
10 10

4 4
10 10

2 2
10 10

0 0
10 −3 −2 −1 0
10 −3 −2 −1 0
10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10
f (days−1) f (days−1)

Fig. 5. The power spectrum of the 600 day DAX index evolution signal correspond-
ing to the six major crashes between Oct. 01, 59 and Dec. 31, 96

The roughness behavior [52,53,54] of the DAX index evolution signal be-
fore crashes can be defined trough the fractal dimension D of the signal, i.e.
[52]
3−β
D=E+ , (7)
2
where E is the Euclidian dimension. The values of β and D are reported in
Table 1 with the crash dates and relative amplitude of the 6 major DAX
crashes which occurred between Oct. 01, 1959 and Dec. 30, 1996. The same
12 M. Ausloos and K. Ivanova

type of data is reported in Table 2 for the 3 major DAX crashes in October
1997. The power spectrum of the large Oct. 28, 97 crash is shown in Fig. 6.

12
10
Oct. 28, 97
10
10

8
10
S(f)

6
10

4
10

2
10

0
10 −3 −2 −1 0
10 10 10 10
−1
f (days )
Fig. 6. The power spectrum of the 600 day DAX index evolution signal prior to
the Oct. 28, 97 crash

Table 1. Crash dates and relative amplitude of the 6 major DAX crashes having
occurred between Oct. 01, 1959 and Dec. 30, 1998; power law exponent β− of the
signal power spectrum (600 data points) and corresponding fractal dimension D−
of the signal prior to, and β+ and D+ , after these 6 major DAX crashes.

crash dates relative amplitude β− D− β+ D+


16.10.89 -0.137 1.90±0.09 1.55 1.67±0.09 1.67
19.10.87 -0.099 2.24±0.09 1.38 1.82±0.09 1.59
19.08.91 -0.099 1.82±0.10 1.59 1.62±0.06 1.69
26.10.87 -0.080 2.00±0.09 1.50 1.70±0.08 1.65
29.05.62 -0.075 1.77±0.08 1.62 1.28±0.08 1.86
28.10.87 -0.070 1.94±0.10 1.53 1.81±0.07 1.60
Patterns, Trends and Predictions in stock market 13

Table 2. The 3 major DAX crashes in October 1997 : crash dates, relative ampli-
tude, power law exponent β− of the signal power spectrum (600 data points prior
to these 3 major DAX crash dates) and the corresponding fractal dimension D− .

crash dates relative amplitude β− D−


28.10.97 -0.084 2.14±0.07 1.43
27.10.97 -0.043 1.97±0.07 1.52
23.10.97 -0.048 1.91±0.05 1.55

2.2 Aftershock patterns


The index evolution after a crash has also been analyzed through a recon-
structed signal that is the difference between the DAX value signal at each
day y(i) and the DAX value at the crash day y0 . For the 6 largest crashes in
the time interval of interest the recovery can be slow (Fig.7). It took about
one month for the Oct. 28, 97 crash. To observe some periodic fluctuation
after the crash, the power spectrum of the DAX has been computed for the
600 days following a crash day (Fig. 8 (a-f)). Note the high-frequency log-
periodic oscillation regime of the power spectrum for the Oct. 19, 1987 case
on Fig. 7(d). The values of each β and corresponding fractal dimension D
are reported in Table 1.
As a final point of this section, it should be noticed that the fractal di-
mension is close to 1.70, thus very similar to that of a percolation backbone.
This might be the hint that hierarchical structures are present, and a cause
of crashes. As a consequence, the market could be viewed as a discrete fractal
system, transiting at crashes like a physical system at a percolation transi-
tion.. In related work, Amaral and coworkers [55] have studied the statistics
of several companies as well as their respective growth. They have found that
the growth of companies can be modelled using a hierarchical lattice like a
Cayley tree. For simple models of hierarchically organized markets some self-
regulation is found in fact [56]. On such systems the fractal dimension can
be considered to have an imaginary part which is related to the log-periodic
oscillations, - in fact is the signature of the branching ratio [57].
In conclusion of this section, we may conjecture that stock markets are
also hierarchical objects where each level may have a different weight, con-
nectivity, and characteristics time scale (the horizons of the inve stors) [4].
The hierarchical tree might be fractal at crashes and its geometry might con-
trol the type of criticality. This gives some argument in favor of the sand pile
model on a fractal basis [58] as a microscopic model actually able to simulate
a crash [4].
14 M. Ausloos and K. Ivanova

1
Oct 16, 89
Oct 19, 87
Aug 19, 91
Oct 26, 87
May 29, 62
Oct 28, 87
0.5
Oct 28, 97
y(i)/y(0) −1

−0.5

0 1 2 3
10 10 10 10
Time after the crash (days)
Fig. 7. The DAX recovery signal evolution after the six strongest DAX crashes
having occured between Jan. 01, 85 and Dec. 31, 88, and after the strongest DAX
crash in 1997 ; y0 denotes the index value at the closing of the crash day

3 Foreign Currency Exchange Rates


Beside the crash cases discussed here above numerous examples of scale in-
variance seem to be widespread in natural and social systems [53,59]. A funda-
mental problem is the existence and width of the scaling range for long-range
power-law correlations (LRPLC) in economic systems, as well as the presence
of economic cycles. Indeed, traditional methods (like spectral methods) have
corroborated the evidence that the Brownian motion idea or ordinary random
walk is quite away from reality and LRPLC quite frequent [18,20,22,23]. Dif-
ferent approaches [54] have been envisaged to measure the LRPLC or analyze
them in financial data: tails of partial distribution functions of the volatility,
wavelet analysis, Detrended Fluctuation Analysis (DFA) [60], etc.

3.1 DFA analysis

The DFA method [60] consists in dividing the whole data sequence y(n) of
length N into N/τ non overlapping boxes, each containing τ points. Then,
the local trend
z(n) = an + b (8)
Patterns, Trends and Predictions in stock market 15

12 12
10 10
(a) Oct. 16, 89 (b) Oct. 19, 87
10 10
10 10

8 8
10 10
S(f)

S(f)
6 6
10 10

4 4
10 10

2 2
10 10

0 0
10 −3 −2 −1 0
10 −3 −2 −1 0
10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10
−1
f (days ) f (days−1)

12 12
10 10
(c) Aug. 19, 91 (d) Oct. 26, 87
10 10
10 10

8 8
10 10
S(f)

S(f)
6 6
10 10

4 4
10 10

2 2
10 10

0 0
10 −3 −2 −1 0
10 −3 −2 −1 0
10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10
−1 −1
f (days ) f (days )

12 12
10 10
(e) May 29, 62 (f) Oct. 28, 87
10 10
10 10

8 8
10 10
S(f)

S(f)

6 6
10 10

4 4
10 10

2 2
10 10

0 0
10 −3 −2 −1 0
10 −3 −2 −1 0
10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10
f (days−1) f (days−1)

Fig. 8. The power spectrum of the 600 day DAX index evolution signal after the
six major crashes having occured between Oct. 01, 59 and Dec. 31, 96

in each box is defined to be the ordinate of a linear least-square fit of the


data points in that box. One should remark that a trend z(n) different from
a first-degree polynomial can also be used like the cubic trend [61]. Other
detrending functions may improve the accuracy of the DFA technique, sort
out the reason for crossovers between scaling regimes, and pin point noise
and intrinsic trends [62].
16 M. Ausloos and K. Ivanova

The so-defined detrended fluctuation function F (τ ) is then calculated


following
(k+1)τ  
2 1 X 2 N
F (τ ) = |y(n) − z(n)| , k = 0, 1, 2, · · ·, −1 (9)
τ τ
n=kt+1

Averaging F (τ ) over the N/τ intervals gives a function depending on the box
size τ . The above calculation is repeated for different box sizes τ . If the y(n)
data are randomly uncorrelated variables or short range correlated variables,
the behavior is expected to be a power law
hF (τ )2i1/2 ∼ τ α (10)
with an exponent 1/2 [60] if the excursion is governed by a mere random walk.
An exponent α 6= 1/2 in a certain range of τ values implies the existence of
LRPLC in that time interval. Mathematically, the correlation of a future
increment y(n) − y(0) with a past increment y(0) − y(−n) is given by
h(y(0) − y(−n))(y(n) − y(0))i
Γ (n) = = 22α−1 − 1, (11)
h(y(n) − y(0))2 i
where the correlations are normalized by the variance of y(n). For α > 1/2,
there is persistence, i.e. Γ > 0. In this case, if in the immediate past the signal
has a positive increment, then on the average an increase of the signal in the
immediate future is expected. In other words, persistent stochastic processes
exhibit rather clear trends with relatively little noise. An exponent α < 1/2
means antipersistence, i.e. Γ < 0. In this case, an increasing value in the
immediate past implies a decreasing signal in the immediate future, while
a decreasing signal in the immediate past makes an increasing signal in the
future probable. In so doing, data records with α < 1/2 appear very noisy
(rough). The α = 0 situation corresponds to the so-called white noise. Finally,
one should note that α is nothing else than Ha, the so-called Hausdorff
exponent for fractional Brownian motions [53,54]. It can be useful to recall
[54] that the power spectrum of such random signals is characterized by a
power law with an exponent β = 2α − 1.

3.2 Data and analysis


We have considered the daily evolution of several currency exchange rates
with respect to the U SD from January 1990 till December 1999 including
only all open banking days. This represents about N = 3000 data points. The
data are those obtained from [63], at the closing time of the foreign exchange
market in London for the ten currencies Ci, (i=1,10) forming the EU R on
Jan. 01, 1999.
The evolution of such Ci/U SD exchange rate from Jan. 01, 1993 to June
30, 2000 is drawn in Fig. 9. In Fig. 10, a log-log plot of the 10 functions
Patterns, Trends and Predictions in stock market 17

ATS
11 BEF
DEM
10 ESP
FIM
9 FRF
IEP
8 ITL
NLG
7 PTE

6 EUR

2
/ USD
1

1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002

Fig. 9. Normalized EU R and Ci (i=1,10) currency forming the EU R exchange


rates with respect to the U SD between Jan. 01, 1993 and June 30, 2000. The data
are artificially multiplied by two and then displaced along the vertical axis in order
to make the fluctuations noticeable. The vertical dash line marks the date for the
EUR official introduction

hF (t)2i1/2 is shown for the whole data of Fig. 9. Moreover we plot the result
for a false EU R, i.e. a linear combination of the ten currencies forming the
EU R [64,65,66,67] Except for IEP , the functions are very close to a power
law with an exponent α = 0.51 ± 0.02 holding over two decades in time,
i.e. from about one week to two years. This finding clearly shows the non-
existence of LRPLC in the foreign exchange market with respect to the U SD.
Other cases showing marked deviations from Brownian motion have been
discussed elsewhere [65,67,68,69]. It can then be observed that a wide variety
of behaviors is found in the foreign currency exchange market. Exponent
values and the range over which a power law holds drastically vary from a
currency exchange rate to another. It appears that the currency exchange
rates can be classified into three different categories from the LRPLC point
of view.
First, the rates which exhibit an exponent α larger than 1/2 (persistent
behavior). This case corresponds to currency exchange rates between leading
currencies (e.g., U SD, JP Y , EU R) and so called weaker ones [69,70].
18 M. Ausloos and K. Ivanova

0
10

−1
10

−2
10 ATS
BEF
<F2(τ)>1/2

−3 DEM
10
ESP
−4
10 FIM
FRF
−5
10 IEP
ITL
−6 NLG
10 / USD
PTE
−7
EUR
10 0 1 2 3
10 10 10 10
τ
Fig. 10. Log-log plot of the DFA function showing how to obtain the α exponent
for the 11 exchange rates of interest for EU R/U SD. The fit slope being only of
interest, the DFA function data has been arbitrarily displaced along the vertical
axis

A second category concerns the rates exhibiting strict randomness (α =


1/2) within error bars. This is the case for example of the U SD/Ci rates as
shown above.
A third category represents the currency exchange rates with antiper-
sistent behavior (α < 1/2) as e.g. DEM/BEF [68]. These currencies most
often concern currency exchange rates between (european) countries which
are submitted to strict monetary rules and to strict regulatory corrections
by central banks due to international multilateral conventions. It should be
pointed out that in general the range, over which the antipersistency signa-
ture, i.e. the power law is valid, occurs over a limited time span in this third
category. In fact, there is a crossover around τ ∗ ≈ 10 weeks. For longer time
scales (τ >> τ ∗ ), the signal becomes again persistent or random.

3.3 Probing the local correlations


It is also of interest to know whether the LRPLC are stable along the data.
In order to probe the local strength of the correlations, one constructs a so-
called observation box of width T placed at the beginning of the data, and
calculates α for the data contained in that box. Then, the box is moved along
Patterns, Trends and Predictions in stock market 19

the data by some step toward the right along the financial sequence and α is
again calculated. Iterating this procedure one obtains a ”local measurement”
of the degree of ”long-range correlations” over T . It is crucial to choose the
most adequate box size T , i.e. to choose T of the same order of magnitude
as the maximum range τ over which the above power law is valid.

12

11 ATS
10 BEF
9 DEM
8 ESP
7 FIM
FRF
α

5 IEP
4 ITL
3 NLG
2 PTE
1 EUR
/ USD
1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001
τ
Fig. 11. Time dependence of the DFA local α-exponent for EU R and each currency
forming the EU R exchange rate with respect to U SD. The α-values are artificially
multiplied by two and then displaced along the vertical axis in order to make the
fluctuations noticeable. For each time dependent α a horizontal dashed line is drawn
to indicate a reference to Brownian fluctuations

The evolution of the EU R/U SD and Ci /U SD α’s for the 1995-2000


period is illustrated in Fig. 11. In order to probe the local values of α, we
have used a window of size T = 2 years. The exponent α varies around
1/2, i.e. the horizontal dashed line in Fig.10. The local value of α seems to
decrease at first and regrows in 95, is stable in 96, has a big fluctuation in
mid/fall 97 and becomes pretty stable thereafter. The ITL case evolution is
slightly different. The minute differences have probably to be associated to
national political or economic events having an impact on the international
monetary policy. It seems interesting to notice that the large fluctuations
in α occur just before the crash dates of stock market indices. See also the
marked singularity in mid 1999, a signature of the XR’s adjustments prior
to the EUR introduction. In order to further prove this point, a linear DFA
20 M. Ausloos and K. Ivanova

analysis of the Dow Jones Industrial stock index around the 1987 October
crash was performed [71]. A similar pattern is found.
Other XR time series have been examined in order to check the non-
stationarity of α [65,67]. This does support the idea that the foreign currency
exchange markets are mainly governed by random conditions [72] or is said
to be efficient in more usual economic language. However, this unconditional
randomness cannot be extrapolated to speculating times nor emerging cur-
rencies [73]. Different universality classes thereby emerge. It may be useful to
recall that Hartmann[74] has examined the competition between U SD and
EU R in a more general (political and economy) framework.

4 Conclusions
The DAX has been analyzed from the point of view of crashes, in particular
the correlations in the signal volatility, before and after the critical days.
The search for the crash day is separated into two numerical problems, that
of the index divergence itself and that of the index oscillation frequency
acceleration on the other hand. By considering the envelope of the DAX, we
have demonstrated that before crashes, a log-periodic pattern exists. Even
though error bars are intrinsically large, it is surprising to see that a rupture
point is easily predicted. A hierarchical structure close to a fractal percolation
backbone (or tree) seems intrinsic at crashes. The stability of this result
should be tested in real time for the best future of our economic system.
A few foreign exchange currency rates with respect to the U SD have been
examined in order to illustrate the DFA technique, the intrinsic structure of
the DFA exponent, and its implications with respect to crashes.

Acknowledgements

Luc T. Wille is gladly thanked for inviting us to present the above results
and considerations, and enticing us into writing this report. Thanks to the
State of Florida for some financial support allowing the authors to participate
in the conference. MA thanks N. Vandewalle for numerous discussions.

References
1. B. Lauterbach, U. Ben-Zion: J Finance 48, 1909 (1993)
2. R. Roll: ’The International Crash of October 1987’, R. W. Kamphuis et al.,
eds.: Black Monday and the Future of Financial Markets, (Dow Jones/Irwin,
Homewood, IL, 1989)
3. N. Vandewalle, Ph. Boveroux, F. Brisbois: Eur. J. Phys. B 15, 547 (2000)
Patterns, Trends and Predictions in stock market 21

4. M. Ausloos, K. Ivanova: ‘Crashes : symptoms, diagnoses and remedies’. In


Empirical sciences in financial fluctuations, Tokyo, Japan, Nov. 15-17, 2000
Proceedings (Springer Verlag, Berlin, 2001) in press.
5. D. Sornette, A. Johansen, J.P. Bouchaud: J. Physique. I (France) 6, 167 (1996)
6. N. Vandewalle, Ph. Boveroux, A. Minguet, M. Ausloos: Physica A 255, 201
(1998)
7. B.M. Roehner: Eur. Phys. J. B 17, 341 (2000)
8. http://www.historyhouse.com/stories/tulip.htm
9. http://www.litrix.com/madraven/madne004.htm
10. http://www.enlou.com/people/bio-lawj.htm
11. http://landow.stg.brown.edu/victorian/history/ssbubble.html
12. http://www.britannica.com/eb/article?eu=70665&tocid=0
13. R. Westfall: The Life of Isaac Newton, (Cambridge Univ. Press, Cambridge
1994)
14. http://mypage.direct.ca/r/rsavill/Thecrash.html
15. M. Ausloos: Europhysics News, 29, 70 (1998)
16. R. Cont: In Statistical Physics on the Eve of the 21st Century , ed. by M.T.
Batchelor and L. T. Wille, (World Scientific, Singapore, 1999) 47-64
17. B.B.Mandelbrot: J. Business 36, 349 (1963)
18. R.N.Mantegna, H.E.Stanley: Nature 376, 46 (1995)
19. J.-P.Bouchaud, D.Sornette: J. Phys. I (France) 4, 863 (1994)
20. E.E. Peters: Fractal Market Analysis : Applying Chaos Theory to Investment
and Economics, (Wiley Finance Editions, New York, 1994)
21. E.E. Peters: Chaos and Order in the Capital Markets : A New View of Cycles,
Prices, and Market Volatility, (Wiley Finance Editions, New York, 1996)
22. R.N. Mantegna, H.E. Stanley: An Introduction to Econophysics, (Cambridge
Univ. Press, Cambridge, 2000)
23. J. Voit: The Statistical Mechanics of Financial Markets, (Springer, Berlin, 2001)
24. H.E. Stanley: Phase transitions and critical phenomena (Clarendon Press, Lon-
don 1971)
25. D. Sornette, A. Johansen, J.-P. Bouchaud: J. Phys. I (France) 6, 167 (1996)
26. J.A. Feigenbaum, P.G.O. Freund: Int. J. Mod. Phys. B 10, 3737 (1996)
27. D. Sornette, A. Johansen: Quantitative Finance 1 452 (2001)
28. J.A. Feigenbaum: Quantitative Finance 1 346 (2001)
29. D. Sornette: Physics Reports 297, 239 (1998)
30. J.C.Anifrani, C.Le Floc’h, D.Sornette, B.Souillard: J. Phys. I (France) 5, 631
(1995)
31. A.Johansen, D.Sornette, H.Wakita, U.Tsunogai, W.I.Newman, H.Saleur: J.
Phys. I (France) 6, 1391 (1996)
32. D.Stauffer, D.Sornette: Physica A 252, 271 (1998)
33. H. Dupuis: Trends/Tendances 22, (38) 26 (1997)
34. G. Legrand: Cash 4, (38) 3 (1997)
35. D.Daoût: Le Vif, L’Express xx, 124 (1997)
36. N. Vandewalle, M. Ausloos: Eur. J. Phys. B 4, 139 (1998)
37. H. Dupuis: Trends/Tendances 22, (44) 11 (1997)
38. G. Legrand: Cash 4, (44) 3 (1997)
39. J.-Ph. Bouchaud, P. Cizeau, L. Laloux, M. Potters: Physics World 12, 25 (1999)
40. L. Laloux, M. Potters, R. Cont, J.-P. Aguilar, J.-Ph. Bouchaud: Europhys.
Lett. 45, 1 (1999)
22 M. Ausloos and K. Ivanova

41. F. Brisbois, Ph. Boveroux, M. Ausloos, N. Vandewalle: Int. J. Theor. Appl.


Finance 3, 423 (2000)
42. N. Vandewalle, M. Ausloos, Ph. Boveroux, A. Minguet: Eur. J. Phys. B 9, 355
(1999)
43. M. Ausloos: Physica A 285, 48 (2000)
44. M. Ausloos, N. Vandewalle, K. Ivanova: ‘Time is Money’. In: Noise, Oscillators
and Algebraic Randomness ed. by M. Planat, (Springer, Berlin 2000) pp. 156–
171
45. W.H. Press, B.P. Flamery, S.A. Teukolsky, W.T. Vetterling: Numerical Recipes
– the Art of Scientific Computing, (University Press, Cambridge, 1992) 2nd
edition
46. R.N. Mantegna: Eur. J. Phys. B 11, 193 (1999)
47. J.A. Feigenbaum, P.G.O. Freund: Mod. Phys. Lett. B 12, 57 (1998)
48. B.M. Roehner: Eur. J. Phys. B 14, 395 (2000)
49. A. Johansen, D. Sornette: Int. J. Mod. Phys. C 10, 563 (1999)
50. D. Stauffer, R.B. Pandey: Int. J. Theor. Appl. Finance 3, 479 (2000)
51. A. Johansen, D. Sornette: Eur. J. Phys. B 17, 319 (2000)
52. M. Schroeder: Fractals, Chaos, Power Laws (Freeman, New York 1991)
53. B.J. West, B. Deering: The Lure of Modern Science: Fractal Thinking, (World
Scient., Singapore, 1995)
54. M. Ausloos: ‘Financial Time Series and Statistical Mechanics’. In Vom Bil-
lardtisch bis Monte Carlo - Spielfelder der Statistischen Physik, ed. by K.H.
Hoffmann and M. Schreiber, (Springer, Berlin, 2001) Lecture Notes in Physics
(http://arXiv.org/abs/cond-mat/0103068)
55. L.A.N.Amaral, S.V.Buldyrev, S.Havlin, H.Leschhorn, P.Maass, M.A.Salinger,
H.E.Stanley, M.H.R.Stanley: J. Phys. I France 7, 621 (1997)
56. V.V. Gafiychuk, I.A. Lubashevsky, Y.L. Klimontovich: Complex Systems 12,
103 (2000)
57. N.Vandewalle, M.Ausloos: Phys. Rev. E 55, 94 (1997)
58. N. Vandewalle, R. D’hulst, M. Ausloos: Phys. Rev. E 59, 631 (1999)
59. P. Bak: How Nature Works, (Copernicus, New York, 1996)
60. C.-K. Peng, S.V. Buldyrev, S. Havlin, M. Simmons, H.E. Stanley A.L. Gold-
berger: Phys. Rev. E 49, 1685 (1994).
61. N. Vandewalle, M. Ausloos: Int. J. Comput. Anticipat. Syst. 1, 342 (1998)
62. K. Hu, P.Ch. Ivanov, Z. Chen, P. Carpena, H.E. Stanley: private communication
http://arXiv.:physics/0103018
63. http://pacific.commerce.ubc.ca/xr/data.html
64. M. Ausloos, K. Ivanova: Physica A 286, 353 (2000)
65. M. Ausloos, K. Ivanova: Eur. Phys. J. B 20, 537 (2001)
66. K. Ivanova, M. Ausloos: ’False EUR Exchange Rates vs. DKK, CHF , J P Y
and U SD. What is a strong currency?’. In: Empirical sciences in financial fluc-
tuations, Tokyo, Japan, Nov. 15-17, 2000 Proceedings (Springer Verlag, Berlin,
2001) in press
67. M. Ausloos, K. Ivanova: Int. J. Mod. Phys. C 12, 169 (2001)
68. N. Vandewalle, M. Ausloos: Physica A 246, 454 (1997)
69. N. Vandewalle, M. Ausloos: Int. J. Mod. Phys. C 9, 711 (1998)
70. K. Ivanova, M. Ausloos, unpublished
71. M. Ausloos, N. Vandewalle, unpublished
72. R. Friedrich, J. Peincke, Ch. Renner: Phys. Rev. Lett. 84, 5224 (2000)
Patterns, Trends and Predictions in stock market 23

73. K. Ivanova, M. Ausloos: Eur. Phys. J. B 8, 665 (1999); Err. 12, 613 (1999)
74. Ph. Hartmann: Currency Competition and Foreign Exchange Markets. The Dol-
lar, the Yen and the Euro (Cambridge Univ. Press, Cambridge, 1998)
75. http://lowrisk.com/crash/crashcharts.htm; http://lowrisk.com/crash/87vs97.htm;
http://lowrisk.com/crash/1929crash.htm

Вам также может понравиться