Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 17

European Journal of Operational Research 123 (2000) 568±584

www.elsevier.com/locate/dsw

Theory and Methodology

Coordinating an innovation in supply chain management


Bowon Kim *

Graduate School of Management, Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology (KAIST), 207-43 Cheongryangri Dongdaemoon,
Seoul 130-012, South Korea
Received 1 July 1998; accepted 1 January 1999

Abstract

The importance of a long-term relationship between a manufacturing ®rm and its supplier(s) has been emphasized in
the literature on supply chain management. Essential to such a relationship is the coordination among participants in a
supply chain. In order to sustain the relationship, the coordination should enhance the pro®tability of not only the
manufacturer, but also the supplier(s). In this paper, we consider a particular supply chain situation in which the
manufacturer coordinates, e.g., supports, its supplier's innovation that can eventually lead to supply cost reduction.
Developing a mathematical model, we show that although the coordination could improve the manufacturing ®rm's
own pro®tability, it might not be attractive to the supplier unless the supply cost reduction should ultimately increase
the market demand to a certain extent. Under particular circumstances, if the market demand stays constant, the
manufacturer's pro®t increase due to the coordination equals the amount of pro®t loss to the supplier. The analysis
presents exact mathematical criteria to determine whether the coordination strategy can be agreeable to both the
manufacturer and the supplier. Numerical examples are employed to show the applicability of the criteria. Ó 2000
Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Purchasing; Supply chain management; Optimal control theory; Supplier innovation

1. Introduction lationship makes both the manufacturer and the


suppliers better o€ than when there is no such re-
Studies on supply chain management have lationship (Asanuma, 1989; Cusumano and Ta-
emphasized the importance of a long-term strate- keishi, 1991; Parlar and Weng, 1997). Therefore,
gic relationship between a manufacturing ®rm and we can infer that in order to be sustainable, the
its suppliers (Spekman, 1988; Doyle, 1989; Choi supplier±manufacturer relationship must result in
and Hartley, 1996). The fundamental assumption enhancing the pro®tability of the suppliers as well
underlying this emphasis is that the long-term re- as the manufacturer itself (Iyer and Bergen, 1997).
The essence of this relationship is concerned
with coordination between the two participants
* Tel.: +82 2 958 3610; fax: +82 2 958 3604. (Reyniers, 1992; Whang, 1995; Sox et al., 1997).
E-mail address: bwkim@cais.kaist.ac.kr (B. Kim). Much work has been carried out for research on

0377-2217/00/$ - see front matter Ó 2000 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.
PII: S 0 3 7 7 - 2 2 1 7 ( 9 9 ) 0 0 1 1 3 - 7
B. Kim / European Journal of Operational Research 123 (2000) 568±584 569

coordination mechanisms (Malone and Crowston, such as contractual commitment between the
1994). Anand and Mendelson (1997) showed that manufacturer and the supplier, and cooperative
the ®rm's coordination structure is jointly deter- advertisements.
mined by its decision-rights structure and its in- Malone and Crowston (1994) de®ned coordi-
formation structure (Eisenhardt and Tabrizi, nation as the process of managing dependencies
1995). They modeled the e€ects of alternative co- among activities, and suggested di€erent kinds of
ordination structures characterized by the two di- dependencies associated with such aspects as
mensions on the performance of a ®rm that faces shared resources, task assignments, producer/con-
uncertainty in market demand. Similarly, Desiraju sumer relationships, design for manufacturability
and Moorthy (1997) examined how the coordina- and so forth. In this paper, we consider the man-
tion dynamics could be a€ected by the information ufacturer's supporting supplier innovation as a
asymmetry between manufacturer and supplier way to deal with interorganizational coordination,
(Gurbaxani and Whang, 1991; Clemons and Row, e.g., managing the dependence between manufac-
1992; Blair and Lewis, 1994). turing ®rm and its supplier(s) (Whang, 1993):
E€ective supplier relationship can contribute to supplier innovation could relate to improvements
improving operations performance in such attri- in quality, yield, delivery time and also supply cost
butes as quality, delivery and price or cost, that in (Monczka et al., 1993; Lau and Lau, 1994; Hartley
turn are regarded as important criteria for supplier et al., 1997). That is, in order to make it attractive
selection (Weber et al., 1991; Akinc, 1993; Lau and for the supplier to participate in the supply chain
Lau, 1994; Ingene and Parry, 1995). Reyniers and coordination, the manufacturer must convince the
Tapiero (1995) examined issues of delivery and supplier that such a relationship will bene®t the
control of quality in supplier±manufacturer con- supplier too. The manufacturer's support can be
tracts, highlighting the importance of strategic and regarded as an incentive for the supplier.
contractual aspects in supply quality management Hammond (1992) proposed that the imple-
(Trevelen, 1987). Hartley et al. (1997), on the other mentation of speci®c coordinating mechanisms
hand, investigated a related issue, i.e., on-time between ®rms in a supply chain can facilitate in-
performance or lead-time, from a perspective of dividual decision-making processes so that per-
new product development, showing a signi®cant formance much closer to the system-optimal level
relationship between supplier-related delays and can be attained (Weng, 1995). If we view the
overall project delays. In a similar vein, Clark manufacturing ®rm and its supplier as consisting
(1989) underscored the importance of supplier in- in a network, their network pro®t can be de®ned as
volvement for e€ective product development (De the pro®t achieved through the coordination be-
Meyer and Van Hooland, 1990; Cooper, 1994). tween themselves, but before being allocated to
As alluded already, a sustaining supplier± each of them individually (Jeuland and Shugan,
manufacturer relationship cannot be possible 1983). Thus, we can suggest the ®rst condition for
without tangible bene®ts accrued to both partners a sustainable supplier±manufacturer coordination:
(Monczka et al., 1993). Such a phenomenon was that is, the network pro®t attained through the
described as Pareto-improving by Iyer and Bergen coordination must be larger than the sum of un-
(1997). They postulated that with the arrangement coordinated individual pro®ts. Since the network
of quick response (QR) between a buyer (retailer pro®t is before the allocation to each individual
in their paper) and a supplier (manufacturer in participant, an optimal strategy at the network
their paper), the buyer can always get bene®ts, but level might not necessarily be optimal to each in-
it might not be attractive to the supplier. Based on dividual ®rm in the supply chain. Thus, the second
empirical studies, they further suggested that the condition for a sustainable supplier±manufacturer
buyer's service level commitments could reduce the coordination is that at least in the long run each
burden as well as uncertainty the supplier should individual participant in the supply chain must
bear. In addition, other industry practices to perceive its allocated pro®t is larger than that it
overcome the unbalanced bene®t were presented could attain with no such coordination. This
570 B. Kim / European Journal of Operational Research 123 (2000) 568±584

condition relates to the procedural justice in global we draw some conclusions and inferences along
operations management (Kim and Mauborgne, with suggestions for future research in this area.
1991). For the purpose of our research, we do not
make a sharp distinction between the two condi-
tions: in fact, it will turn out that the network 2. Model formulation
pro®t cannot be positive unless each partici-
pant should achieve higher pro®tability through In order to speci®cally focus on the intricate
coordination. relationship of manufacturing ®rm's supporting
In this paper, the coordination is re¯ected in the the supplier innovation, we model a supply chain
manufacturing ®rm's support for the supplier's consisting of only one manufacturer and its sup-
innovation activities: we speci®cally focus on a plier (Kekre et al., 1995). Analytical and manage-
particular type of supply chain coordination, i.e., rial implications from this sparse model can be
supplier±manufacturer coordination for the sup- extended to more complicated situations. But, this
plier innovation. The fundamental premise is that is hardly a unique assumption: Newman (1988)
the manufacturer's subsidy for its supplier's inno- studied single source quali®cation, implying that
vation can eventually lead to supply cost reduc- single sourcing option, if utilized properly, can
tion, and thus the manufacturer's own product provide long-term bene®t to a manufacturing ®rm
price. The supplier's innovation is assumed to af- (Newman, 1989), while Trevelen and Schweikhart
fect the supply quality and delivery time, both of (1988) probed sourcing strategies with a risk and
which are combined to determine the supply cost. bene®t analysis framework (Ramasesh et al.,
We will show that although the manufacturer's 1991). In an empirical study, Dyer and Ouchi
subsidy for its supplier can be an incentive for the (1993) showed that one or two suppliers are usu-
supplier's innovation, a simple subsidy might not ally enough to o€er bene®ts equivalent to those
be enough to induce the supplier's cooperation provided by multiple suppliers to the manufac-
under a certain market demand structure. turing ®rm (Presutti, 1992).
This paper is organized as follows. In the next Fig. 1 depicts the present model situation. After
section, we establish a mathematical model to de- receiving supplies, e.g., raw materials or interme-
scribe the supplier±manufacturer relationship diate inputs, from the supplier, the manufacturing
briefed above. Details of the model and its as- ®rm produces its ®nal products and sells them to
sumptions are also elaborated. In Section 3, we the market. As the arrow from the Manufacturer
show how the mathematical model is solved to to the Supplier indicates, the primary decision
draw exact analytical criteria that can guarantee making is concerned with whether the Manufac-
the mutual bene®t for the two participants. It is turer should support its Supplier's innovation that
followed by Section 4 presenting numerical ex- can lead to the reduction of the supply cost.
amples that can indicate the applicability of the As shown in Fig. 1, there is another important
mathematical model. Finally, in the last section, element that can a€ect the supplier±manufacturer

Fig. 1. A simple model structure.


B. Kim / European Journal of Operational Research 123 (2000) 568±584 571

Table 1
Comparison of the two models
Simple model (Section 2.1) Extended model (Section 2.2)
Manufacturing capacity Fixed capacity, D (much smaller than the Flexible capacity (insigni®cant ®xed cost, e.g.,
aggregate market demand) changeover cost)
Demand structure Competitive market Monopolistic/oligopolistic market (imperfect
market)
Price, p given D as a function of p set by the manufacturer
Deterministic demand Deterministic demand
Decision impact Constant revenue due to price given Revenue change via price change deterministic
demand
Cost reduced Cost reduced
Pro®t increase through cost reduction only Pro®t increase through cost reduction and revenue
increase
Supplier subsidy as pro®t loss Supplier subsidy as pro®t loss to the manufacturer
to the manufacturer

Demand information Insigni®cant delay between supplier and manufacturer


Analysis Comparing pro®ts for with and without coordination (subsidy)

relationship, which is the Market Demand. In the product's market price, the larger the market de-
ensuing analysis, we consider two di€erent cases in mand for the product. This situation might be
which the market demand structure behaves dif- comparable with an oligopolistic or monopolistic
ferently. In the ®rst case, we assume the market market condition, where a ®rm can increase the
demand for the ®nal product is constant. It is market demand by lowering the product price.
equivalent to a premise that the manufacturing How sensitive is the market demand response to
®rm is in a competitive or perfect market with a the price change will be an important component
®xed production capacity: this situation is com- to be determined in the analysis. Table 1 compares
parable with the competitive market condition the two models analyzed in this paper.
where a single ®rm cannot in¯uence the prevailing In addition, for analytical simplicity without
market price, and therefore at least for the short loss of generality, we assume that there is little
run the market demand for that particular ®rm is information delay between the manufacturer and
constrained by the production capacity, assuming its supplier (Whang, 1993). Thus, we do not con-
the marginal revenue is larger than the marginal sider any ineciency due to an information dis-
production cost (Varian, 1992). From the manu- tortion in the supply chain (Desiraju and
facturer's viewpoint, there is little incentive to cut Moorthy, 1997).
its price since the price cut will surely be followed
by other ®rms given that the market is competitive.
Therefore, under such a circumstance, the market 2.1. A simple model: The case of constant market
demand for the ®rm's product will stabilize around demand
a ®xed quantity, e.g., the ®rm's production ca-
pacity. On the other hand, if the manufacturing The ®rst simple model assumes constant pro-
®rm can reduce the cost for the ®nal product, it duction capacity and a given market price for the
can increase its pro®t to the extent of cost saving. product. In this situation, the manufacturing ®rm
We relax this assumption in the second case cannot unilaterally lower its price to attract more
where the market demand for the manufacturer's demand. But, it can try to reduce the cost so as to
product is a function of the product price set by increase the pro®t. The production capacity of the
the manufacturing ®rm. That is, the lower the ®nal manufacturing ®rm, i.e., essentially the market
572 B. Kim / European Journal of Operational Research 123 (2000) 568±584

demand for the ®rm, is given as D at time t 2 ‰0; T Š, speci®c functional form is adopted, based on the
and the market price for the product is given as p. well-established learning curve model (Yelle,
Manufacturer's total unit cost of the product 1979), so that c2 ˆ cxm , where c is the base supply
consists of two parts, internal production cost (c1 ) cost, m ˆ ln /m = ln v, /m ˆ 1 ÿ N and 0 6 N 6 1
and supply cost (c2 ) charged by the supplier. the learning rate, which is determined by the sup-
Therefore, the unit pro®t is p ÿ c1 ÿ c2 and the plier's innovation capability. For instance, if N ˆ
total pro®t realized at t is D…p ÿ c1 ÿ c2 †. Since we 0:05 and v ˆ 2, c2 is reduced by 5% each time x…t†
assume that p and D are exogenously determined, doubles while x…t† P 1. Although it can be con-
the only way for the manufacturer to earn more ceptually easier to follow, adopting the learning
pro®t is to reduce either c1 or c2 . In this research, curve formula for c2 is not essential for the ensuing
we are interested in the collaborative relationship analysis: c2 can be further simpli®ed by imposing a
between a manufacturing ®rm and its supplier, and more succinct constraint m < 0, not involving the
thus focus on supplier innovation to reduce c2 . learning rate. Table 2 shows the summary of
From the supplier's point of view, there would variables and parameters for the ®rst simple
be little incentive to lower c2 unless such innova- model.
tion enables the supplier to earn more pro®t. If the Employing the variables and parameters de-
manufacturing ®rm wants to increase the unit ®ned so far, we can formulate the ®rst simple
pro®t and the only remaining alternative is to re- model as follows, (P1).
duce c2 , then it might o€er a certain amount of
ZT
support or subsidy for the supplier to innovate.
In the ensuing analysis, it is assumed that the Maximize Jˆ ‰ D…p ÿ c1 ÿ c2 † ÿ auŠ dt; …1†
supplier takes on projects/experiments as innova- 0
tion activities to reduce the supply cost. Thus, the subject to
manufacturer's support for the supplier's innova-
tion is to support or subsidize the innovation x_ ˆ u …2†
projects. We also assume that the ®rst such project 0 6 u 6 a; x…0† ˆ x0 ˆ 1 specified: …3†
was already implemented by the supplier before
the manufacturer starts subsidizing the innova- As mentioned already, a is the manufacturer's to-
tion. Let us denote u…t† to represent the number of tal cost associated with supporting one innovation
projects the manufacturing ®rm subsidizes for the project. We further assume that out of this a, cm is
supplier's innovation at t. We further impose a
constraint 0 6 u…t† 6 a which implies that the Table 2
manufacturing ®rm cannot support more than a Summary of variables and parameters for the simple model
projects at any given time: the exact size of a de- D: Production capacity (market demand) at t
pends on the ®rm's internal resource availability as p: Market price of the ®nished good
well as its capability. Since an accurate determi- c1 : Internal unit production cost
nation of a is not critical to our discussion in this c2 ˆ cxm : Supplier's unit supply cost to the manufacturer
c: Supply unit cost base
paper, a presumption is made that a is exogenously
assessed so as to be feasible to the problem. ln /m

For analytical simplicity without loss of gener- ln v
ality, u…t† is considered as a continuous variable. In /m : Capturing supplier's innovation potential
addition, it is also presumed that the manufactur- v: Capturing `how fast the cost reduction occurs'
er's total cost to support one such project is a. x…t†: Cumulative number of innovation projects supported by
the manufacturer
Let us denote x…t† as the cumulative number of u…t†: Number of projects the manufacturer subsidizes at t
projects supported
Rt by the manufacturer upto t, a: Maximum number of projects the manufacturer can a€ord at
i.e., x…t† ˆ 0 u…t† dt and dx…t†=dt ˆ x_ …t† ˆ u…t†. any given time
Now, we can express c2 as a function of x…t†, sat- a: Manufacturer's cost associated with an innovation project
isfying dc2 =…dx† < 0. For analytical tractability, a ‰0; T Š: Decision horizon
B. Kim / European Journal of Operational Research 123 (2000) 568±584 573

the net amount actually paid to the supplier: According to Eq. (2), we can further show
0 6 cm < a is imposed. Thus, a ÿ cm is the amount 
that is paid to the external entities outside the  at ‡ 1; 0 6 t 6 t ;
x …t† ˆ …7†
supply chain. at ‡ 1; t < t 6 T :


x…0† ˆ 1 can imply that at the beginning the


supplier conducted one project (or experiment) We evaluate t by taking into account two condi-
which enables it to provide the manufacturer with tions, k…t † ˆ a and k…T † ˆ 0. From Eqs. (6) and
supplies at a unit cost of c. It is premised that as (7) for t 6 t 6 T ;
the number of projects/experiments the supplier k_ ˆ cmD…at ‡ 1†
mÿ1
and
performs increases, the supply cost is reduced: the
speed of cost reduction depends on the parameters
k ˆ cmD…at ‡ 1†mÿ1 t ‡ k:
constituting the cost function.
For the purpose of the analysis, a time value of
Since k…T † ˆ 0;
the pro®t is assumed insigni®cant, and thus the
discounting factor is not considered. k ˆ ÿcmD…at ‡ 1†
mÿ1
T and
To solve (P1), we make use of the maximum
principle in the optimal control theory, the asso- k ˆ cmD…at ‡ 1†
mÿ1
…t ÿ T †:
ciated Hamiltonian being
Finally,
H ˆ D…p ÿ c1 ÿ cxm † ÿ au ‡ ku: …4†
mÿ1
k…t † ˆ cmD…at ‡ 1† …t ÿ T † ˆ a
In order to obtain an optimal solution, we take a
partial di€erentiation of Eq. (4) with respect to u. and t must satisfy
Because H is a linear function of u we cannot use
mÿ1 a
the usual optimization criterion, i.e., oH =ou ˆ 0: …at ‡ 1† …t ÿ T † ˆ : …8†
nor is it necessary to check the sucient condition cmD
for optimality. Rather, we ®rst obtain oH =ou ˆ We need to do numerical analysis to evaluate t
ÿa ‡ k and ®nd out a binary solution, satisfying Eq. (8). With t , the optimal costate,
 control and state variables can be graphed as in
 a if k P a; Fig. 2.
u …5†
0 if k < a: For evaluating whether the supplier subsidy
strategy makes the manufacturing ®rm better o€,
Applying the necessary conditions of the maxi-
we need to compare the pro®t (J  ) based on the
mum principle,
strategy with that involving no such supplier sub-
oH sidy. De®ne J0 as the total pro®t the manufac-
k_ ˆ ÿ ˆ cmDxmÿ1 : …6† turing ®rm can earn without supporting its
ox
supplier's innovation.
Since m < 0; k_ < 0 always holds. We know addi-
tional characteristics of k: (i) it represents the
Theorem 1. In order for the supplier subsidy
marginal value of x…t†, (ii) k…T † ˆ 0 because x…T † is
strategy to be pro®table for the manufacturing ®rm,
left free, and (iii) it is a continuous function.
it must be satis®ed that J  ÿJ0 > 0 and therefore,
Therefore, it must be that k…t† P 0 throughout
t 2 ‰0; T Š. D n o
Along with k…t† P 0 and k_ < 0, Eq. (5) implies D…c ÿ c^†T ‡ c ÿ …1 ÿ amt †^
c ÿ aat
a…m ‡ 1†
there exists a time point t such that k…t † ˆ a,
> 0;
0 6 t 6 T , and thus
 where c^  cx…t †m ˆ c…at ‡ 1†m .
 0; 6 t 6 t ;
u …t† ˆ
0; t < t 6 T : Proof. See Appendix A.
574 B. Kim / European Journal of Operational Research 123 (2000) 568±584

where b is de®ned as the net project bene®t the


supplier can obtain from the manufacturer's support
for a unit project/experiment.

Proof. See Appendix B.

What is more important is the following theo-


rem based on the previous two theorems.

Theorem 3. Suppose that the manufacturer's net


outlay for the supplier subsidy per unit project/
experiment, a, is not less than the supplier's net
bene®t, b, and that the production capacity (thus,
the market demand) D is constant regardless of the
supplier innovation, the manufacturing ®rm's sup-
plier subsidy strategy cannot be pro®table to both
the manufacturer and its supplier concurrently. If
a ˆ b, the manufacturer's pro®t increase due to the
supplier innovation is exactly the same as the
amount of loss experienced by the supplier due to
the same innovation.

Proof. From Theorem 1, the subsidy strategy is


pro®table to the manufacturer only if
D n o
D…c ÿ c^†T ‡ c ÿ …1 ÿ amt †^
c > aat :
a…m ‡ 1†
Fig. 2. A graphical interpretation of the optimal control solu-
Also from Theorem 2, the strategy can be ac-
tions.
ceptable to the supplier only if
D n o
However, the condition in Theorem 1 is just bat > D…c ÿ c^†T ÿ c ÿ c^…1 ÿ amt †
a…m ‡ 1†
from the manufacturer's perspective. What makes
the manufacturing ®rm better o€ might not nec- > 0:
essarily do the same thing for the supplier. For a Therefore, the subsidy strategy would be adopted
balanced analysis, we need to take the supplier's by both manufacturer and supplier only if the two
view as well. inequality relationships are satis®ed, i.e.,
Denote J s as the supplier's total pro®t if the
D n o
supplier accepts the manufacturer's subsidy, and bat > D…c ÿ c^†T ÿ c ÿ c^…1 ÿ amt †
J0s as that if the supplier does not accept the deal. a…m ‡ 1†
> aat :
Theorem 2. The manufacturing ®rm's supplier
subsidy strategy is bene®cial to the supplier only if That is, a necessary condition must be met that
bat > aat , i.e., b > a. However, according to our
J s ÿ J0s earlier argument about the `realistic condition' in
Appendix B, b < a holds rather than b > a. As a
ˆ bat ÿ D…c ÿ c^†T result, we can state that in general, the subsidy
D n o
strategy cannot be acceptable to both manufac-
ÿ c ÿ c^…1 ÿ amt † > 0;
a…m ‡ 1† turer and supplier simultaneously if the market
B. Kim / European Journal of Operational Research 123 (2000) 568±584 575

demand for the ®nal product does not change as while the product cost and its market price de-
the product price varies. creased together. In the following model, the price
is determined by the manufacturing ®rm as fol-
Moreover, if a ˆ b, from Theorems 1 and 2, it lows:
can be shown that J s ÿ J0s ˆ ÿ…J  ÿ J0 †, which
proves the theorem. p ˆ r ‡ c1 ‡ cxm ;
In this section, we have proved that a manu-
facturing ®rm's simple strategy to support its r is the ®xed markup.
supplier's innovation that can lead to the supply Then, D…t† ˆ d1 ÿ d2 …r ‡ c1 ‡ cxm †.
cost reduction is not enough to guarantee in- It is practical to assume D…t† ˆ d1 ÿ d2 …r ‡ c1 ‡
creased pro®tability to both the manufacturer and cxm † > 0 throughout the ensuing analysis: there-
its supplier simultaneously. That is, in order for fore, we focus on d2 that makes D…t† > 0 valid.
the supply chain to have an increased pro®t as a Now the manufacturing ®rm faces the follow-
whole, it is not sucient to make an improvement ing optimization problem, (P2):
limited within the supply chain itself alone.
ZT
In the next section, we take a look at the pos-
sibility that the innovation subsidy strategy can Maximize Jˆ ‰r…d1 ÿ d2 r ÿ d2 c1
bene®t both the manufacturing ®rm and its sup- 0

plier. In particular, we concentrate on the condi- ÿ d2 cxm † ÿ auŠ dt


tion under which such strategy can make the two
participants better o€ by considering a market subject to x_ ˆ u;
demand structure sensitive to the price change of 0 6 u 6 a; x…0† ˆ x0 ˆ 1:
the ®nal product.
As in solving (P1), we obtain the new Hamil-
tonian,
2.2. An extended model: The case of price-depen-
dent market demand H ˆ r…d1 ÿ d2 r ÿ d2 c1 ÿ d2 cxm † ÿ au ‡ ku;

As mentioned before, in this extended model, and optimal solutions for (P2) as follows.
we assume that the market demand for the man- Applying the same reasoning as in the simple
ufacturing ®rm's product is a function of the model case, we can derive t which should satisfy
product price set by the manufacturer. More spe- mÿ1
…at ‡ 1† …t ÿ T † ˆ …a=cmrd2 † so that
ci®cally, we adopt a simple linear demand curve
well established in the literature (Varian, 1992) x ˆ at ‡ 1 while t 6 t ;
D ˆ d1 ÿ d2 p; x ˆ at ‡ 1 while t > t :
where d1 is the base (e.g., theoretical maximum) 
demand for the product and d2 measures a demand Denote J~ as the total pro®t the manufacturer can
sensitivity in response to the price change, i.e., earn by subsidizing the supplier innovation when
dD=dp ˆ ÿd2 , which represents the marginal its market demand is a linear function of the

change in demand as the price changes by a unit. product price, and J~0 as the total pro®t the man-
Further we assume that the manufacturing ®rm ufacturer can get without such subsidy.
tries to keep its unit net pro®t constant when it
allows the product price to be reduced in order to Theorem 4. When the market demand is a linear
increase the market demand. This assumption is function of the product price, in particular
not completely new: in an empirical study, Ster- D…t† ˆ d1 ÿ d2 …r ‡ c1 ‡ cxm †, the supplier subsidy
man et al. (1997) showed an example in which a strategy is bene®cial to the manufacturing ®rm if
 
®rm's markup ratio remained remarkably constant and only if J~ ÿJ~0 > 0, thus
576 B. Kim / European Journal of Operational Research 123 (2000) 568±584
    
1 1 ÿ amt to be acceptable to the supplier, it must be satis®ed
d2 r c 1 ‡ ÿ c^ 1 ‡ T
a…m ‡ 1†T a…m ‡ 1†T that
n o
> aat or d2 r…CA ÿ CB †T > aat ; …9† bat > d1 c^t ‡ SF T ÿ SE
n o
where ÿ d2 c^t SB ‡ SA SF T ÿ SC SE ÿ SD ; …10†
 
1 where
CA ˆ c 1 ‡ ;
a…m ‡ 1†T
  SA ˆ r ‡ c1 ‡ c ‡ c^ ÿ cs ;
1 ÿ amt
CB ˆ c^ 1 ‡
a…m ‡ 1†T SB ˆ r ‡ c1 ‡ c^ ÿ cs ;
m m
and c^  cx…t † ˆ c…at ‡ 1† : SC ˆ r ‡ c 1 ÿ c s ;

1 h i
Proof. See Appendix C. SD ˆ c^2 …at ‡ 1† ÿ c2 ;
a…2m ‡ 1†
1 h i
We need to examine the implication of Theo-
SE ˆ c^…at ‡ 1† ÿ c ; SF ˆ c ÿ c^
rem 4 a little further. In order for the manufacturer a…m ‡ 1†
to subsidize the supplier innovation, the resulting
pro®t increase should be at least the same as the
amount of subsidy spent for the innovation pro-
Proof. See Appendix D.
jects, aat . From Eq. (9), the condition mentioned
above can be expressed as d2 r…CA ÿ CB †T ˆ aat .
It is not easy to understand the practical im-
That is, d2 r…CA ÿ CB †T can be regarded as the
plications of SA to SE . But, we can try to make an
pro®t increase due to the subsidy strategy for the
indirect inference of the meaning of Eq. (10) by
supplier innovation, which can be further decom-
rearranging the terms so that
posed by rearranging terms:
n o
(a) if we suppose that CA ÿ CB is the average c^t ‡ SF T ÿ SE
cost saving (and therefore, price reduction) at ( )
each t 2 ‰0; T Š because of the supplier innova- c^t SB ‡ SA SF T ÿ SC SE ÿ SD
tion, from the manufacturer's point of view, d1 ÿ d2 ;
c^t ‡ SF T ÿ SE
(b) d2 …CA ÿ CB † is the average demand increase
due to the supplier innovation per unit period, where
and ( )
(c) d2 r…CA ÿ CB † is the pro®t increase per unit c^t SB ‡ SA SF T ÿ SC SE ÿ SD
d1 ÿ d2
period, and ®nally we can conclude c^t ‡ SF T ÿ SE
(d) d2 r…CA ÿ CB †T is the manufacturer's total
revenue increase over t 2 ‰0; T Š resulting from can be regarded as the average demand at t 2 ‰0; T Š
the supplier subsidy strategy. while fc^t ‡ SF T ÿ SE g as the supplier's revenue
As in the simple model analysis, the strategy loss per unit demand for t 2 ‰0; T Š. Thus,
should bene®t the supplier if it can be practically n o
s c^t ‡ SF T ÿ SE
implemented. Denote J~ as the supplier's optimal
( )
total pro®t when it accepts the manufacturer's c^t SB ‡ SA SF T ÿ SC SE ÿ SD
s
subsidy for the innovation, and J~0 as that without d1 ÿ d2
c^t ‡ SF T ÿ SE
involving any such subsidy.
represents the total revenue loss to the supplier for
Theorem 5. In order for the supplier subsidy t 2 ‰0; T Š by accepting the manufacturer's subsidy
strategy under the variant market demand structure for supply innovation. As a result, Theorem 5
B. Kim / European Journal of Operational Research 123 (2000) 568±584 577

states that the supplier subsidy strategy is accept- plore an impact of market demand structure on
able to the supplier if and only if the total net the pro®tability of supplier innovation support.
subsidy from the manufacturer should be larger
than the total revenue loss to the supplier.
3. Numerical examples
Theorem 6. Given the conditions assumed in this
section, the manufacturing ®rm's strategy to support To draw more managerial insights from Theo-
its supplier innovation can be acceptable to both the rem 6, we examine numerical examples. In this
manufacturer and the supplier if and only if Eqs. (9) section, we report key numerical results using pa-
and (10) are satis®ed simultaneously. That is, rameter values in Table 3.
     Since we are interested in how the market sen-
1 1 ÿ amt sitivity a€ects the supplier innovation support
d2 r c 1 ‡ ÿ c^ 1 ‡ T
a…m ‡ 1†T a…m ‡ 1†T (coordination) strategy, we focus on the numerical
> aat ; examples in which Eq. (11) is satis®ed by varying
d2 .
n o Numerical examples are depicted in Figs. 3±7:
bat > d1 c^t ‡ SF T ÿ SE
since we are concerned with D > 0, we focus on d2
n o
such that 0 < d2 < 50, which covers practically
ÿ d2 c^t SB ‡ SA SF T ÿ SC SE ÿ SD :
meaningful ranges. Fig. 3 compares the manufac-
turing ®rm's total pro®t associated with the strat-
As in the constant demand situation, if a > b is egy to coordinate, e.g., support, its supplier
held, the condition becomes innovation with that not adopting the strategy as
     the market demand sensitivity, d2 , varies, depicting
1 1 ÿ amt
d2 r c 1 ‡ ÿ c^ 1 ‡ T Eqs. (C.1) and (C.2) in Appendix C. Fig. 4 shows
a…m ‡ 1†T a…m ‡ 1†T
n o the same comparison for the supplier, graphing
> aat > bat > d1 c^t ‡ SF T ÿ SE Eqs. (D.1) and (D.2) in Appendix D. Finally,
n o Fig. 5 integrates the two ®gures to describe the
ÿ d2 c^t SB ‡ SA SF T ÿ SC SE ÿ SD : …11† relationship in Eq. (11).
From Fig. 3, we can see that overall the man-
Unlike Theorems 3 and 6 indicates that it could be ufacturing ®rm gets better o€ by supporting the
possible for both the manufacturing ®rm and its supplier innovation regardless of the demand
 
supplier to become better o€ from manufacturer's sensitivity, i.e., J~ P J~0 . Although the di€erence
supporting the supplier innovation. Under what between two strategies, one with supplier subsidy
 
circumstances Eq. (11) holds depends on many (J~ ) and the other without it (J~0 ), is negligible
factors such as characteristics of the market de- when d2 is very small, in particular d2 6 5:5, after
 
mand as expressed in d1 and d2 , decision time ho- the initial period, J~ becomes larger than J~0 .
rizon captured by T, and the supplier innovation For the supplier, we can draw a similar con-
s s
capability embedded in m, i.e., its learning rate. clusion from Fig. 4: J~0 is larger than J~ until d2
s s
However, the most critical di€erence between the becomes about 42.0, after which it holds J~ > J~0 .
model assumptions is concerned with the nature of Thus, we can infer that there is a nonlinear
s s
the market demand structure. Therefore, in the relationship between J~ and J~0 for the supplier
numerical examples, it is reasonable for us to ex- case.

Table 3
Parameter values for numerical analysis
T a c c1 cs d1 /m v r a b
100 10 4 4 1 500 0.95 2 2 5 5
578 B. Kim / European Journal of Operational Research 123 (2000) 568±584

Fig. 3. Manufacturing ®rm's pro®t comparison.

Fig. 4. Supplier's pro®t comparison.

Conclusions derived from Figs. 3 and 4 can be the subsidy strategy acceptable to the supplier.
combined in Fig. 5 where at about d2 ˆ 42:0 the This implies that the initial demand for the prod-
coordination strategy becomes acceptable to the uct is very small since D ˆ d1 ÿ d2 p. Second, a
supplier as well. For both the manufacturer and large d2 also means that the demand increase as the
the supplier, the range of 42:0 6 d2 < 50:0 makes it product price decreases is very large: a small re-
mutually bene®cial to coordinate the supplier in- duction in the supply cost should have a signi®cant
novation that can eventually reduce the supply impact on the demand increase.
cost and attract more market demand. In e€ect, We can ask what kind of industry can most
42:0 6 d2 < 50:0 can be called `zone of coordina- bene®t from this supplier±manufacturer coordi-
tion' (Fig. 6). nation. Based on the two observations above, we
From Fig. 5, we can make two practical ob- can infer that it might be an industry in between
servations. First, it is very large d2 s that can make introduction and growing stages in a product life
B. Kim / European Journal of Operational Research 123 (2000) 568±584 579

Fig. 5. Determining the joint positive pro®t range.

Fig. 6. Range for mutually bene®cial coordination.

cycle that can bene®t most: in this kind of indus- of mutual bene®t cannot be expected if the market
try, we can expect a relatively small initial market demand is constant regardless of the supplier in-
demand, but a huge potential for demand growth novation. An important managerial implication is
as innovation occurs. that the supply chain coordination cannot be
We have tried other parameter values and were pro®table unless the eciency improvement inside
able to derive qualitatively similar conclusions. the supply chain can induce more revenues from
However, the principal implication of this nu- outside the chain, e.g., the market.
merical exercise is to show that it is possible for Since our research focuses on the e€ect of
both manufacturer and supplier to get better o€ by market demand sensitivity on the supplier±manu-
coordinating the supplier innovation if the market facturer coordination, we have so far examined the
demand for the ®nal product is sensitive to the manufacturer's and its supplier's pro®t changes as
product price set by the manufacturing ®rm to a d2 varies. Utilizing the similar approaches along
certain extent. Despite being relied on numerical with the analytical solution in Section 2, we can
examples, this is a quite strong conclusion since analyze other dynamics involving di€erent pa-
Theorem 3 mathematically proved that this kind rameters. In Fig. 7, we examine how the supplier's
580 B. Kim / European Journal of Operational Research 123 (2000) 568±584

Fig. 7. Changes in t as /m varies, given d2 ˆ 43.

innovation capability (captured in its learning 4. Conclusion and managerial implications


rate) a€ects t (the optimal time length of inno-
vation support) for three di€erent Ts: although Our primary research inquiry in this paper has
d2 ˆ 43 is used for this particular numerical ex- been to identify conditions associated with market
ample, one can see a similar pattern for any rea- demand that can make the supplier±manufacturer
sonable value of d2 . coordination for the supplier innovation mutually
From Fig. 7, we can infer the following points. pro®table to both participants. We showed that if
When the supplier innovation capability is rela- the market is not sensitive to the product price,
tively low, e.g., for about /m > 0:96, t is relatively and thus eventually the supplier innovation itself,
short: the reason could be that the innovation then the supplier±manufacturer coordination
capability is too low to warrant a reasonable re- cannot satisfy both the manufacturing ®rm and the
turn for the innovation subsidy by the manufac- supplier simultaneously. The extended analysis
turer. Likewise, if the capability is very high, e.g., along with numerical examples indicated that it
for about /m < 0:65, t is relatively short: in this could be possible for such supplier innovation
case, the capability is so high that even a small subsidy to be acceptable to both participants at the
amount of subsidy can contribute a lot, and same time if the market demand increases in re-
therefore it is not necessary to support many in- sponse to the favorable innovation coordinated by
novation projects. Finally, when the supplier's in- the manufacturer and its supplier. An important
novation capability is moderate, e.g., about implication is that unless the revenue increases
0:80 < /m < 0:93, the need for innovation support outside of the supply chain itself, any eciency
is the highest, implying that the coordination of gains within the supply chain cannot be sustain-
innovation is most e€ective in that range. Another able since they are traded o€ between the chain
point we can make is that as the decision horizon, participants, i.e., it is a zero-sum game without a
T , increases, so does t : the longer the decision substantive revenue increase from the outside. An
horizon, the more endurable the e€ect of innova- analogy might be that as long as the absolute size
tion support. of a pie remains ®xed for 2 persons, no method,
We can use the analysis model to investigate however brilliant that might be, can succeed in
other important dynamics associated with di€erent allocating larger pieces to the two people than
parameters as well as variables. those they got before.
B. Kim / European Journal of Operational Research 123 (2000) 568±584 581

Although the mathematical analysis as well as J  ˆ D…p ÿ c1 †T ÿ c^D…T ÿ t † ÿ aat


numerical examples is logically drawn, we admit D n o
that the models are based on rather constrained ‡ c ÿ c^…at ‡ 1† ;
a…m ‡ 1†
assumptions. For instance, we limited our inves-
tigation within a simple supply chain consisting of where c^  cx…t †m ˆ c…at ‡ 1†m .
only one manufacturer and its single supplier. It In order to evaluate whether the supplier sub-
was also assumed that the market demand is either sidy strategy makes the manufacturing ®rm better
not responsive to the product price change or only o€, we need to compare the pro®t (J  ) based on the
linearly responding to it. Moreover, we opted to strategy with that involving no such supplier sub-
consider neither any stochastic features nor in- sidy. De®ne J0 as the total pro®t the manufac-
formation delay between the supply chain partic- turing ®rm can earn without supporting its
ipants for the purpose of current research: we supplier's innovation.
believe future studies can generalize the research We can calculate
conclusions by allowing relaxation of these strin-
J0 ˆ D…p ÿ c1 ÿ c†T : …A:2†
gent assumptions. In the numerical analysis, we
could have examined e€ects of changes in param- J  can be rearranged so that
eter values other than d2 on the pro®t di€erence
J  ˆ D…p ÿ c1 ÿ c†T ‡ D…c ÿ c^†T ‡ c^Dt ÿ aat
between the two alternative strategies. We have
mainly focused on the demand sensitivity param- D n o
‡ c ÿ c^…at ‡ 1† : …A:3†
eter because that is key to our research question. a…m ‡ 1†
Although some of the limits mentioned above can
Therefore, in order for the subsidy strategy to be
be easily recti®ed or might turn out to be insig-
attractive to the manufacturing ®rm, it must be
ni®cant, most of them can shed some light on this
that J  > J0 or J  ÿ J0 > 0. By combining
line of research in exploring the supplier±manu-
Eqs. (A.2) and (A.3), we obtain the necessary
facturer coordination in a supply chain.
condition for the pro®table supplier subsidy
strategy as
Appendix A J  ÿ J0 ˆ D…c ÿ c^†T ‡ c^Dt ÿ aat
D n o
With Eq. (7), we can calculate the optimal ‡ c ÿ c^…at ‡ 1†
pro®t the manufacturing ®rm can earn by em- a…m ‡ 1†
ploying the supplier support strategy. That is, D n o
ˆ D…c ÿ c^†T ‡ c ÿ …1 ÿ amt †^
c
Zt a…m ‡ 1†
m
J ˆ ‰ D…p ÿ c1 ÿ c…at ‡ 1† † ÿ aaŠ dt ÿ aat > 0:
0
m
‡ ‰ D…p ÿ c1 ÿ c…at ‡ 1† †Š…T ÿ t †: …A:1†
Appendix B
The second term in Eq. (A.1) represents the pro®t
for t 2 ‰t ; T Š: since x ˆ at ‡ 1 and u ˆ 0 for t >
We can calculate
t ;
Zt
ZT
m J s ˆ ‰ D…c…at ‡ 1†m ÿ cs † ‡ baŠ dt
‰ D…p ÿ c1 ÿ c…at ‡ 1† †Š dt
0
t
ZT
ˆ ‰ D…p ÿ c1 ÿ c…at ‡ 1†m †Š…T ÿ t †:
‡ D…^
c ÿ cs † dt …B:1†
Therefore, the total manufacturer's pro®t becomes t
582 B. Kim / European Journal of Operational Research 123 (2000) 568±584

where cs is the supplier's unit internal manufac- Appendix C


turing cost: it can be either raw material cost or
other base cost that cannot be reduced through the Each of the pro®ts can be determined as fol-
innovation. lows:
Let's de®ne b as the net project bene®t the
Zt
supplier can obtain from the manufacturer's sup- 
port for a unit project/experiment. If the cost the J~ ˆ m
fr…d1 ÿ d2 r ÿ d2 c1 ÿ d2 c…at ‡ 1† † ÿ aag dt
supplier must spend in order to implement the 0
project/experiment is cs P 0 (it is the external ex- ZT n o
penses, i.e., direct cost, the supplier must pay to ‡ r…d1 ÿ d2 r ÿ d2 c1 ÿ d2 c^† dt
conduct an innovation project), b ˆ cm ÿ cs . From
t
the manufacturer's perspective, the total cost per
project is a, while the supplier's net bene®t from ˆ r…d1 ÿ d2 r ÿ d2 c1 ÿ d2 c†T ‡ d2 r…c ÿ c^†T
the support is only b, which remains within the d2 r n o
supplier after the project has been done: b becomes ‡ c ÿ c^…1 ÿ amt † ÿ aat : …C:1†
a…m ‡ 1†
an embedded asset to the supplier. In general, we
can impose a realistic constraint that cs < cm < a 
and b ˆ cm ÿ cs < a ÿ cs < a. J~0 ˆ r…d1 ÿ d2 …r ‡ c1 ‡ c††T
Eq. (B.1) takes the particular form since the ˆ r…d1 ÿ d2 r ÿ d2 c1 ÿ d2 c†T : …C:2†
supplier's net pro®t from supplying products (in-
termediate goods) to the manufacturer is D…c…at ‡ In order for the subsidy strategy to be bene®cial to
1†m ÿ cs † at t 6 t , but D…c…at ‡ 1†m ÿ cs † at t such the manufacturing ®rm, it must be satis®ed that
 
that t < t 6 T . J~ > J~0 . From Eqs. (C.1) and (C.2),
Eq. (B.1) can be rewritten as  
J~ ÿ J~0 ˆ d2 r…c ÿ c^†T
d2 r n o
J s ˆ D…^
c ÿ cs †…T ÿ t † ‡ …ba ÿ cs D†t ‡ c ÿ c^…1 ÿ amt † ÿ aat > 0
a…m ‡ 1†
D implies
‡ c…at ‡ 1† ÿ c†
…^
a…m ‡ 1†   
1
c ÿ c†T ‡ …ba ÿ c^D†t
ˆ D…c ÿ cs †T ‡ D…^ d2 r c 1 ‡
a…m ‡ 1†T
 
D 1 ÿ amt
‡ c…at ‡ 1† ÿ c†:
…^ ÿ c^ 1 ‡ T > aat :
a…m ‡ 1† a…m ‡ 1†T

On the other hand, if the deal is rejected by the


supplier, the total pro®t would be Appendix D

J0s ˆ D…c ÿ cs †T : …B:2† Applying the previous reasoning, we calculate

Therefore, if the supplier subsidy strategy is ben- Zt


s
J~ ˆ
m m
e®cial to the supplier, it must be satis®ed that f‰d1 ÿ d2 …r ‡ c1 ‡ c…at ‡ 1† †Š…c…at ‡ 1†
J s ÿ J0s > 0. From Eqs. (B.1) and (B.2), we have 0
the following. ZT nh
ÿ cs † ‡ bag dt ‡ d1
J s ÿ J0s ˆ bat ÿ D…c ÿ c^†T
t
D n o i o
ÿ c ÿ c^…1 ÿ amt † : ÿ d2 …r ‡ c1 ‡ c^† …^
c ÿ cs † dt; …D:1†
a…m ‡ 1†
B. Kim / European Journal of Operational Research 123 (2000) 568±584 583

s
J~0 ˆ ‰d1 ÿ d2 …r ‡ c1 ‡ c†Š…c ÿ cs †T ; …D:2† Clemons, E.K., Row, M.C., 1992. Information technology and
industrial cooperation: The changing economics of coordi-
nation and ownership. Journal of Management Information
where cs is the ®xed, i.e., constant, portion of the Systems 9, 9±28.
supplier's unit internal manufacturing cost. Cooper, R., 1994. Komatsu Ltd. (A): Target Costing System
By simplifying and rearranging Eqs. (D.1) and HBS Case #9-194-237.
(D.2), we determine Cusumano, M.A., Takeishi, A., 1991. Supplier relations and
management: A survey of Japanese, Japanese-transplant,
s s
n o and US auto plants. Strategic Management Journal 12, 563±
J~ ÿ J~0 ˆ bat ÿ d1 c^t ‡ SF T ÿ SE 588.
n o De Meyer, A., Van Hooland, B., 1990. The contribution of
‡ d2 c^t SB ‡ SA SF T ÿ SC SE ÿ SD ; manufacturing to shortening design cycle times. R&D
Management 20, 229±239.
s s Desiraju, R., Moorthy, S., 1997. Managing a distribution
and therefore J~ ÿ J~0 > 0 implies channel under asymmetric information with performance
requirements. Management Science 43 (12), 1628±1644.
n o Doyle, M., 1989. Strategic purchasing can make-or-break a
bat > d1 c^t ‡ SF T ÿ SE ®rm. Electronic Business 20, 46±48.
n o Dyer, J.H., Ouchi, W.G., 1993. Japanese-style partnerships:
ÿ d2 c^t SB ‡ SA SF T ÿ SC SE ÿ SD ; Giving companies a competitive edge. Sloan Management
Review 35, 51±63.
Eisenhardt, K.M., Tabrizi, B.N., 1995. Accelerating adaptive
where
process: Product innovation in the global computer indus-
try. Administrative Science Quarterly 40, 84±110.
SA ˆ r ‡ c1 ‡ c ‡ c^ ÿ cs ; Gurbaxani, V., Whang, S., 1991. The impact of information
systems on organizations and markets. Communications of
the Association for Computing Machinery 34 (1), 59±73.
SB ˆ r ‡ c1 ‡ c^ ÿ cs ; SC ˆ r ‡ c 1 ÿ c s ; Hammond, J.H., 1992. Coordination as the basis for quick
h i response: A case for virtual integration in supply networks,
1 HBS Working Paper #92±007. Harvard Business School,
SD ˆ c^2 …at ‡ 1† ÿ c2 ;
a…2m ‡ 1† Boston, MA.
h i Hartley, J.L., Zirger, B.J., Kamath, R.R., 1997. Managing the
1 buyer±supplier interface for on-time performance in prod-
SE ˆ c^…at ‡ 1† ÿ c ; SF ˆ c ÿ c^: uct development. Journal of Operations Management 15,
a…m ‡ 1†
57±70.
Ingene, C.A., Parry, M.E., 1995. Channel coordination when
retailers compete. Marketing Science 14, 360±377.
References Iyer, A.V., Bergen, M.E., 1997. Quick response in manufacturer
retailer channels. Management Science 43 (4), 559±570.
Akinc, U., 1993. Selecting a set of vendors in a manufacturing Jeuland, A., Shugan S., 1983. Managing channel pro®ts.
environment. Journal of Operations Management 11, 107± Marketing Science Summer, 239±272.
122. Kekre, S., Murthi, B.P.S., Srinivasan, K., 1995. Operating
Anand, K.S., Mendelson, H., 1997. Information and organiza- decisions, supplier availability and quality: An empirical
tion for horizontal multimarket coordination. Management study. Journal of Operations Management 12, 387±396.
Science 43 (12), 1609±1627. Kim, W.C., Mauborgne, R.A., 1991. Implementing global
Asanuma, B., 1989. Manufacturer±supplier relationships in strategies: The role of procedural justice. Strategic Man-
Japan and the concept of relation-speci®c skill. Journal of agement Journal 12, 125±143.
the Japanese and International Economies 3, 1±30. Lau, H., Lau, A.H., 1994. Coordinating two suppliers with
Blair, B.F., Lewis, T.R., 1994. Optimal retail contracts with o€setting lead time and price performance. Journal of
asymmetric information and moral hazards. RAND Jour- Operations Management 11, 327±337.
nal of Economics 25 (2), 284±296. Malone, T.W., Crowston, K.G., 1994. The interdisciplinary
Choi, T.Y., Hartley, J.L., 1996. An exploration of supplier study of coordination. ACM Computing Surveys 26 (1), 87±
selection practices across the supply chin. Journal of 119.
Operations Management 14, 333±343. Monczka, R.M., Trent, R.J., Callahan, T.J., 1993. Supply base
Clark, K.B., 1989. Project scope and project performance: the strategies to maximize supplier performance. International
e€ect of parts strategy and supplier involvement on product Journal of Physical Distribution and Logistics Management
development. Management Science 35 (10), 1247±1263. 23, 42±54.
584 B. Kim / European Journal of Operational Research 123 (2000) 568±584

Newman, R.G., 1988. Single source quali®cation. Journal of Sterman, J.D., Repenning, N.P., Kofman, F., 1997. Unantici-
Purchasing and Materials Management, Summer, 10±17. pated side e€ects of successful quality programs: Exploring a
Newman, R.G. 1989. Single sourcing: Short-term savings paradox of organizational improvement. Management Sci-
versus long-term problems. Journal of Purchasing and ence 43 (4), 503±521.
Materials Management, Summer, 20±25. Trevelen, M., 1987. Single sourcing: A management tool for the
Parlar, M., Weng, Z.K., 1997. Designing a ®rm's coordinated quality supplier. Journal of Purchasing and Materials
manufacturing and supply decisions with short product life Management Spring, 19±24.
cycle. Management Science 43 (10), 1329±1344. Trevelen, M., Schweikhart, S.B., 1988. A risk/bene®t analysis of
Presutti, W., 1992. The single source issue: US and Japanese sourcing strategies: Single versus multiple sourcing. Journal
sourcing strategies. International Journal of Purchasing and of Operations Management 7 (4), 93±114.
Materials Management 28 (1), 2±9. Varian, H.R., 1992. Microeconomic Analysis. W.W. Norton &
Ramasesh, R.J., Ord, J.H., Pan, A., 1991. Sole versus dual Company, New York.
sourcing in stochastic lead time (s, Q) inventory models. Weber, C.A., Current, J.R., Benton, W.C., 1991. Vendor
Management Science 37, 428±443. selection criteria and methods. European Journal of Oper-
Reyniers, D.J., 1992. Supplier±customer interaction in quality ational Research 50, 2±18.
control. Annals of Operations Research 34, 307±330. Weng, Z.K., 1995. Channel coordination and quantity dis-
Reyniers, D.J., Tapiero, C.S., 1995. The delivery and control of counts. Management Science 41 (9), 1509±1522.
quality in supplier±producer contracts. Management Sci- Whang, S., 1993. Analysis of interorganizational information
ence 41 (10), 1581±1589. sharing. Journal of Organizational Computing 3 (3), 257±
Sox, C.R., Thomas, L.J., McClain, J.O., 1997. Coordinating 277.
production and inventory to improve service. Management Whang, S., 1995. Coordination in operations: A taxonomy.
Science 43 (9), 1189±1197. Journal of Operations Management 12, 413±422.
Spekman, R.E., 1988. Strategic supplier selection: Understand- Yelle, L.E., 1979. The learning curve: Historical review
ing long-term buyer relationships. Business Horizons, July± and comprehensive study. Decision Sciences 10,
August, 75±81. 302±328.

Вам также может понравиться