Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 137

Tropical Ecology Support

Program (TÖB)

The Economic Valuation


of Biological Diversity
Tropical Ecology Support
Program (TÖB)

The Economic Valuation


of Biological Diversity

Dr. Thomas Plän

Eschborn, 1999
TÖB Publication No.: TÖB P-3e

Published by: Deutsche Gesellschaft für


Technische Zusammenarbeit (GTZ) GmbH
Postfach 5180
D-65726 Eschborn
Responsible: Tropenökologisches Begleitprogramm (TÖB)
Dr. Claus Bätke
Author: Dr. Thomas Plän, inf – Informationsmanagement,
Biotechnologie / Biodiversitätsnutzung,
Lessingstr. 3a, D-93049 Regensburg, Germany
Tel.: +49-941-299054, Fax: +49-941-25627,
email: Tplaen@t-online.de
Edited by: Michaela Hammer
Nominal fee: DM 5,-
ISBN:
Produced by: TZ-Verlagsgesellschaft mbH, D-64380 Roßdorf

© 1999 All rights reserved


Foreword

For the majority of the world's population, tropical ecosystems are a vital life-
sustaining force. However, the progressive destruction and depletion of natural
resources in developing countries are jeopardising efforts aimed at achieving
sustainable development and effective poverty reduction.
The Flanking Program for Tropical Ecology is a supraregional service project
being run by the Deutsche Gesellschaft für Technische Zusammenarbeit (GTZ)
GmbH on behalf of the Federal German Ministry for Economic Cooperation
and Development (BMZ), its mandate being to help collect and process
experience in this sector, thus improving the information status.
On request, the program flanks specific projects with studies focusing on
issues relevant to tropical ecology. By so doing, it is aiming to further develop
concepts and approaches geared to protecting, conserving and ensuring the
sustainable use of tropical ecosystems. At the same time, this research work
provides the basis for designing innovative instruments that will facilitate more
ecologically-sound development cooperation in future.
By applying scientific results at grass-roots extension level, the program assists
other projects in the implementation of international agreements, in particular
Agenda 21 and the Biodiversity Convention, to which the BMZ attaches great
importance.
A key element of the program concept centres on a joint approach which
provides German and local scientists with a forum for discussion. The
Flanking Program for Tropical Ecology is thus making a valuable contribution
to the practice-oriented upgrading of counterpart experts and the consolidation
of tropical-ecology expertise in partner countries.
This series of publications has been produced in a generally comprehensible
form with the specific aim of presenting its results and recommendations to all
organisations and institutions active in development cooperation, and also to all
those members of the general public who are interested in environmental and
development-policy issues.

Dr. H. P. Schipulle Dr. C. van Tuyll


Head of the Environmental Policy, Head of the Rural Development Division
Protection of Natural Resources and
Forestry Division
Federal German Ministry for Economic Deutsche Gesellschaft für Technische
Cooperation and Development (BMZ) Zusammenarbeit (GTZ) mbH
Contents

Table of Contents

TABLE OF CONTENTS .....................................................................I

LIST OF FIGURES..........................................................................IV

LIST OF TABLES ...........................................................................IV

GLOSSARY ...................................................................................V

SUMMARY ...................................................................................IX

1 INTRODUCTION ......................................................................1
1.1 Description of the development cooperation project and
purpose of the project ................................................................. 1
1.2 Analysis of problems .................................................................. 2
1.3 Objectives................................................................................... 3

2 RESULTS AND ANALYSIS ........................................................7


2.1 Decrease in biodiversity as a consequence of the lack of
markets and of market failure ..................................................... 7
2.2 Classification of the types of values of biological diversity ...... 11
2.3 Examples of evaluating biological diversity ............................. 22
2.3.1 Use value of genes and biochemicals............................ 22
2.3.2 Use value of species...................................................... 28
2.3.3 Use value of ecosystems and landscapes....................... 30

3 RECOMMENDATIONS ............................................................35
3.1 Valuation methods and techniques............................................ 35
3.1.1 Determining direct and passive use values on
simulated markets ......................................................... 38
3.1.2 Indirectly determining direct use values........................ 43
3.1.3 Determining indirect use values.................................... 45
I
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

3.2 The cost aspect of the conservation and destruction of


biological diversity and the cost-benefit analysis procedure ..... 48
3.2.1 Opportunity costs: restoration costs, sustainability
costs, lost use values..................................................... 48
3.2.2 Cost-benefit analysis..................................................... 52
3.3 Organisation of markets with appropriate prices....................... 53
3.3.1 Monetisation and cost-benefit analyses......................... 54
3.3.2 Dismantling failed interventions ................................... 55
3.3.3 Creation of private property rights and integrated
biodiversity management.............................................. 56
3.3.4 Creation of market-based regulatory instruments.......... 58
3.3.5 Creation of global markets............................................ 61
3.4 Recommendations for development cooperation ...................... 65
3.4.1 Project-oriented cost-benefit analyses using the
available valuation instruments..................................... 66
3.4.2 Training and capacity-building to inventor and
monitor biodiversity ..................................................... 66
3.4.3 Creation and/or strengthening of institutional
prerequisites for the development and
implementation of national biodiversity strategies ........ 67
3.4.4 Training and capacity-building to conduct cost-
benefit analyses and valuation techniques..................... 67
3.4.5 Supporting research capacities in developing
countries at the frontier between ecology and
economics 68
3.4.6 Identification of interventions failures .......................... 70
3.4.7 Creation of incentive instruments ................................. 71
3.4.8 Participation of local communities in biodiversity
yields ............................................................................ 71

II
Contents

3.4.9 Assistance in the creation of property rights ................. 72


3.4.10 Cooperation in establishing global environmental
markets through bilateral and multilateral
agreements.................................................................... 73

4 BIBLIOGRAPHY ....................................................................75
4.1 Cited references........................................................................ 75
4.2 Other references ....................................................................... 83

III
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

List of figures
Fig. 1: Total economic value of a biological asset 13

Fig. 2: Classification of resources 17

Fig. 3: Classification of economic values and attributable valuation


methods (methods in angled brackets are less suitable ones) 37

Fig. 4: Comparison of the resulting costs and use of protected areas 52

List of tables
Table 1: Use values of genes and biochemicals 28

Table 2: Use values of species 30

Table 3: Use values of ecosystems 33

IV
Glossary

Glossary

Allocation Mechanism for the allocation of productive factors or


mechanism resources to certain goals

Assimilation Admission and processing of a substrate

Bequest value Value of keeping a resource intact for future


generations

Biodiversity or General term for the number, variety and diversity of


biological diversity living organisms in a certain environment or unit of
space, divisible into the order and integration levels
genes, species and ecosystems

Biological resource General term for genetic resources, organisms or


parts of organisms, populations or any other
biological component of ecosystems of actual or
potential use or value for mankind

Bioprospecting Exploration of biodiversity in search of commercially


exploitable genetic and biochemical resources

Biotic Of or relating to organisms or life processes

Cost-benefit analysis Collection and evaluation of relevant actions or


(CBA) measures and their alternatives in monetary terms

Direct use value Value of biological resources or resource systems by


consumption or production or by their direct
interaction with market subjects

Discounting Preference of a currently available private use, which

V
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

involves social destruction, over a private use in the


future, which also involves social preservation

Ecosystem Fundamental functional ecological unit which


includes organisms and environment, divisible into
energy flows, food chains, diversity samples,
biogeochemical food cycles, development and
evolution, cybernetics

Emission rights Pollution licence entitling the holder to a certain level


of emissions

Existence value Intrinsic value of a resource

Global environmental Global markets which have either been enforced by


markets (GEMs) international sets of rules or have resulted from
voluntary agreements

Gross national Total value of the goods and services produced by


product (GNP) firms owned by a country

Gross primary Entire photosynthesis, including organic material


production used during respiration

Habitat Place in which an organism lives

Indirect use value Value of biological resources or achievement for


directly used resources or ecosystems

Market analysis Analysis of the procurements and sales prospects of


an enterprise or an industry and the market influences
affecting it at a certain time

VI
Glossary

Natural capital The natural wealth of biological resources

Net primary Quantity of organic material stored in green plants


production minus that used in respiration

Opportunity costs Costs of alternatives that are not used

Option value Use reserved for a later time

Passive use value Measurement of the significance of resources or


similar factors for us, our descendants or other
species

Population Total individuals belonging to a certain species in a


certain area

Preference Ranking of demand for certain goods by individuals

Productivity Accumulation of one organic substance per unit of


time

Quasi-option value Value of delaying an irreversible decision to wait for


additional information to help in the decision-making
process

Surrogate market Evaluation of markets for private goods and services


concept related to the relevant resources and products

Screening Purposeful search for certain substances or effects

Travel cost approach Market approach based on the expenditure required


for a particular journey corresponding to or
characteristic of products or resources, etc.

VII
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

Total economic value Sum or aggregation of direct value, indirect value,


(TEV) option/quasi-option value and passive use value of a
resource or a resource system

Transferable International trade development rights to enable


development rights adequate protection of global biodiversity values, in
(TDRs) particular in tropical countries

Willingness to pay Survey to obtain a value, e.g. for biological diversity

VIII
Summary

Summary
Biological diversity is decreasing at all levels of integration at an alarming
rate. The market prices of biological resources do not reflect their true
values because of a lack of internalisation of external costs and benefits.
This omission is an indication of market failure, based in particular on the
difference between private and social/ecological benefits, on the lack of
markets and on failed interventions.

This paper is based on the hypothesis that the failure to allocate economic
values to the respective components of biological diversity is one of the
causes of this decrease in diversity. Conversely, the allocation of the
appropriate economic values to these components should be able to halt
this trend and to reverse it.

After an introductory chapter, the chapter on "Results and Analysis"


highlights the loss of biodiversity under the aspect of the lack of markets
and of market failure. It is postulated that a market-oriented strategy to
valuate the components of biological diversity would help to stop this
decline. Types of values of biological diversity are therefore subdivided
into different use-dependent and use-independent categories. The
social/ecological value of biological resources or services is made up of
four categories of use values: the direct use value, indirect use value,
option/quasi-option use value and passive use value. These are added
together to give the so-called total economic value (TEV). However, there
is a certain amount of overlap between these types of values, which means
that there is a danger of values attributes being counted more than once in
different value categories. The more aspects of use value that can be
determined and compiled to form the TEV, the closer the TEV will come to
the "real" value of a biological asset. However, if this TEV fails to be
IX
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the


benefits of biological diversity and the lack of information available about
these benefits as a result of market failure, there is an urgent need for
economic valuation studies to be carried out.

The results of several studies carried out to assess genes and biochemicals,
species, ecosystems and landscapes in terms of the use values of the
respective components of biological diversity are highlighted.

The third chapter discusses application relevance and recommendations for


action and presents the relevant assessment methods. These methods
primarily suggest how markets would need to be reformed in order to
correct the present imbalance between prices and values and/or, where this
is not possible, provide decision-making aids indicating the political
measures that need to be taken to correct market signals.

The contingent valuation method (CVM) and related methods of analysis


are of particular importance in this context, because they allow combined
valuations of the direct use value, the option/quasi-option use value and the
passive use value of the components of biological diversity. Moreover,
these methods are the only useful ones to determine passive or non-use
values. Alternative indirect techniques by which to determine direct use
values are also presented.

Methods to determine preferences such as the CVM are not suitable to


determine the indirect use values (e.g. ecological regulatory functions) of
nature as a production factor, since these values support economic activities
or even enable such activities to be carried out regardless of preferences. In
order to determine indirect use values, methods such as productivity
change, maintenance or optimisation work effort, the restoration cost
approach and the production-function approach are currently being applied.

X
Summary

The latter approach is designed to determine the physical effects that


changes of ecological functions have on economic activities.

In order to be able to be compared with use values and benefits, the costs
associated with the conservation, sustainable use and restoration of
biological diversity need to be determined. On the basis of the results of
this analysis, the alternative that is not chosen generates opportunity costs.

Finally, cost-benefit analyses (CBAs) allow relevant activities and their


alternatives to be identified and valuated in monetary terms. The relevant
cost and benefit variables have to established to allow an accurate direct
comparison of the possible alternatives to be made.

By applying valuation methods, it was able to be shown that the economic


benefits of conserving biological diversity are limited at a local level, are
somewhat higher at a regional and national level and become substantial at
a global level. In contrast, the costs frequently show the opposite trend:
They are significant at a local level and low at a regional and national level.
In order to allow effective conservation of biodiversity, the imbalance on
each of these levels needs to be corrected.

In this context, four measures are discussed which should lead to an


effective translation of the evaluation approaches into the creation of
markets. They concern the following:

The removal of damaging distortions of market mechanisms (deregulation)


by dismantling failed interventions. In order to establish prices that reflect
social costs, it is important to abolish all supportive measures that
artificially reduce the private costs of activities detrimental to biodiversity.

The creation of markets by privatisation and integrated biodiversity


management based on the efficiency criterion, i.e. those who control assets

XI
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

should also be those who profit from the benefits of these assets. This could
be attained by establishing property rights to those biological resources to
which vested titles do not yet exist and/or by transferring vested titles from
the State to landowners (including those not yet entitled to land tenure due
to pending reforms).

The introduction of control instruments, in particular market-induced


instruments, in addition to regulatory ones. While the latter imply direct
control (reduction/limitation) of unwanted actions in conjunction with
legislative or politically agreed standards, market economy-based
intervention instruments (MEIs) create economic incentives. Strictly
speaking, MEIs include all political measures explicitly related to private
benefits and costs by which the comparative social benefits and costs can
be incorporated into market prices. These instruments can be subdivided
into five categories: duties/taxes/fees, subsidies, pledge systems, tradable
rights and compensatory incentives.

The creation of global environmental markets (GEMs). These markets can


be enforced by international law or can be created on the basis of voluntary
agreements. A common feature of both approaches are bilateral or
multilateral transfer payments. The particular practical relevance of
approaches used to valuate conservation, sustainable use and restoration
costs for transfer payments (e.g. transferable development rights, TDRs)
lies in the fact that these payments can be related to the amount of money
required in national and international budgets to be spent inter alia on
conservation. In this respect, it is not sufficient to provide donor countries
with financial compensation. The transfer payments must also reach those
individuals and communities immediately involved in using and preserving
the components of biological diversity in question.

XII
Summary

After describing application-relevant methods and mechanisms, ten


specific recommendations are made for development cooperation (DC):

• the establishment of project-oriented cost-benefit analyses applying the


available valuation methodology for the DC projects themselves,

• training and capacity-building to inventory and monitor biodiversity in


the partner countries,

• the creation and enforcement of institutional frameworks for the


development and implementation of national biodiversity strategies,

• training and capacity-building within the partner countries to carry out


cost-benefit analyses and valuation techniques,

• the support of research capacities in developing countries at the frontier


between ecology and economics,

• the identification of failed interventions and consultation concerning


their dismantling,

• consultation on the establishment of economic incentives, especially


market-based ones,

• the development of strategies for the participation of local communities


in biodiversity yields,

• assistance in the creation of vested titles/property rights and

• cooperation in creating GEMs on the basis of bilateral and multilateral


agreements.

XIII
Introduction

1 Introduction

1.1 Description of the development cooperation project


and purpose of the project
In December 1994, with the financial support of the German Forum on
Environment and Development, the present author submitted a carefully
considered preliminary study on "Economic concepts in the valuation of
biological diversity". This study contained a short presentation and
evaluation of economic valuation concepts of biological diversity.

After discussions had been held with those involved in the Deutsche
Gesellschaft für technische Zusammenarbeit (GTZ) GmbH's Tropical
Ecology Support Programme (TÖB), this preliminary study was developed
into a final study to be translated into English and laid out in accordance
with the guidelines for TÖB research projects. Above all, it was to be
revised to enable it to be used for practical purposes: How are valuation
studies on biological diversity carried out and what methods are available
to obtain adequate payment for the determined values?

First of all, the German version of the study was therefore revised to meet
comprehensibility criteria. In order to enable it to be put to practical use, it
was also supplemented by a description of the methods used to valuate
biological diversity, procedures used for cost-benefit analyses (CBAs),
recommendations regarding the organisation of markets with appropriate
prices and supplementary recommendations for development cooperation
(DC). Finally, the revised text was translated into English.

1
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

1.2 Analysis of problems


Biological diversity or biodiversity is the umbrella term for the number,
variety and diversity of living organisms in a certain environment and unit
of space. It is subdivided into the following order and integration levels:

• genes (and their derivatives),

• species and

• ecosystems.

On all three of these levels of integration and on a global scale, biological


diversity is decreasing at an alarming rate. This paper is based on the
hypothesis that the failure to allocate economic values to the respective
components of biological diversity is one of the causes of this decrease in
diversity. Conversely, the allocation of the appropriate economic values to
the components in question should be able to halt and even reverse this
trend.

If market prices reflected the actual value of biological resources (including


resource systems) and of their services (especially ecological ones), i.e. if
external costs were internalised and the costs of the respective resources
thus corresponded to all the values attributable to them, and if not only
their private value but also their social (and ecological) value became
apparent on the market to a sufficient degree, this notion should support
conservation and the sustainable use of biological diversity. In addition, the
socio-economic benefits of biological resources need to be determined as
comprehensively as possible and translated into marks or dollars. Even if
complete monetisation of the components of biological diversity cannot be
achieved (e.g. because access to certain goods and resources is impossible

2
Introduction

to monitor and control), it might nevertheless be possible to arrive at an


approximate value for these components.

1.3 Objectives
This study is concerned with existing valuations of the components of
biological diversity, i.e. those to which market prices have been assigned,
either as raw materials or as refined products. In addition, the various
methods of direct and indirect valuation that are used to try to capture the
"real" value of biological resources over and above their actual market
prices are listed and classified.

Which methods are available to determine the direct and indirect use values
of biological resources? To what extent do biological resources contribute
directly or indirectly to the economic prosperity and the socio-economic
development of political economies? Or, put differently, what is the "real"
value that authors attach to commercially used and usable biological
resources? And how do they estimate the indirect value of biological
resources, most obvious in functions such as flood protection,
photosynthesis, climate stabilisation and soil protection?

Many different approaches exist. One common procedure is the calculation


of those costs that are incurred by restoration ecology. Another procedure
is based on the market prices of biological resources using the theoretical
concept of maximum sustainable harvests. A further approach addresses
ecological and economic productivity. In this study, an attempt is made to
categorise the various approaches and to evaluate their respective deficits,
without overlooking the pitfalls of an exclusively economically oriented
valuation approach.

3
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

On the basis of the deficits that are identified, hypotheses of quality goals,
values and costs of biological diversity are derived. Scientific, political and
economic aspects are considered in order to establish which economic
and/or monetary preconditions need to be fulfilled in order to enable
biodiversity to be conserved and restored.

Using cost-benefit analyses, the social conservation, sustainable use and


restoration of biological diversity in monetary terms and their related costs
and benefits can be compared with the private and social values of
competitive benefits and costs. The following three steps are presented:

• the consequences of these competitive scenarios are identified,

• these scenarios are quantified in terms of their respective economic


benefits and costs and

• cost-benefit analyses are summarised and compared.

However, even if this comparison favours the conservation alternative, this


does not yet result in a conservation effect. This can only happen if the
actual use value and its cost advantages become visible on the market in
market prices. This can be accomplished as follows:

• by creating markets for the components of biological diversity,

• by using free market instruments to correct the existing price


imbalances,

by using regulatory interventions to impose balancing effects that even a


functioning market could not achieve.

This also raises the question of financing instruments that could generate
the crucial incentive for the conservation, sustainable use or restoration of

4
Introduction

biological diversity at a national and international level. The concluding


discussion concerns how financial instruments that already exist or that are
in preparation should be considered and how they should be developed or
modified.

This paper is organised as follows:

Following this introductory chapter, the second chapter on "Results and


Analysis" highlights the loss of biodiversity under the aspect of the lack of
markets and of market failure. It is postulated that a market-oriented
valuation of the components of biological diversity would help to counter
this loss. To this end, types of values of the components of biological
diversity are then subdivided into different use-dependent and use-
independent categories. Finally, actual and target values of genes, species
and ecosystems are presented and illustrated using examples.

In the third chapter on "Recommendations", methods are presented to


valuate biological diversity for the different use values. The second section
of this chapter deals with the cost aspect of conservation and presents the
instrument of cost-benefit analysis. In the third section, measures are
discussed which should lead to an effective translation of the evaluation
approaches into the creation of markets. These measures are developed into
recommendations for DC.

5
Results and Analysis

2 Results and Analysis

2.1 Decrease in biodiversity as a consequence of the lack


of markets and of market failure
The notion that economic well-being may not be impaired and that it may
even be enhanced if the profits obtained by depleting natural capital are
reinvested in reproducible capital is not particularly new in the literature on
theoretical economics. It has been suggested that reinvestment of the profits
derived from the intertemporal efficient use of exhaustible natural
resources in reproducible and hence non-exhaustible capital will ensure a
constant stream of consumption over time (e.g. Hartwick 1977; Solow
1974, 1986).

In the context of ecological crisis, however, the increasing rate of loss of


biological resources has led to a fundamental reappraisal of the role of the
living environment in the economy in recent years. Biodiversity is now
increasingly regarded as a form of natural capital that supports economic
activities. In Art. 2 of the Convention on Biological Diversity (CBD),
biological diversity is therefore defined as "variability among living
organisms from all sources including, inter alia, terrestrial, marine and
other aquatic ecosystems and the ecological complexes of which they are
part". This definition "includes variety within species, between species and
of ecosystems". In the same passage, biological resources are characterised
as including "genetic resources, organisms or parts thereof, populations or
any other biotic component of ecosystems with actual or potential use or
value for humanity".

In order for biological diversity and resources to be able to contribute to


general prosperity, their economic yields have to become comparable to

7
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

and higher than competitive sources. In other words, if the yields from
investments that reduce the natural capital are higher than those that sustain
it, the consumption of natural capital is economically justified (Barbier et
al. 1994, pp. 53f.).

This economic justification, however, is currently disappearing. Market


prices of biological resources do not reflect the true value of these
resources because they do not include external costs and benefits. The
failure to include such external effects in the price is an indication of
market failure.

This market failure can have different causes:

• Difference between private and social benefits: Where components of


biological diversity are traded on markets, their market prices usually
reflect only the private benefits and not the social (and ecological)
benefits that are attributable to them in different degrees from the local
to the global level. The assignment of market prices to marketed
components of biological diversity thus does not mean that these prices
reflect their actual economic values. Partially reliable methods to
establish the social value of the components of biological diversity are
lacking. Above all, there are no mechanisms that permit the integration
of such valuation results into market prices.

• Lack of property rights to components of biological diversity or the


discounting problem, i.e. preference of a currently available private use,
which involves social destruction, over a private use in the future, which
also involves social preservation, makes it more difficult to find a
solution to this problem.

8
Results and Analysis

• Lack of markets: The problem is not only that only certain attributes of
the biological components that are traded on markets are included in
market prices, but that most biological resources and ecological services
are not traded on markets at all, while there are markets for alternative
uses. The market does not take into account anthropogenic influences on
biological diversity or the effects of biological diversity on humans.
Local and/or global markets for the relevant components of biological
diversity in which the market subjects could convert their value
conceptions of biological/ecological goods and services into purchases
and sales by aid of the price mechanism are lacking.

• Interventions failures: Additional market failures as a consequence of


politic failure, e.g. by disincentives (e.g. subsidies, direct income
transfers, tax exemptions), making existing markets inefficient and
favouring the depreciation or destruction of biological resources (clear-
cutting, cultivation of certain species, nutrient supplies detrimental to
the ecosystem).

Despite these limitations, the ability of the market to bring private and
social benefits closer together and to contribute to a reduction of the threat
to biological diversity should not be underestimated. "Finally, the quality of
an allocation mechanism (= mechanism for the allocation of productive
factors or resources to certain goals) may not exclusively be judged on the
basis of a comparison of its results with ideal results, which are ultimately
not attainable by any allocation mechanism (the so-called Nirvana
approach). (...) Since in reality only incompletely functioning allocation
mechanisms are available, it is worth asking what the market may
contribute in pragmatic terms to taking care of natural resources" (Endres
and Querner 1993, p. 139). By setting prices that reflect the real economic

9
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

value, the social interest in the conservation of biological resources


becomes translatable into an individual interest.

Overcoming this market failure therefore implies the following:

• the inclusion of the social values and costs of biological diversity in


market prices,

• the creation of markets for the value-oriented mobilisation of demand


for and supply of biological resources and

• the abolition of price-distorting political and economic interventions.

The benefit that a certain component of biological diversity gives its


consumers governs the purchase decision (e.g. pharmacologically
exploitable resource, resource that can be exploited in tourism) and thus
also the price. This benefit corresponds to the value that a potential
consumer attaches to the respective component. One of the most important
tasks of the monetisation of biological diversity is therefore to reflect this
benefit and/or value in the market price. The appropriate methodology will
be dealt with in a later section.

According to Hampicke (1991, pp. 104f.), regarding biological diversity in


economic and monetary terms obviously does not mean dealing with the
monetary value of a species or nature on its own ("this kind of monetisation
approach would not be allowed"). The question is actually how much it
would cost to stop destruction of these resources and/or to re-establish their
maximum possible functional capacity. "It cannot be agreed that this goes
beyond the borders of what is admissible in monetary analyses. The
criticism not infrequently expressed by the public that this kind of
monetisation can only be based on misunderstandings could be avoided if
people listened more carefully to what most economists really said." "If a
10
Results and Analysis

level of nature conservation is postulated that makes nature almost


inviolable, then in economic terms this means that it is not possible to fall
below this minimum level of species conservation even against paying
demand - in purely mathematical terms, the price of this is infinitely high.
It would only be at our disposal if the costs of nature conservation were
unreasonably high, which might be interpreted as meaning that they are so
high they cannot be expressed in monetary terms – e.g. if human lives have
to be sacrificed. Then a decision must be made between two non-
monetisable alternatives, a decision nobody would be envied for having to
make."

2.2 Classification of the types of values of biological


diversity
The demand for biological goods results from the different value
preferences of market subjects. Use values are relative and linked to market
subjects and their preferences, i.e. all decisions on political allocation result
in opportunity costs (i.e. the costs of alternatives that are not used). In cost-
benefit analyses (see Sect. 3.2.2), the alternatives can then be weighed up
against each other. The social value of biological resources or services is
thus composed of four categories of use value:

Use-dependent values

1. The direct value of biological resources or resource systems is derived


from their direct use (by consumption or production) or from their direct
interaction with market subjects. Some biological resources are traded on
markets, and their direct use values (e.g. agriculturally useful plants and
animals, wood, medicinal plants, wildlife watching) are included in their
market prices. Expenditure on the use of ecosystems for tourism, hunting

11
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

or fishing also reflects their direct market values. As already mentioned,


these market prices are incomplete, because they do not take account of
certain social value attributes.

2. The indirect value of biological resources or services results from the


value that these have for directly used resources or ecosystems. Many
biological resources derive their value from their indirect economic
importance for directly used resources. Indirect values result from (a)
their benefit for other directly used species and/or their genes (indirect
biocoenotic value), (b) their importance for ecological services, e.g.
protection from erosion, assimilation of biological waste materials,
microclimatic stabilisation, water retention, carbon storage (indirect
ecosystem value), and (c) their importance for future evolution (indirect
evolutionary value).

3. The option use value describes a use reserved for a later time. The option
to use biological resources at a later date is kept open by value
assignment. The quasi-option value refers to the delay of an irreversible
decision to wait for additional information to help in the decision-
making process. Because future information connected with the resource
in question may be valuable, this resource remains untouched for the
time being. Due to gaps in our knowledge, it can be difficult to assess
risks and uncertainties when carrying out an evaluation; together with
the partially irreversible consequences of the alternative use of the
components of biological diversity, this means that the concept of the
quasi-option value is becoming increasingly important.

Use-independent values

4. The passive use value of biological diversity results from the importance
attributed to it for us, our descendants or other species. It can be

12
Results and Analysis

subdivided into its bequest value (the value of keeping a resource intact
for future generations) and its existence value (the value conferred by
ensuring the survival of a resource). The non-use or passive use value of
biological resources is nearly completely determined by ethical
considerations and is of importance where individuals who do not intend
to use components of biological diversity would nevertheless feel a loss
if these disappeared (Brown 1990; Randall 1991).

The direct value, indirect value, option/quasi-option value and passive use
value of resources or resource systems add up to give their total economic
value (TEV, Fig. 1).

TEV = F (DUV, IUV, OV, QOV, BV, EV)

TEV = UV + NUV = (DUV + IUV + OV + QOV) + (BV + EV)

TEV: Total economic value


UV: Use value
NUV: Non-use value
DUV: Direct use value
IUV: Indirect use value
OP: Option value
QOV: Quasi-option value
BV: Bequest value
EV: Existence value

Fig. 1: Total economic value of a biological asset

There is some overlap between the different types of values, which means
that there is a risk of the same value attributes being counted more than

13
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

once in different value categories. This is particularly true of option,


bequest and existence values. However, there are different concepts in
economics of how the valuations of environmental changes should be
aggregated in order to arrive at an overall economic evaluation.

ad 1.Many biological resources are traded directly on local or international


markets. This suggests that some direct use values of biological
resources will be reflected in the prices of marketed goods and
services. However, because subjects (individuals, public and private
institutions, companies) can more readily perceive the economic value
of marketed products and services of biological resources than the
value of non-commercial and direct subsistence uses, the result may
be a bias towards the development of the commercial use and an
exploitation of biological resources. This may mean not only that
commercial fishery, forestry and agricultural operations, for example,
may be preferred to subsistence operations or to a philosophy of
nature conservation involving doing nothing, but also that many
natural ecosystems and habitats may also be converted to other
monetisable direct uses (Perrings 1995, p. 866).

The user value, for instance, is a typical non-monetised direct use


value, corresponding to the individual personal benefit of biological
diversity, e.g. by observing or photographing nature or being
stimulated to carry out artistic activities. Where this direct use value is
commercialised (e.g. by charging fees for wildlife watching), it
becomes a serious alternative to other price-related direct uses (e.g.
hunting).

However, the explicit view of the direct use value shows that a value-
related consideration of non-monetised direct alternative uses is

14
Results and Analysis

necessary in order to give them a fair chance on the market. (On the
creation of markets by monetisation, see Sect. 3.3).

ad 2.The indirect use value of a particular component of biological


diversity is not usually taken into account by market prices. Its
expression in monetary terms becomes more realistic the more
indirect the particular use is. While an indirect biocoenotic use of soil
micro-organisms (e.g. Leguminosae are associated with nitrogen-
fixing bacteria) for the direct use of legumes is relatively easy to
derive, the central ecological role that elephants play in the
diversification of African savannas and forests, the spreading of seeds,
the prevention of scrubland, the expansion of grassland and the
reduction in numbers of the tsetse fly is considerably more difficult to
quantify, and indirect ecological use values, in particular, do not
readily lend themselves to direct economic assessment. Determining
these use values by value preferences becomes increasingly difficult
and ultimately impossible due to the complexity of the object and of
system properties that are emerging in the light of present ecological
knowledge.

ad 3.Difficult theoretical calculations in decision-making suggest that


decisions with irreversible results should be examined particularly
carefully in terms of possible consequences; moreover, in situations in
which there is both an irreversible and a reversible alternative, the
reversible one should be chosen. While the basic idea of the option
value is to maintain access options on components of biological
diversity that are not used at present, the idea of the quasi-option value
is to use expenditure on biodiversity conservation to diminish
uncertainty and/or to avoid irreversible decisions (Hampicke 1991,
pp. 87f.). The difficult methodical question here is how much society

15
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

should pay for the conservation of components of biological diversity


that might one day become useful.

ad 4.The bequest value is often included in the existence value, and the
user value is sometimes added to these two values, reflecting the
personal benefits of biological diversity. Since there is some overlap
between these value types, these value components should be
determined as a holistic non-use or passive use value.

The more aspects of use value that can be determined and integrated into
the TEV, the closer it comes to representing the "real" value of biological
goods or services. In particular, due to the aspects of passive use and option
value, the TEV is subject to group- and culture-dependent differences.
Above all, however, the TEV remains a theoretical variable unless it is
reflected by market prices.

In addition to the relativity of values and prices on the user level, further
limitations result from the usability of the respective resources. The use
value includes the following:

a) the extent to which biological resources can be used for different


purposes (transformability),

b) the extent to which they are replaceable by other resources


(substitutability) and

c) whether the use of biological resources by a market subject impairs the


use of these or other resources by other market subjects (rival usability,
sustainability criterion).

16
Results and Analysis

However, market prices are not only based on demand and the value
preferences of market subjects it indicates. The market prices of biological
resources are also determined by

d) supply and by exclusivity of their usability, i.e. by (actual and


intellectual) property rights and their effectiveness. Purely public goods
(e.g. air, water) or a jointly usable resources pool (e.g. the welfare effects
of the forest) can in fact be attributed with values, but because they are
not scarce, they remain outside the market.

Figure 2 shows the relation between the sustainability criterion (c) and the
supply aspect (d).

Others cannot be excluded Others can be excluded


from the use of resources from the use of resources
Use of resources by A does not
influence consumption by Purely public goods
others Resources under
(e.g. national) sovereignty
Jointly usable resource pool
Use of resources by A does
influence consumption by Private goods
others

Fig. 2: Classification of resources

ad a-c)The values of competitively usable resources have to be determined


in separate valuation steps and be evaluated comparatively in cost-
benefit analyses (see Sect. 3.2.2). Their results differ particularly due
to the conflict between interests of private and social use. It is the
dominance of private use interests in the market that frequently
17
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

constitutes a threat to biological diversity. Markets and market prices


exist for purely privately used goods, but not for purely public goods.

ad d) When the Convention on Biological Diversity (CBD) came into


force, exclusive national rights of use and property were created for
the large majority of biological resources.

Use rights to biological resources that are privately owned are purely
exclusive. However, there is still some controversy over a whole range
of biological resources and their services as to whether the use rights
should be exclusively private or national. Vogel (1994) correctly
acknowledges that it is only through consistent privatisation of
biological resources that an interest in sustainability can become
generally accepted against alternative uses.

Before the CBD came into effect, those of the earth's biological
resources that are now subject to national sovereignty were treated as
the common heritage of mankind and thus as non-exclusively usable,
freely accessible resources. Now that the CBD has come into force,
the number of non-exclusive biological resources has decreased
considerably. Resources that are still non-exclusively usable include
marine biology resources outside national sovereignty zones.
Ecological services of biological diversity are usually also non-
exclusively usable (e.g. the production of oxygen by green plants).

A gradual transition is taking place between exclusively privately


usable biological resources and (the few) completely non-exclusively
usable resources freely accessible to the public. The items "resources
under national sovereignty" and "jointly usable resource pool" in
Fig. 2 are the quasi-exclusive and/or quasi-non-exclusive links
between these extremes. In determining use values, it is important to

18
Results and Analysis

make value preferences much more visible in markets by means of


property interests.

Regardless of whether a local, national or global perspective is taken,


normative valuation approaches have to be integrated into the TEV of
biological resources in order to take proper account of rights of access and
property, unless the goods concerned are public ones.

At the beginning of this paper, the hierarchical division of biological


resources into the levels of genes, species and ecosystems was presented.
TEVs can be determined on each of these three levels (and on further
intermediate levels). However, the TEV of a gene or a biochemical will
obviously not be suitable to show the TEV of its host species, and the TEV
of a species (or a biocoenosis) is not sufficient to illustrate the value of the
respective ecosystem. To use an analogy, the total value of a screw cannot
be used deduce the value of an engine, the value of an engine cannot be
used to determine the value of an aeroplane and the value of an aeroplane
does not indicate the value of an airport. The significance of economic
valuation depends on the integration level on which it was carried out.

In this respect, it is not surprising that particular attention is paid to the


application of economic valuation approaches at the level of the ecosystem
(Barbier et al. 1994). If cost-benefit analyses (see Sect. 3.2.2) of an
ecosystem's TEV result in the conservation option, this also includes a
number of components of biological diversity on the lower integration
levels for which individual TEVs do not need to be determined (and which
would presumably not be technically feasible). If cost-benefit analyses of
an ecosystem result in the options sustainable use, restoration or alternative
use, then supplementing the TEV on lower hierarchical levels may become

19
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

necessary in order to arrive at evaluations or specific management


recommendations for specific populations or genetic resources.

Economic valuations of biological resources of the lower levels can of


course lead to effects that make a TEV on a higher integration level
superfluous. In addition, depending on the economic question concerned,
dealing with objects on a lower level of the hierarchy can lead to
synergistic results that are relevant for higher levels as well. For instance,
screening all the higher plants of an ecosystem for pharmacological
ingredients may have a direct ecosystem-sustaining effect, while interest in
one specific gene will only generate marginal conservation effects, if any.

Furthermore, the notion of a so-called primary value has also been


introduced; this is added to the TEV (i.e. the secondary value) to give the
total environmental value (TV). It represents properties of an ecosystem or
biosphere that are highly relevant in economic terms, but that cannot be
captured by value preferences. Whether it will be possible to express it in
economic terms at all is contentious (see Perrings 1995, pp. 842f.). There is
no clear-cut distinction between this and the indirect use value, and it is
therefore not discussed separately here. The properties of its system should
be integrated in the indirect use value.

The central importance of these values for monetisation approaches,


however, is undisputed. Immler (1993) states that "the productive natural
capital is the key category in a holistic ecological/economic valuation". In
answer to the objection that economics does not offer the tools for
operationalising pricing, he rightly points out that "any approximation to
this admittedly difficult unit is better and more reasonable than an
operational term which is certainly wrong" and that "the lack of industrial
understanding of the category 'natural capital' is not the consequence of a

20
Results and Analysis

nature that cannot be understood, but of an economics that does not want to
know anything about it".

One method of approximation is the production-function approach. The


transformation of ecological value units into economic ones could be
successful on the basis of productivity, both an ecological and an economic
concept. Ecological productivity (net and gross primary production) has a
theoretically assignable (potential) maximum, which could be defined as
the productivity of the primary ecosystems ("world-wide wilderness
productivity") and/or by the theoretical productivity of ecosystems after the
sudden end of human influences ("potential natural productivity").
Cultivated ecological systems may obviously show the same net
productivity (agricultural areas including external fertiliser supply) but a
smaller gross productivity than autochthonous ecosystems. (Due to the
ecological degradation phenomena such as nutrient washing and soil
erosion that accompany the creation of cultivated ecological systems,
however, their net primary production also diminishes over time; 20% of
cultivable soil has been lost over the past 30 years world-wide). Even back
in 1986, humans consumed 40% of the global terrestrial net primary
production (Vitousek et al. 1986).

However, even if ecosystems were ranked by determining their TEVs, this


would not correspond to ecologically specified rankings (e.g. on the basis
of productivity criteria). This is partially because of the inclusion of non-
use values (whereby a mountainous region that is not particularly
productive, but attractive might gain a higher monetary value than a highly
productive grassland, for example). However, it is primarily due to the fact
that there are at present still no methods or scientific information to
approximate the actual indirect use value. For instance, we need to
understand the role of species in mediating the key structuring processes in

21
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

ecosystems over a range of environmental conditions. This requires


ecological and economic production functions to be specified (Perrings
1995, p. 889).

It also requires not just snapshots of the value of ecosystem function, but
also time series that show how the value of such functions is changing. Not
only the ecological aspect, but also the evolutionary component is not taken
into consideration sufficiently in economic valuation approaches of
biological diversity, although awareness of the value of the genetic
resources of plants and their relatives in the wild has risen in economic
terms as well, implicitly acknowledging its importance (see e.g. Mooney
and Fowler 1991). However, it is only by regarding natural ecosystems in
economic terms as durable in situ production, experimentation and storage
sites of biodiversity evolution that conservationists' expectations linked to
bioprospecting strategies can have a chance of being realised.

2.3 Examples of evaluating biological diversity


This section deals with estimates of the value of genes, species and
ecosystems arrived at using the valuation methods described previously and
methodologically illustrated in Sect. 3.1 (see Perrings 1995, pp. 844 ff.).

2.3.1 Use value of genes and biochemicals

Whereas the utilisation of genes (animal and plant breeding) or natural


products used to be linked to the cultivation of the respective species, new
biotechnologies now permit genes and biochemicals to be utilised
independently of their parent species, e.g. in cell cultures or transgenic
organisms. This makes the examples discussed in this section different
from product examples such as ivory or timber, whose use remains bound
to the species producing them. However, the borders between the two types
22
Results and Analysis

are transient, and it may be more profitable not to make use of these
biotechnological options and to obtain certain natural products from
complete (cultivated or wild living) individuals of the species of origin.

The direct use value of genetic diversity results from delivering the raw
material with desirable properties for the pharmaceutical, agricultural and
food production industry. Modern biotechnology and genetic engineering
(with the potential for intra- and inter-species gene transfer they offer)
allow the use potential of genetic resources to be extended and therefore
lead economically to an increase and/or a supplementary effect to the direct
use value of genetic resources and their derivatives (natural products).

The size of the market for biotechnologically manufactured products


world-wide is now more than US $250 billion per year, and private
biotechnological research and development (R&D) investments in the
countries of the Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development
(OECD) amount to approximately US $9 billion per year. The annual
growth rates vary between 8% (biotechnological processes) and 20%-35%
(gene technology processes). For example, the United States' proceeds of
sale in 1992 amounted to approximately US $5 billion, i.e. a 35% increase
compared to the previous year (Burrill and Lee 1992; cited in Downes
1993). For the year 2000, a tenfold increase is expected (Industrial
Biotechnology Association 1992; cited in Downes 1993).

Like the existing and potential market prices specified in the following
examples, these are usually distorted by transfer components, and
corrections therefore have to be made for economic cost calculations (cf.
Hampicke 1991, pp. 180f.). Above all, however, the obtained or attainable
price for the respective biological resources is not determined ecologically,
but solely on the basis of market criteria.

23
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

Nevertheless, conservation effects on biological resources can arise from


the presence or development of a market (although the opposite can also
occur). Thus bioprospecting projects are associated with the idea that the
identification (via bioassays) and development of useful biochemicals and
genes might result in a market that exerts conservation effects on concrete
resources in situ with optional conservation effects on other resources in
the same habitat that are not yet commercially exploited. According to
Sánchez and Juma (1994), the exchange of genetic resources and
technologies between the North and the South should increase to about
10% of the respective world trade volume.

Some authors have published papers about the commercial value of genetic
resources. However, some of these data are questionable, because indirect
or passive use values were hardly integrated into these valuations and
TEVs are also lacking. As far as direct use options are concerned,
pharmacological or agricultural uses of genes and biochemicals have been
dealt with more intensely, whereas enzyme use or the genetic resources of
ornamental plants, for example, have been largely neglected.

A study by Sedjo et al. (1994) addresses prospecting strategies for genetic


resources by comparing them with a lottery. Neither the prize nor the
possible number of main winners among whom the prize is finally divided
is known, and it is not clear whether numbers are drawn for which no
tickets have been submitted. This comparison highlights the unknown
spatial distribution of organisms and the uncertainty about whether the
relevant gene or biomolecule might also be found in other organisms. Due
to genetic engineering, the market for genetic resources is developing into
new segments, and it is not known how scarce most biological resources
actually are; the willingness of industry to pay high prices for biomolecules
is thus relatively small. The study by Sedjo and colleagues concludes that,

24
Results and Analysis

under optimal conditions, a maximum economic yield of US $10,000 per


species might result. With respect to endangered habitats in which the
relevant species exist, a maximum of $20 per hectare might be paid.

On the basis of respective contracts, prospecting companies have so far


been willing to pay approximately $50-200 per unprocessed in situ sample
(Laird 1993). However, it would be too simplistic to infer the market value
of the genetic material from these amounts, because it is primarily the
labour-intensive collection that is paid for and not the material itself.

Pharmacologically useful biomolecules

According to a study by the OECD (1987), about 25% of all medicaments


in the OECD countries are of plant origin; if we include those countries that
are not industrially developed, the overall world-wide proportion increases
to 75%. In the OECD member countries, plant-based medicaments
amounting to more than DM 100 billion were sold in 1985. Two fifths of
all modern U.S. pharmaceutical products contain one or more ingredients
of natural origin (Oldfield 1984).

The commercial value of medicines derived from species living in the wild
is estimated at more than US $40 billion p.a. world-wide, and the figure for
the United States in 1980 was US $8112 billion. The present share of the
genetic material used for pharmaceutical products originating from the
South amounts to about US $4.7 billion. The present hectare yields of
medicinal plants from the tropical rain forest are estimated to range from
$262 to $1000 (Pearce and Moran 1994).

Assuming a rate of extinction of 10%, an estimated 2067 plant species will


have become extinct by the year 2000, 16 of them of special

25
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

pharmaceutical interest; Farnsworth and Soejarto (1985) have estimated


this to entail an economic loss of US $3.25 billion ($16×203 million).

By means of bioprospecting, i.e. screening biological diversity in search of


commercially exploitable genetic and biochemical resources, the value of
the germ plasm for medicinal purposes from the South, which currently
amounts to approximately US $4.7 billion, might rise over the next
10 years to US $47 billion. For Costa Rica, Aylward (1993) estimated the
value of "pharmaceutical prospecting" at $4.81 million per successfully
prospected product. However, these figures have to be related to capital
outlays of over US $200 million for the development of a single successful
pharmaceutical ready for the market (Krattiger and Lesser 1994).

Mendelsohn and Balick (1995) are sceptical regarding the future economic
importance of bioprospecting. They estimate the entire social value of non-
discovered tropical pharmaceuticals at only approximately US $150 billion
or US $48 per hectare, and the market value for private enterprises at US
$3 billion or US $1 per hectare.

A rough estimation of the pharmaceutical value of extinct plant species on


behalf of UNEP came to the conclusion that the average "pharmaceutical"
loss for each of these species amounts to approximately $80,000 (UNEP
1993). This figure is problematic, however, because some "best-sellers"
that have earned the companies that sell them millions (e.g. aspirin, taxol)
are included in this estimate.

Genetic resources of plants

The complexity of modern and traditional breeding practices means that


only a very general approximation of the actual monetary value is possible,
and even then only for the most common grain varieties. This uncertainty

26
Results and Analysis

in putting a number on the existing market value is reflected in estimations


concerning the contribution of the genetic resources of the South to the
valuation of food production in the North. For wheat and corn, the figures
are estimated at US $75 million p.a. for Australia, US $500 million p.a. for
the United States and US $2.7 billion p.a. for all the OECD countries
together (Mooney and Fowler 1991). According to Woodruff and Gall
(1992), about half of the increase in agricultural productivity in this century
can be directly attributed to artificial selection, recombination and intra-
species gene transfer.

Calculations by the U.S. seed industry show that a genetic trait of a plant in
the Third World that can be used for breeding purposes may contribute
over $2 billion annually to the yields of U.S. wheat, rice and corn
producers. The U.S. Department of Agriculture estimates that genetic plant
material has led to an average increase in productivity of about 1% a year,
with an initial monetary value far exceeding US $1.billion.

Bioprospecting as a source of new cultivated plants and of raw materials to


breed improved plant varieties and as a supplier of natural pesticides and
renewable resources such as fibres and botanical chemicals has great
potential (Plotkin 1992).

At the beginning of the next millennium, the world-wide biotechnology


food sector will increase to US $20 billion (a sixfold increase).

27
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

Table 1: Use values of genes and biochemicals

Components used Evaluation method Estimated Source


applied value (US $)
Plants Market analysis: 2,580,000 Farnsworth and
estimations of Soejarto 1985
proceeds of sale
Plants Market analysis 474,000 Principe 1989
Trees Market analysis 7,500 McAllister 1991
Plants Evaluation of the 23,700,000 Principe 1989
number of lives saved
Species from Cameroon Costs of renewing 15-150 Ruitenbeek
patents 1989
Species from Costa Rica Market analysis, 253 Harvard
estimated licence fees Business School
Plants of the rain forest Market analysis and 585-1,050,000 Pearce and
evaluation of human Puroshothaman
lives saved 1992
Pharmaceutical bioprospecting for a Market analysis: net 4.81 million Aylward 1993
commercially successful plant returns on
product bioprospecting
Living organisms Market analysis: 52-46,000 Reid et al. 1993
returns on purchase +
licence fees

2.3.2 Use value of species

In contrast to Sect. 2.3.1., the components of biological diversity dealt with


in this section are used as total organisms.

Use of plants

Of the approximately 250,000 higher plant species that have been described
world-wide, about one third probably has edible components, i.e. around
80,000 species. About 15,000 species (including spice plants, herbs, etc.)

28
Results and Analysis

are actually used for human nutrition (Heywood 1994, personal


communication). Supraregionally or world-wide, about 150 species are
cultivated for human nutrition. However, only five varieties of grain
(wheat, corn, rice, barley and millet) account for 50% of vegetable nutrition
in humans, and 20 species supply 90% of the world-wide demand (Myers
1989).

The quantity of renewable resources currently used and processed world-


wide amounts to approximately 2 billion tons of timber, 2 billion tons of
grain (including the food supply) and 2 billion tons of other products such
as sugar-cane, carrots, oil and leguminous plants. The global timber trade is
worth approximately $80 billion annually.

According to Peters et al. (1989), the present net value of sustainably used
biological raw materials (rubber, fruits, wood) from the rain forest in Peru
amounts to $6330 per hectare, i.e. more than sixfold the value of utilisable
wood ($490/ha). In the German chemical industry, about 2 million tons of
renewable resources are utilised at present (i.e. 10% of the entire
consumption of raw materials).

Use of game animals

Prescott-Allen and Prescott-Allen (1986) estimate the monetary


contributions of wild and semi-wild animals and plants as accounting for
approximately 4% of the gross national product (GNP) in the United States
and Canada. Barnes and Pearce (1991) have shown that the direct use value
of certain forms of wildlife management is financially more productive
than the transformation of game reserves into pasture areas (cf. Table 2).

29
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

Table 2: Use values of species

Components of biodiversity Evaluation Estimated Source


used method applied value (US $)
Wildlife watching value of elephants, CVM; travel cost 25 Brown and Henry 1989
Kenya method million/year
Ivory exports before the export ban, 35-35 Barbier et al. 1990
Africa million/year
Use of wild buffaloes, Zimbabwe 3.5-4.5/ha Child 1990
Export of non-coniferous wood 11 billion/year Barbier et al. 1994
products, entire tropics
Harvest of wood fruits and latex, 6330/ha Peters et al. 1989
Peru
Fish and firewood from wetlands, 38-59/ha Barbier et al. 1991
Nigeria
Improvement of the survival CRM 21/person and Brown et al. 1994
probability of the Northern spotted year
owl
CVM, contingent valuation method; CRM, contingent ranking method.

2.3.3 Use value of ecosystems and landscapes

Ecological resources and services that can be derived from the production,
carrier and information functions of ecosystems produce economic yields
in the form of direct use values. Direct use values include timber and non-
wood products, medicinal plants, plant genes, hunting and fishery,
recreation and tourism, education and human living areas, since all these
products and services are the result of a direct use of forests. Direct use
presupposes access to forest resources, among other things.

In contrast, indirect use does not require access to forest resources. The
most important indirect use values of biological diversity include the
regulatory functions of ecosystems. Each ecosystem is composed of a

30
Results and Analysis

whole range of physical, biological and chemical components. Interaction


between these components results in specific types of ecosystem functions
or characteristics such as the nutrient cycle, biological productivity, water
regime and sedimentation. These regulatory ecological functions are
fundamental to numerous secondary ecological functions and services,
which again are of fundamental importance in human life and societies
(e.g. erosion protection, water retention, detoxification, assimilation of
biological waste, climatic stabilisation, carbon storage).

As far as the role of individual species in the mediation of such regulatory


functions is understood, it is principally possible to establish the indirect
use value of such species. Indeed, the relationship between individual
organisms and ecosystem functioning is of central importance in the
concept of indirect use valuation.

Immler (1989) assumes that roughly a third of GNP (based on the German
GNP) would be necessary to re-establish the disturbed non-human natural
services and processes.

Most studies assessing the economic value of forests only take account of
partial values and not the TEV (for a relevant review, see Perrings 1995,
pp. 886f.). Indirect and non-use values are usually completely neglected,
and direct use values are also frequently only incompletely considered.

The first attempt to estimate the TEV of tropical forest habitats was
undertaken by Castro (1994). Castro calculated an average net actual value
of $1278-$2871 per hectare for Costa Rica's game wilderness. Multiplied
by the total area of 1.3 million hectares, this gave a present total value of
$1.7-$3.7 billion, of which, according to this study, 34% benefits Costa
Rica and 66% the world community.

31
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

Kaosard et al. (1994) evaluated not the total, but almost the total economic
value of the Khao Yai Park in Thailand (not including non-use values for
people who do not live in Thailand and estimations of carbon storage). The
comparative evaluation with agriculturally managed areas arrived at a
figure of $250 per hectare (see Table 3).

Barbier et al. (1991) showed that the direct use of the Hadejia Jama'are
floodplain in Nigeria for fishery, the production of firewood and migration
agriculture results in economic yields that are higher than alternative
irrigation projects upstream.

32
Results and Analysis

Table 3: Use values of ecosystems

Components used Evaluation method Estimated value Source


applied (US $)
Nature tourism, Cameroon: 19/ha Ruitenbeek 1989
Sustaining soil fertility by Productivity change 8/ha and 23/ha Ruitenbeek 1989
forests and inundation
control, Cameroon
Khao Yai Park, Thailand CVM, travel cost 80 million/year, Kaosard et al.
method 400/ha/year 1994
Ecotourism, Costa Rica Travel cost method 1250/ha Tobias and
Mendelsohn 1991
Importance of wetlands for Production-function Ellis and Fisher
crab production, Arabian approach 1987
Sea
Valuation of reserves, Production-function 566,070-2,160,000 Munasinghe 1993;
Madagascar approach, CVM, travel Kramer et al. 1993
cost method
Carbon storage by forests, 1300/ha/year Pearce 1990
Brazil
Importance of mangroves 536 million Ruitenbeek 1992
for agriculture, fishery,
Indonesia
Water retention by forests, 232-388/acre Bowes and
USA Krutilla 1989
Forest in Peru, Rio Nanay Productivity method 6300/ha for non- Peters et al. 1989
(comparisons of timber products
income) vs. 1000 for clear-
cutting
Primeval forest, Costa Rica TEV 102-214/ha/year, Castro 1994
1278-2871/ha,
133-278
million/year, 1.7-
3.7 billion

33
Recommendations

3 Recommendations

3.1 Valuation methods and techniques


Because of the benefits of biological diversity and the lack of information
about these benefits due to market failure, there is an urgent need for
economic valuation studies to be carried out. In the following, relevant
valuation methods are thus presented. Arguments in favour of their
application include the following:

• they give valuable information on how markets need to be reformed in


order to correct the present bias and/or, where this is not possible,

• they provide decision-making aids indicating political measures that


should be taken to correct market signals.

When applying these valuation methods, however, it is important to


remember what is actually being measured by the valuation technique, e.g.
direct use benefits, net benefits including use and non-use benefits, etc.,
and the reliability of the different data and methodologies in assessing these
different benefits yields (Perrings 1995, p. 878).

As Fig. 3 shows, the use value categories "direct use values", "indirect use
values", "option/quasi-option values" and "non-use values", which together
give the TEV, allow the application of various valuation methods. In the
following, these methods are presented and the range of effects to be
valued is considered.

Not all of these methods are able to completely determine biodiversity-


related costs and benefits. Each of them, however, is useful in the correct

35
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

context. Roughly speaking, we can differentiate between monetisation


methods as follows (see OECD 1996, p. 74):

• on the basis of actual market prices (market analyses),

• on the basis of simulated market prices (contingent valuation and


ranking; individual choice model),

• on the basis of surrogate market prices (e.g. the travel cost approach and
hedonic price approach) and

• on the basis of the production-function approach (e.g. value of changes


of productivity, avoided damage costs).

Since, in the context of this study, we are interested in the external use
values of biological diversity that are not reflected by actual market prices,
the subsequent discussion is limited to valuation approaches for simulated
markets (Sect. 3.1), surrogate markets (Sect. 3.2) and the production-
function approach (Sect. 3.3). The common instrument of market analysis
is therefore not discussed here.

The presently available set of valuation methods show very large


differences not only in valuation methodology, but also in their
conceptional treatment of the problem. For instance, there is still no
consensus on how to determine the existence value (Perrings 1995, p. 891).

These methods presuppose acceptance by those with political


responsibility. They have to guarantee that the monetisation requirements
that are identified become economically effective by income transmissions,
taxes, etc.

36
Recommendations

Fig. 3: Classification of economic values and attributable valuation


methods (methods in angled brackets are less suitable ones)

Use values Non-use values

Direct use values Indirect use values Option values Existence values
(functional values) Quasi-option values Bequest values

METHODS: METHODS: METHODS: METHODS:

Market analysis Avoided 'Individual choice' Contingent valuation


damage costs model method

Travel cost Prophylactic Restricted


method expenses information value

Contingent valuation Value of productivity Contingent valuation


method changes method

Hedonic prices <Transplantation


costs>

'Public' prices <Replacement cost


approach>

<Replacement cost
approach etc.>

Figure 3 highlights the particular importance of the contingent valuation


method (CVM); this method allows statements to be made about all use
value categories with the exception of the indirect use value. Indeed, it is
the only useful method to identify non-use values. This is because passive
or non-use values of the components of biological diversity are not related
to any activity or even the purchase of market goods and thus cannot be
determined using indirect valuation methods (Stephan and Ahlheim 1996,
p. 153).

37
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

3.1.1 Determining direct and passive use values on simulated markets

Sociological interviewing methods are the most practicable approaches to


determine the economic value of the components of biological diversity. In
principle, these methods can be differentiated according to two interview
objectives:

• to attribute a value to the components of biological diversity concerned


(contingent valuation method, CVM) on the basis of analyses of
willingness to pay (WTP) and willingness to accept (WTA) or
• to rank values (contingent ranking method, CRM).

The best way to apply the direct valuation method is to determine the
WTP/WTA of one environment-related use for the person being
interviewed or the one that corresponds to his or her personal opinion and
knowledge, e.g. recreation options. WTP analyses on the basis of losses of
environmental/biological diversity are more problematic. Moreover, we
still have some way to go before the psychological and cognitive processes
that influence the formulation of answers can be definitively assessed.

Even if the direct valuation method is not exact enough for carrying out
cost-benefit analyses or for legislative purposes, provided that specific
questions are asked, its results may nevertheless be used as a
supplementary public opinion poll to establish earmarking priorities
concerning the use and conservation of biodiversity, particularly because it
is the only method that is able to translate non-use values into market prices
(Blamey and Common 1993).

The main problem of this method is undoubtedly related to the possible


disparity between the data obtained from interviewees concerning their
WTP and the amounts that they are actually willing to pay if the need arises
(Ruck 1990, p. 330). In Australia, for instance, CVMs and related methods
38
Recommendations

are not generally recognised as accepted methods, since the values that are
determined are seen as improbably high (Blamey 1996).

Contingent valuation method (CVM)

In a direct analysis of WTP or willingness to renounce, value preferences


are determined on the basis of interviews. This method is referred to as the
CVM, not least because of the hypothetical nature of the situation
("simulated market situation"). It is applied to determine direct use, non-use
or passive use (existence and bequest values) and option/quasi-option use
values, but not indirect use values. Thus CVM (and the analogous CRM)
differ from all other important economic valuation methods, which can
only be used to determine one type of use value.

According to Pearce and Moran (1994), the CVM is the most important
method for the economic valuation of biodiversity, largely because it is the
only one that directly reflects the non-use-orientated (bequest and
existence) values of biodiversity. In addition to information retrieval and
information exchange during the interview process, verbatim minutes and
tape recordings allow the interviewer to analyse the biodiversity-related
knowledge and understanding of the interviewee ("think-aloud analysis").

Interest in this method has greatly increased over the last 10 years:

• because it is the only procedure that can be used to evaluate non-use-


values,

• because well-conceived and correctly conducted interviews might be as


valid as valuations of direct use values obtained by other methods and

• because the conception, analysis and interpretation of stated preferences


have also improved, e.g. the "scientific sampling" and "benefit

39
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

estimation" theories have improved the computerised data


administration and analysis of public opinion polls and their validity.

The first stage of a CVM involves providing interviewees with background


information about the relevant biological resources. They are given further
information about the quality, quantity and the time-scale of changes.

In the second stage, a payment instrument is selected. This involves asking


interviewees whether they would be willing to pay into a hypothetical fund
or whether they would prefer a tax or a price increase. At this stage, it is
very important for the interviewer to propose a reliable payment instrument
and to be able to depict a plausible and acceptable scenario for the
interviewee.

In the third stage, a method has to be selected that allows the WTP or
willingness to renounce to be determined as accurately as possible. In an
open-ended approach, interviewees have to state the maximum amount that
they would be ready to pay or renounce. If a "dichotomous choice"
approach is used, the interviewee is confronted with a concrete amount that
is varied within a group of interviewees to come as close as possible to the
"real" value (see Perrings 1995, pp. 845f.; Hampicke 1991, pp. 118ff.;
Pearce and Moran 1994, pp. 58ff.).

Valuation of the direct value assigned to a product or service on the basis


of the interview requires verification of the reliability and validity, and
answers need to be examined to identify any possible falsifications.

In order to obtain exact and reliable answers regarding the WTP,


standardised guidelines can be used, such as those developed by the U.S.
National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration Committee (NOAA;
Arrow 1993):

40
Recommendations

1. Sample type and size - probability sampling is essential. The choice of sample
specific designs and size is a difficult technical question that requires the guidance
of a professional sampling statistician.

2. Minimize non-responses - high non-response rates would make CV (contingent


valuation) survey results unreliable.

3. Personal interview - it is improbable that reliable value estimates can be elicited


with mail surveys. Face-to-face interviews are usually preferable, although
telephone interviews have some advantages in terms of costs and centralized
supervision.

4. Pretesting for interviewer effects - an important respect in which CV surveys differ


from actual referendum is the presence of an interviewer (except in the case of mail
survey). It is possible that interviewers contribute to 'social desirability' bias, since
preserving the environment is widely viewed as something positive. In order to test
this possibility, major CV studies should incorporate experiments that assess
interviewer effects.

5. Reporting - every report of a CV study should make clear the definition of the
population sampled, the sampling frame used, the sample size, the overall sample
non-response rate and its components (e.g., refusals), and item non-responses on all
important questions. The report should also reproduce the exact wording and
sequence of the questionnaire and of other communications to respondents (e.g.,
advance letters). All data from the study should be archived and made available to
interested parties.

6. Careful pretesting of a CV questionnaire - respondents in a CV survey are


ordinarily presented with a good deal of new and often technical information, well
beyond what is typical in most surveys. This requires very careful pilot work and
pre-testing, plus evidence from the final survey that respondents understood and
accepted the description of the good or service offered and the questioning
reasonably well.

7. Conservative design - when aspects of the survey design and the analysis of the
responses are ambiguous, the option that tends to underestimate the willingness-to-
pay is generally preferred. A conservative design increases the reliability of the

41
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

estimate by eliminating extreme responses that can enlarge estimated values wildly
and implausibly.

8. Elicitation format - the willingness-to-pay format should be used instead of


compensation required because the former is the conservative choice.

9. Referendum format - the valuation question should be posed as a vote on a


referendum.

10. Accurate description of the program or policy - adequate information must be


provided to respondents about the environmental program that is offered.

11. Pretesting of photographs - the effects of photographs on subjects must be carefully


explored.

12. Reminder of substitute commodities - respondents must be reminded of substitute


commodities. This reminder should be introduced forcefully and directly prior to the
main valuation to assure that the respondents have the alternatives clearly in mind.

13. Temporal averaging - time-dependent measurement noise should be reduced by


averaging across independently drawn samples taken at different points in time. A
clear and substantial time trend in the responses would cast doubt on the reliability
of the value information obtained from a CV survey.

14. 'No-answer' option - a 'no-answer' option should be explicitly allowed in the


addition to the 'yes' or 'no' options on the main valuation (referendum) question.
Respondents who choose the 'no-answer' option should be asked to explain their
choice.

15. Yes/no follow-ups - yes and no responses should be followed-up by the open-ended
question: 'Why did you vote yes/no?'

16. Cross-tabulations - the survey should include a variety of other questions that help
interpret the responses to the primary valuation question. The final report should
include summaries of willingness-to-pay broken down by these categories (e.g.,
income, education, attitudes towards biodiversity).

17. Checks on understanding and acceptance - the survey instrument should not be so
complex that it poses tasks that are beyond the ability or interest level of many
participants.

42
Recommendations

Contingent ranking method (CRM)

The CRM is the stepsister of the CVM. The different feature in this
interview situation is that respondents are confronted with a set of options
that they are asked to rank according to their valuation scale. For each of
the options, the interviewer designates a set of characteristics and describes
how the options differ. The resulting costs should be delineated for each
option.

Asking questions about relative valuations and specifically costed


alternatives facilitates the choice for the interviewee; conversely, however,
it becomes more difficult to determine the actual monetary limit.

Further methodological progress

The "stated preference" method (SPM; Adamowicz 1994; Louviere 1994)


promises further improvements in the direct valuation process. Application
of the SPM (which was originally developed for the marketing and
transportation business) allows consumer responses to be made to a larger
range of subject characteristics than is normally possible using direct
valuation analysis.

3.1.2 Indirectly determining direct use values

The indirect or surrogate market valuation methods are all based on the fact
that the commodities "nature" or "biological resources" are consumed
together with complementary private goods with well-known or easily
determinable prices. These indirect approaches are techniques that derive
preferences from actual market-based observations. Preferences for a
biodiversity commodity can be assumed if an individual buys a product that
is somehow related to the biodiversity commodity in question. The relevant
techniques are as follows:
43
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

• the travel cost method,

• the "hedonic price" approach,

• the avertive behaviour approach and

• the dose-response method.

Surrogate market techniques focus on markets for private commodities and


services that are related to biological (or environmental) resources or
products. The products or services sold on these surrogate markets
correspond to the products/resources in question, because individuals
reveal their preferences for a biodiversity commodity by purchasing a
related object or service. "Strongly simplified: If a bird watcher spends DM
1000 on a telescope, then he is obviously willing to pay at least DM 1000
to watch birds" (Hampicke 1991, p. 115).

However, the potential of surrogate market approaches is limited for


several reasons:

• No hypothetical conclusions can be drawn. If the natural commodity is


no longer available, there will be no expenditure on the surrogate object
(in the case described above, the telescope) either.

• The method only measures the intensity of a personal interest ("user


value"), and not the interest in conserving biological diversity
("existence value").

• The relationship between private expenditure and the conservation goal


is frequently weak (e.g. telescopes may also serve other purposes).

• Experiencing nature is often non-specific; many people experience


biological diversity even in an ecologically worthless spruce forest.

44
Recommendations

Analogous limitations need to be addressed in the travel cost method. The


relationship between travel expenses and the valuation of the components
of biodiversity at the journey's destination is questionable if this journey is
undertaken for other reasons as well. Nevertheless, this method can lead to
valuable explanations about the WTP for experiencing nature, especially if
expensive and very specific destinations (e.g. a national park) have been
chosen. Past applications refer to large game parks in Africa (Brown and
Henry 1989) and tropical forest reserves in Costa Rica (Tobias and
Mendelsohn 1991), for example. In the latter study, it was shown that the
WTP of native and foreign visitors (primarily from the United States)
corresponding to a hectare of tropical forest exceeds the purchase price by
two powers of ten. In economic terms, the only possible conclusion is that
the area of the reserve should be increased. With respect to the travel cost
method, Ruck (1990, p. 261) states that, in the case of Kenya and Tanzania,
the abolition of national parks as tourist attractions would also lead to
substantial losses in seaside tourism, whereas in countries such as Sri
Lanka, India or the Ivory Coast, where tourism is largely beach or congress
tourism and national parks do not play a central role, there would be less or
no effects on the cost-benefit analyses of the tourism industry.

The dose-response approach is designed to determine relationships between


damage and its causes (e.g. pollution load); a certain load level is related to
the output change, which in turn leads to value changes on the market. This
approach, however, is only applicable to environmental changes and is
therefore not suitable for the economics of use-independent values.

3.1.3 Determining indirect use values

The methods presented in Sects. 3.1.1 and 3.1.2 to determine preferences


are not suitable to determine the direct or indirect use values (ecological

45
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

regulatory functions) of nature as production factors, since they support


economic activities regardless of preferences. In order to determine indirect
use values, other methods therefore have to be applied. However, such
methods currently still suffer from our lack of knowledge about the
functional importance of biological diversity and the ecological services
linked to them.

Indirect productivity measurements

The productivity change method can be used to determine the direct and
indirect use values of ecosystems within market prices. For instance, the
value of the ecological function of a forest in the catchment area of a
hydroelectric power plant can be measured by the net value of the
difference in water power production because of sedimentation in the
presence or absence (clearing) of forest or with a smaller (reduction) forest
stand.

A related productivity method measures the expenditure of work by a


market subject (individual, enterprise) to maintain or optimise ecological
effects (e.g. a farmer building terraces to prevent soil erosion). The
observed protective or preventive expenditure provides a measure of the
subject's valuation of the relevant ecological services (Perrings 1995,
p. 856).

The replacement cost approach focuses on the costs of replacing (e.g.


reintroduction) or restoring (e.g. reforestation) components of biological
diversity.

Avoidance and repair costs are difficult to determine, since neither


sophisticated techniques nor reliable cost levels are available for the
avoidance or repair of environmental damage. We cannot use the costs of

46
Recommendations

reducing the percentage of sulphur dioxide and nitrogen oxide in the air to
approximately zero to conclude that the value of clean air corresponds to
the level of avoidance costs. An estimation of forest degradation by acid
rain or the loss of fishery resources by water pollution on the basis of
avoidance costs, for example, will be misleading unless those concerned
are willing to bear these costs. The final report by the German Ministry of
the Environment's research programme on the "Costs of Environmental
Pollution/Benefit of Environmental Protection" puts the relevant avoidance
costs at DM 130 million p.a. (Wicke 1986).

Production-function approach

The production-function approach determines the physical effects of


changes of ecological functions on economic activities. The consequences
of these changes become visible in the change in economic yield of these
economic activities. Thus a relation between economic and ecological
productivity is produced.

In order to translate ecological into economic productivity, it is clearly


necessary to understand how regulatory ecological functions support
economic activities, and this is still the limiting factor. This becomes even
more difficult where the causes (e.g. the functional role of individual
species) of ecological functions have to be understood in greater detail. It is
highly desirable both from an economic and an ecological point of view to
promote this understanding.

Our lack of understanding of the ecological causes of economic


productivity should not prevent production-function valuations from being
carried out using existing knowledge. On the basis of different assumptions
about causal links between ecological and economic factors, Ruitenbeek

47
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

(1992), for instance, has carried out valuations in different scenarios. The
results of these valuation approaches are given in Sect. 2.3.

The marketable yield Q is formally represented as being dependent on a set


of factors: Q = F(Xi ... Xk, S). [In the study by Ellis and Fisher (1987) on
the effect of wetlands on the crab harvest, QS is the area of the wetlands in
question.]

3.2 The cost aspect of the conservation and destruction of


biological diversity and the cost-benefit analysis
procedure
The preceding sections have dealt with the type and range of economic use
values of biological resources and the methods used to determine them.
This section discusses the costs associated with the conservation,
sustainable use and restoration of biological diversity in order to balance
these costs with their social and economic benefits. If biological resources
for conservation, sustainable use or restoration can be treated as scarce
resources and valued accordingly, they can be balanced against alternative
uses. The forgone opportunities are referred to as opportunity costs. On the
basis of cost-benefit analyses (see below), the relevant activities and their
alternatives can ultimately be determined and evaluated in monetary terms.

3.2.1 Opportunity costs: restoration costs, sustainability costs, lost use


values

How much does it cost not to destroy nature? Since the pioneering work by
Krutilla and Fisher (1975), this question has been addressed by a number of
studies. Approaches such as that used by Bishop (1980) to estimate
conservation costs for individual species are still rare; other studies deal

48
Recommendations

with the opportunity costs of area requirements for nature conservation.


The starting point of this kind of research was the work carried out by
Goldstein (1971), who compared two alternative uses of areas in the
Midwest of the United States. Retaining the area as an adventure range for
WTP bird hunters instead of intensifying its agricultural uses proved to be
economically more favourable.

Some studies, such as the ones by Turner et al. (1983) and Krutilla and
Fisher (1975), have established that maintaining a natural condition does
not cause economic costs, because large investment planning has proved to
be unprofitable. A study by Willis et al. (1988) elucidates the difference
between land use costs if distorted prices support a use that destroys nature
while lower opportunity costs are arrived at by correct calculations.

The TEV approach should be used as the basis on which to calculate


opportunity costs. Use-dependent and use-independent values have to be
taken into account, and market price-based and market price-independent
methods should be examined to valuate them. In 1989, the U.S. Court of
Appeals ruled that the procedural guidelines of the U.S. Ministry of the
Interior for the monetary valuation of environmental damage should be
revised (Marggraf and Streb 1997, p. 17). However, this court decision has
not yet been implemented, although a second ruling that environmental
damage should be valuated on the basis of the sum of restoration costs and
forgone use options has now been put into practice.

At this point, it would seem appropriate to step aside for a moment and
consider the actual and potential market values of the (minimum) goals and
costs of biodiversity. What are the ecological and biodiversity standards
that should be aimed at from a scientific point of view? And how can they

49
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

be translated into global and national economic units to make their


economic superiority visible?

"The progressive destruction of nature in many developing countries calls


for an answer to the question of the number, size and geographical location
of national parks that might be regarded as economically optimal within a
given time frame for a country or for human civilisation" (Ruck 1990,
p. 365), where "national park" is used as a synonym for protected,
sustainably used or restored ecosystems/biodiversity. Ruck (pp. 365ff.)
presents ways to arrive at economic responses to this question.

"Market prices for products and factors partly reflect material scarcity and
thus opportunity costs, but they are usually distorted by transfer
components, and corrections therefore need to be made for calculations of
economic costs. A distinction should always be made between dynamic and
static sets of costs, and each has to be incorporated in the other" (Hampicke
1991, p. 180). Funds for the conservation of biological diversity should
always be spent according to defined priorities and as efficiently as
possible: certain goals can either be attained at minimum costs, or the
degree to which a given goal is realised should be maximised at a given
cost. The practical cost categories for the conservation of biological
diversity can be divided into investment, work and land use costs, and each
poses specific problems. A number of studies that have been undertaken
world-wide concerning conflicts of various sizes show that opportunity
costs for the conservation of biological diversity are often far lower than
expected. In those federal states that belonged to West Germany before
German reunification, for example, DM 1 billion would be sufficient to
implement a thorough nature protection programme.

50
Recommendations

Wells (1992) compared the costs and benefits of protected areas at the
local, regional and global level, qualitatively estimating the distribution of
costs and benefits on these different levels. His estimation of the benefit of
protected areas was based on the work of Dixon and Sherman (1990; cited
in Wells 1992). It was shown that the economic benefits of protected areas
are limited at a local level, are somewhat higher at regional and national
levels and become substantial at a global level. The related costs follow the
opposite trend: They are significant at a local level, moderate at a regional
and national level and small at a global level (e.g. contributions to
multilateral financing mechanisms, cf. Fig. 4).

Wells (1992) concluded that to ensure that biodiversity is effectively


protected, this imbalance needs to be corrected by:

• North-South money transfers and

• an increase in profits at both a local and a regional and national level,


e.g. by the expansion of sustainable use strategies.

In order for local communities to actually profit from sustainable uses,


however, further socio-economic and legal conditions have to be fulfilled
on a national and regional level. These concern aspects such as land tenure
rights, property rights to biological diversity and the promotion of rural
development.

51
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

Fig. 4: Comparison of the resulting costs and use of protected areas

Potentially significant benefits Potentially significant costs


LOCAL LEVEL
Consumption benefit Indirect costs (e.g. damage by grazing)
Recreation/tourism Opportunity costs (e.g. by restriction of
use)
Future values
REGIONAL/NATIONAL LEVEL
Recreation/tourism Direct costs (establishment of protected
areas)
Water drainage areas Opportunity costs
Future values
GLOBAL LEVEL
Biological diversity (Minimum costs)
Non-consumption use
Ecological processes
Environmental education and research
Future values

3.2.2 Cost-benefit analysis

Cost-benefit analyses (CBAs) allow biodiversity-relevant activities and


their alternatives to be evaluated and expressed in monetary terms. In order
to be able to compare the costs and benefits of alternative uses, the
following procedure should be followed:

1. All the consequences of a relevant action should be identified (e.g. use,


alternative use, change in the status quo of biodiversity).

2. The present private benefits PV[B(DEV)] and costs PV[C(DEV)]


associated with the individual action taken should be determined and the
difference between them calculated: PV[B(DEV)] - PV[C(DEV)].

3. Depending on the relevant integration level, the present local, national,


global or total (TEVtot = TEVg + TEVn + TEVl) social benefit
52
Recommendations

PV[TEV(SUB)] of the alternative use (e.g. conservation, sustainable


use) should be calculated; its social costs PV[C(SUB)] are then
subtracted.

4. If the difference PV[TEV(SUB) - C(SUB)] is larger than the difference


PV[B(DEV) - C(DEV)], then the social use alternative is the
economically relevant one. It will also be politically relevant whether
the private user is able to participate in the social global, national and/or
local yields.

If the costs and benefits of an action are to be calculated without


considering an alternative scenario, step 2 should be omitted. The action
concerned will then be economically reasonable if the valued benefit
exceeds the respective costs. Since the cost-benefit analysis requires
national and international costs and benefits to be identified and quantified
as comprehensively as possible, it also includes individual cost and benefit
aspects (e.g. external effects), even if these are not economically apparent.

3.3 Organisation of markets with appropriate prices


In the preceding sections, the causes of market failure were explained in
terms of the valuation or rather the lack of valuation of biological diversity.
In addition, techniques were described with which the actual value of the
components of biological diversity can be determined (TEVs at a local,
national and global level, etc.). The critical question is now how these
theoretical insights and methods can have a practical impact on markets
and prices and how the external costs and benefits of biological resources
can become visible on the markets and in market prices.

53
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

3.3.1 Monetisation and cost-benefit analyses

In order for market prices to approximate the "real" value of the


components of biological diversity and/or for efficient market price-
relevant decisions to be made, it is first necessary to gather all the available
information about the value of biodiversity commodities. The first step
from theory to practice therefore has to be to apply the valuation techniques
described in Sect. 3.1 and the cost-benefit analyses presented in Sect. 3.2.
Barbier et al. (1994) draw some important conclusions from the
investigation of Mantadia National Park for the practical relevance of cost-
benefit analyses (Munasinghe 1993):

• Firstly, valuation techniques have to be adapted to the local situation; in


the specific case concerned, the currency "rice" was used to value the
economic advantages of forests.

• Secondly, by carefully selecting and applying valuation techniques in


relevant situations, useful indications can be obtained of the values that
would be impaired by the selected land use alternative. It is important to
realise what is actually measured by the particular valuation method
used, e.g. direct use effects, net proceeds from direct and indirect use
effects, etc., and to have a clear idea of the reliability of data and
methods for the evaluation of the respective advantages.

• Thirdly, it also needs to be clarified what was not measured by the study
in question, on which level of the hierarchy the study was conducted
and whether the TEV or only elements thereof were determined.

Only with such specifically adapted instruments and the initial knowledge
they provide about the "real" economic value of the biological resources
and their use can the following central issue be addressed: What are the

54
Recommendations

mechanisms that transform the socio-economic values that have been


determined into monetary reality on the market?

Four such mechanisms will be discussed below:

1. the removal of damaging distortions of market mechanisms


(deregulation) by dismantling failed interventions (Sect. 3.3.2),

2. the creation of markets by privatisation and integrated biodiversity


management (Sect. 3.3.3),

3. market-induced control systems (Sect. 3.3.4.) and

4. the creation of global biodiversity markets (Sect. 3.3.5).

3.3.2 Dismantling failed interventions

Governments generally tend to intervene in markets. This may be done


with the best intentions. However, even though some interventions may use
price corrections to adjust external effects that are damaging to
biodiversity, many interventions run counter to the goals of protection
biodiversity, even if they serve other important purposes. Well-known
examples of such intervention prices are deforestation subsidies, water
prices that are too low, subsidisation of agriculture, etc. Such measures are
referred to as perverse incentives, i.e. incentives that lead to a decrease in
biological diversity, and are the result of policy failure. The most perverse
incentives are those that have been created to promote goals that destroy
biodiversity (OECD 1996, p. 70).

An important step towards achieving prices that reflect social costs is


therefore to abolish any supportive measures that artificially reduce the
private costs of actions that are detrimental to biodiversity. The OECD
(1998) has very recently undertaken a study of this problem, which will be
55
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

referred to later. One way of correcting the price distortions caused by price
controls or national monopolies is to take internationally valid competitive
market prices as "shadow" prices (Ruck 1990, p. 220).

3.3.3 Creation of private property rights and integrated biodiversity


management

In an ideal free market, the market develops on its own such that private
use interests work to support social interests and correcting measures are
kept to a minimum. In order to at least come close to this ideal, private
users have be able to profit from the national or global yields of the
conservation and/or sustainable use of biodiversity. This could be achieved
by creating vested titles to those biological resources to which vested titles
do not yet exist and/or by transferring property rights from the State to
landowners (including those who should be entitled to such rights due to
pending land reforms).

This approach would be the logical consequence of the "national


sovereignty regime" over genetic resources that was created by the CBD to
replace the former "free access regime" to shift it at the local level. It would
meet the efficiency criterion that those who control net assets should also
be those who profit from the utilisable effects of these net assets. If a local
community cannot draw net use from its investment (the sustainable use of
ecosystems/components of biodiversity), it will not have an interest in
maintaining its investment (Pearce and Moran 1994, p. 144).

Persson (1994) was able to show that the transferral of vested titles to
squatters causes them to stop clearing, in particular if discounting is lower
than the future value of the forest. These property rights could further be
licensed, e.g. as bioprospecting ratios, visitor ratios, harvest ratios,
emission rights, development rights, etc.
56
Recommendations

With respect to genes, species and ecosystems as levels in the biodiversity


hierarchy, property rights will probably refer to the ecosystem level. It
would be advisable for transferred vested titles not to be restricted to single
uses, but to be open for the whole range of use options, e.g. tourism,
bioprospecting, hunting, renewable resources, etc. For a comprehensive
bioprospecting strategy could ensure conservation effects for the specific
resource in situ; moreover, it may also generate conservation effects for
other resources in the same habitat that are not yet being sought or
commercially exploited.

This presupposes that a bioprospecting strategy will be open in terms of the


species, genes and biomolecules it is looking for. A broader screening
policy for commercially useful resources means that the quasi-option value
of the resources that are not yet being screened for can create preservation
effects for the whole ecosystem more effectively. If prospecting is more
specific (species xy, effect ab), a holistic protective effect becomes less
likely, particularly if shortages or losses may result from subsequent
exploitation of the resources being sought. The status of the components of
biodiversity concerned should therefore be monitored by means of pre- and
post-prospecting programmes.

Bioprospecting opens up new sources of income for developing countries.


Instead of having to ask for new technologies and transfer payments from
the North, these countries may be able to offer "genetic technology" in the
form of raw materials, plant-based medicines, etc. (Krattiger and Lesser
1994). For a more lasting success in bioprospecting strategies, it would also
be helpful to transfer an increasing amount of relevant biotechnological
know-how ("capacity-building") to the area from which bioresources
originate to enable further processed resources to be marketed not only
globally, but also regionally.

57
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

The same is true of ecotourism; multiple attractions can increase the


duration of usability, but here, too, monitoring programmes should be
implemented to register any side-effects, and benefits were to be shared
with the local communities concerned.

3.3.4 Creation of market-based regulatory instruments

Many regulatory instruments are available to bridge the gap between TEVs
and current market prices on the national market. The main distinction is
between regulatory and market-based instruments. While regulatory
instruments imply the direct control (reduction/limitation) of unwanted
actions in conjunction with legislative or politically agreed standards,
market-based instruments create economic incentives. "It is no accident
that 'command and control' concepts have dominated environmental policy
so far world-wide. The reasons for this are the sectoral organisation and
splintering of national competences, the minor political importance of
national environmental institutions and, last but not least, the insufficient
integration of environmental policy into public discussion in many
countries" (Paulus 1995).

Economic incentive systems can be subdivided into four categories:

1. Positive incentives: any monetary (direct payment, cost-sharing, tax


advantages) or non-monetary inducement (such as awards in recognition
of outstanding performance) that motivates individuals or groups
(governments, international organisations, local communities) to
conserve biological diversity.

2. Disincentives: any mechanism that internalises the costs of use and/or


damage of biological resources in order to discourage activities that
deplete biological diversity.

58
Recommendations

3. Indirect incentives: any mechanism that creates or improves upon


markets and price signals for biological resources, encouraging the
conservation and sustainable use of biological diversity.

4. Perverse incentives: an incentive that induces behaviour leading to a


reduction in biological diversity. Perverse incentives are the result of
failed government intervention. Most perverse incentives are designed to
achieve other policy objectives and their "perversity" is thus an external
factor or an unanticipated side-effect of the policy (OECD 1996, p. 70).

If the results of economic valuations of biological resources do not lead to


reformed or newly created markets, the economic value of biological
resources can only be asserted by intervention. The notion that the market
is basically flexible enough, with only occasional State subsidies required,
is only a qualitative one. "By no means can it be concluded that economic
adjustment processes and government incentives are implemented in time
and to a sufficient extent to avoid the catastrophic consequences of
resource shortages" (Endres and Querner 1993; on market failure, see
pp. 124ff.).

However, despite the shortcomings of the market mechanism outlined


above in reflecting the TEV of the relevant components of biological
diversity, the capacity of the market to contribute to solving the problem of
the destruction of biodiversity should not be underestimated. As only
incomplete allocation mechanisms currently exist, it is not certain how the
market can contribute to the conservation of natural resources in pragmatic
terms (Endres and Querner 1993, p. 139).

In order to optimise the quality of an allocation mechanism, free market


economy intervention instruments (MEIs) should be used. Examples of
such mechanisms include environment-related fees, a price strategy with

59
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

resources and inputs, duties and taxes, subsidies, environmental funds,


tradable rights and licences, flexible levies, pledge systems, etc. (Paulus
1995).

Strictly speaking, MEIs include all political measures explicitly related to


private costs and benefits by which the comparative social costs and
benefits can be incorporated into market prices. These MEIs can be
subdivided into five categories:

1. charges, taxes, fees or additional prices to be paid for the social costs
arising from damage,

2. subsidies to assist individuals in altering activities or conforming to


environmental standards,

3. deposit/refund or fee/rebate systems in which a surcharge is levied on the


price of products leading to resource depletion which is then refunded if
the product is recycled or if the depleted resource is restored,

4. tradable permits by which rights to exploit resources can be exchanged


and

5. compensatory incentives to create markets or financial inducements for


certain individuals or groups who bear a disproportionate share of the
risks or costs of the conservation of biological resources (Barbier et al.
1994, p. 180).

MEIs, however, entail a considerable amount of administrative and/or


monitoring expenditure. It is therefore important to examine carefully, as
Paulus (1995) does, the institutional conditions and to integrate measures
into existing structures wherever possible. The following criteria need to be
taken into account when selecting measures: ecological effectiveness,

60
Recommendations

economic efficiency, administrative management, public costs and yields,


distribution effects and interspersing ability.

No single MEI instrument will be sufficient to counter specific threats to


biological diversity, and a range of MEIs will be necessary to address the
complex problems of the social costs of conservation, sustainable use and
restoration of biological diversity.

In principle, the groups that damage biological resources should bear the
damage prevention costs and/or the social costs connected with the
damage. Otherwise, those who use biological resources would have to bear
the entire costs of using resources, including the costs of control and
prevention. Conversely, the incremental costs connected with the
mobilisation of non-marketed uses should be offset by the utilisation of
positive incentive systems. The latter could be implemented using market-
based control instruments, as clearly shown by Lippke (1996, p. 253).

3.3.5 Creation of global markets

As mentioned several times in the preceding sections, many conservation


and/or sustainable use approaches produce global benefits. The
conservation of biological diversity in a tropical rain forest may benefit
individuals and groups in other countries, e.g. because they profit from its
renewable resources, because its biogeochemical cycles have global
benefits or because they want it to exist for its own sake.

However, if the country that owns the resources cannot derive monetary
benefit from these global external use values due to a lack of appropriate
markets, it will have no or little incentive to conserve the biological
resources in question.

61
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

It is therefore necessary to create global markets (GEMs). These markets


can be enforced by international law or may result from voluntary
agreements. Examples of the latter include debt-for-nature swaps or
benefit-sharing agreements, as concluded by Merck & Co., Shaman
Pharmaceuticals, Biotics Ltd. and others with the owners of bioresources.
Regulation-induced markets have gained attention in the context of the
Climate Convention, e.g. the intergovernmental agreement on CO2
reduction between Norway, Poland and Mexico concluded via the Global
Environmental Facility (GEF) or the afforestation agreements entered into
by various U.S. energy companies.

Both approaches - regulation-induced and voluntary agreements - have a


common feature: bilateral or multilateral transfer payments. Indeed, in the
foreseeable future, well-organised and specific financial transfer services
will be indispensable. The particular practical relevance of monetisation
approaches for the conservation, sustainable use and restoration costs of
biological diversity lies in the fact that these approaches will form the basis
of assessment for the budgets of national and international measures for the
protection of biological diversity. This is especially relevant for the
implementation of the CBD with regard to international financing
instruments such as the GEF and biodiversity portfolios of the World Bank,
the Development Bank of the United Nations and continental development
banks. The concept of "incremental costs" in the realisation of the CBD and
the conservation of biological diversity may be helpful in this respect.
Exactly what is covered by the term "full incremental costs" in accordance
with Art. 20 of the CBD is still the subject of detailed discussion. A
definition of the scope of this term, however, is urgently needed, since it
determines which elements of biodiversity-relevant projects may be

62
Recommendations

covered as "incremental costs" by the financial mechanisms of the


CBD/GEF.

For a definition of incremental costs, the (then still interim) secretariat of


the CBD listed several items to justify transfer payments in the light of the
CBD; however, these also suggest that a complicated bureaucracy will need
to be established (UNEP/CBD/IC/2/17 of 25 April 1994). It might be more
appropriate to restrict net incremental costs to the CBD aims of
conservation and sustainable use (global externalities of biodiversity loss),
because to achieve the third aim, the sharing of benefits and not
incremental costs would have to be refunded, but yields would have to be
divided. According to Glowka et al. (1994), incremental costs could be
defined in a simplified form as those costs that are necessary to conserve,
use sustainably or restore the components of biodiversity defined by quality
goals (if necessary, minus the immediate yields from the direct sustainable
use of biodiversity and benefit-sharing), whereby the extent of the specific
financial expenditure should be based on non-use-related monetary values.

The International Conservation Financing Project of the World Resources


Institute has attempted to calculate the annual funds necessary for the
conservation of biological resources and estimates a total of $20-50 million
per year (Reid and Miller 1989). The conservation for 20 years of 2000
animal species with 500 individuals each costs approximately $25 billion
alone, as much as the first landing by man on the moon. The traditional
conservation of tropical rain forests is estimated to cost $170 million per
year for at least 5 years.

In order to develop a ranking order for transfer payments, a cost-efficiency


index for biodiversity projects has been developed (see the Second Global
Biodiversity Forum, Nassau 1994):

63
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

• a suitable indicator of the benefits of biodiversity or of biological


significance: data at a national level on species diversity and endemism
(per km2) may be used to represent the benefits gained by the
conservation activity concerned;

• cost of intervention: represented by the amount of investment (per km2)


in conservation measures at a national level;

• probability of success (willingness to conserve): the percentage of land


area defined as protected area is used to assess the probability of
success;

• degree of threat: deforestation rates and population growth are used to


approximate the level of threat.

It should be remembered that it is not sufficient to guarantee the return of


profit shares to the countries owning the resources. Instead, financial
compensation for the use or exploitation of biological diversity must
benefit those groups (e.g. local communities, conservation organisations,
national park administrations) that directly protect and sustainably use
biodiversity. However, this presupposes a whole range of institutional,
organisational and legal conditions, including procedures to ensure the
predictability and reliability of the distribution of transfer funds as
equivalents for economic values.

A number of financing instruments (e.g. an international rain forest fund,


resource franchise agreements) are being discussed to ascertain strategic
international payments. Because of their free market nature, transferable
development rights (TDRs) appear to be particularly promising to allow
adequate conservation of global biodiversity values in tropical countries.

64
Recommendations

The first step towards establishing TDRs for the conservation of biological
diversity would be to differentiate between conservation and development
areas. Individuals owning land in the conservation areas would also receive
TDRs, but would not be allowed to implement these rights within the
conservation areas. Instead, they could sell these vested titles in
development areas in which there is assumed to be a high demand for
limited development rights. Full compensation should thus result for the
owners of the conservation areas by the sales of development rights.

Such a market for TDRs could develop internationally. Tropical countries


could exclude areas of authentic ecosystems from alternative use and offer
TDRs locally and internationally at prices that cover their opportunity costs
(current net value of the forgone development alternative; for further
discussion, see Panayotou 1994). To a certain extent, a TDR system
already exists in the form of the debt-for-nature swaps. The essential
element of these agreements is the transfer of development rights for
conservation areas to international non-governmental organisations
(NGOs) in exchange for assuming part of the national debts of the
countries concerned. However, the extent of these rights is usually not
correlated with the opportunity costs.

3.4 Recommendations for development cooperation


The example of valuation techniques highlights the fundamental dilemma
of environmental economics, i.e. the need to proceed from generalisations
to formulate operational recommendations for action. The economic
analyses in many case studies are fairly convincing, but their scientific
theory is often still not translated into practice. Development co-operation
is required in order to develop operational concepts and to implement them
in pilot projects. The key concepts in this context are the acquisition of

65
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

knowledge about specific costs and benefits, training and capacity-


building.

3.4.1 Project-oriented cost-benefit analyses using the available


valuation instruments

The most obvious measure might be to introduce biodiversity valuation


techniques and comprehensive cost-benefit analyses in project planning
and to create project-oriented cost-benefit analyses (as a continuation of
project environmental-impact assessments, EIAs) as a basis on which to
determine project-related TEVs. This would require the development of
appropriate training programmes and guidelines for those responsible for
the projects in Germany and in the partner country, which should initially
be conducted in a pilot phase for selected projects. When developing such
programmes and guidelines, care should be taken to ensure that the
necessary standardisation still allows sufficient scope for the individual
project conditions and the practical adaptation of the relevant procedures
(e.g. CVM).

3.4.2 Training and capacity-building to inventor and monitor


biodiversity

In order to carry out economic valuations of the components of biological


diversity under reasonable conditions, the component to be valuated must
be adequately characterised, i.e. inventories of the components of
biological diversity concerned should be made on the relevant hierarchy
and integration levels (e.g. genes, species, ecosystems); in the follow-up,
these inventories also need to be reviewed using monitoring and
assessment programmes. There is now an extensive body of literature (e.g.
Stork and Samways 1995; Guarino et al. 1995) on the implementation of

66
Recommendations

such programmes, and this issue will not be addressed in detail here.
Particular attention should be paid to rapid biodiversity assessment
techniques (discussed in the literature) and to close cooperation between
experts and parataxonomists, as has been documented particularly clearly
for the Instituto de la Biodiversidad (INBio) in Costa Rica. DC is required
to support and to participate in biodiversity inventories in the partner
countries by means of suitable training courses and infrastructure measures.

3.4.3 Creation and/or strengthening of institutional prerequisites for


the development and implementation of national biodiversity
strategies

In this context, it is necessary to support the national and regional


authorities responsible for the conservation and sustainable use of
biological diversity in diverse areas, to help integrate biodiversity
conservation strategies in the planning of land use and to support
cooperation among the organisations involved (government authorities,
local authorities, environmental and development organisations, social
movements, development cooperation institutions). DC can contribute to
this process, e.g. by providing consultancy services. A possible form of
support is to ensure that yields from the use of genetic resources are
proportionately supplied to protected areas. At the same time, legislation
must be examined and amended to ensure its compatibility with
conservation and development goals.

3.4.4 Training and capacity-building to conduct cost-benefit analyses


and valuation techniques

Not only should project planning be carried out in donor countries (cf.
Sect. 3.4.1), but the know-how for the application of valuation techniques

67
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

and the implementation of cost-benefit analyses should also be transferred


to the recipient countries by means of DC in association with the capacities
to be built and developed in order to catalogue biodiversity. DC should
organise project-related (advanced) training courses and consult the
relevant institutions of the partner country. At the same time, legislation
should be examined and amended in the light of the relevant methods and
techniques, as done for the relevant American DOI guidelines, for example.

3.4.5 Supporting research capacities in developing countries at the


frontier between ecology and economics

Due to the rising demand for genetic resources, resulting in increased


bioprospecting activity in tropical forests, for example, national inventory
programmes on biological diversity and ecosystem research need to be
supported in order to set up sustainable utilisation strategies. An
international fund should provide support in capacity-building to inventory
biological diversity, to document and analyse samples and to exchange
information. Free access to information and the participation of local
communities need to be ensured. Experience at institutions such as the
Costa Rican Instituto de la Biodiversidad (INBio) suggest that we should
be thinking about models for other countries above and beyond this Costa
Rican approach.

The research and technology capacity of developing countries can be


supported by private initiatives; however, due to the size of these tasks, this
alone will not be sufficient and supplementary efforts will be necessary. In
close cooperation with partner institutions in the tropical countries, foreign
research institutions should contribute to the complex field of basic
research in the rain forests. In this context, it should be ensured that
research results are accessible to all those involved, that emphasis is placed

68
Recommendations

on building national research capacities and that research results are put
into practice by means of environmental education.

One extremely important area in which DC is required is undoubtedly the


establishment and promotion of modern biodiversity research in partner
countries, in particular the creation of a sound modern taxonomy, as this
forms the basis of all other fields of biodiversity research. "Taxonomy is
fundamental in providing the units and the pattern to humankind's notion of
species diversity" (Bisby 1995). As Hubert Markl puts it, "It has to be
clearly stated: Without the active contribution of lively and productive
biotaxonomic research - above all organism inventories of the tropics and
subtropics and the seas of all latitudes - it will be impossible to gain the
ecological insights that are necessary for the global management of the
biosphere (a profitable form of management to our benefit, e.g. self-
restraint in relation to natural communities) in such a way that mankind and
nature will be able to live together on a long-term basis, something our
future depends on. (...) As an infrastructure-related task of biodiversity
research, however, this reflects only part of the particular scientific value of
biotaxonomic research. Is it not the sophisticated differentiation of life
forms that forms the indispensable prerequisite for our astonishment and
enthusiasm for all kinds of organisms more than anything else: their
marvellous ability to adapt to their environment, their skilful methods of
conquering ecological niches, their inexhaustible wealth of original
solutions for all of life's problems from the procurement of food in
competition with their own and other species, the avoidance of enemies, the
fight against parasites and, finally, the development of supra-organismal
social systems whose abilities to learn and adapt seem to know no limits
even in animals, let alone in humans? We would not be able to carry out
research on any of this without the clear distinctions identified by

69
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

taxonomic research that provide the basis for our comparative analyses"
(Markl 1995).

Important tasks for the future include developing a modern taxonomy as an


integral science combining both classical and molecular methods (see
Bisby 1995) and training methodically (classical/molecular) holistic
taxonomists who also have a particular expertise in data processing using
information technology. It should be added that taxonomy will also become
increasingly significant as an infrastructure for biotechnology. In the
context of bioprospecting, biodiversity conservationists have pinned their
hopes on strategies of participative use for biotechnologically exploitable
natural substances for the in situ preservation of biological diversity. DC
should therefore also take account of research into chemical ecology and
natural products, including the industrial, sociological and economic
aspects of biodiversity. Where possible, appropriate DC projects should be
integrated into international scientific biodiversity initiatives such as
DIVERSITAS, BioNET International or Species 2000.

A further key area of biodiversity research for DC is the area of


biodiversity economics. In recent years, not least as a result of discussions
on the CBD, this subdiscipline of environmental economics has undergone
rapid development, and there have been a number of publications focusing
on valuation studies of biological resources. Interdisciplinary coordinated
research efforts are still largely lacking, however.

3.4.6 Identification of interventions failures

In order to come closer to the goal of having prices that reflect social costs,
it is necessary both to eliminate subsidies that artificially lower private
costs and to implement suitable economic instruments or other regulatory
measures to ensure that harmful external effects are taken into account in
70
Recommendations

price setting. As part of DC, consultancy services are required in this


context to support the dismantling of misdirected economic instruments on
the basis of TEVs and cost-benefit analyses; in addition, approval for
biodiversity project funding needs to be linked to the removal of any
disincentives counterproductive to the aim of the project.

3.4.7 Creation of incentive instruments

Consumption and non-consumption values of biological diversity are only


partially reflected in market prices. An overall economic calculation should
also consider ecological follow-up costs. Subsidising non-sustainable uses
sends the wrong politico-economic signals and frequently causes the
exploitation of natural resources. Within the framework of project
cooperation, DC should therefore recommend that more attention be paid to
economic incentives for the conservation of biological diversity together
with the abolition of subsidies for ecologically harmful land uses.

By means of consultancy services, national governments and authorities


should be encouraged to use and test economic instruments able to generate
market prices that approximate previously determined TEVs.

3.4.8 Participation of local communities in biodiversity yields

Successful work on a project requires the appropriate participation of local


communities in decision-making processes and the identification of
problems in project planning, implementation, and monitoring and
evaluation. Decision-making processes concerning the organisation of the
project should be made as transparent as possible and should include
objection options for the local communities concerned.

71
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

The effectiveness of economic incentives for local communities has not


been sufficiently considered so far. Bioprospecting and the gathering of
biological resources by national organisations offer the opportunity for fair
and equitable participation by local communities, and benefit-sharing
arrangements should be made at the beginning of a project. Private
initiatives that take account of such participation should be supported by
government authorities.

3.4.9 Assistance in the creation of property rights

The property rights of local communities need to be strengthened and


secured. This includes examining land tenure structures and strengthening
the rights of indigenous peoples and traditional communities to their
cultural identity and the collective intellectual property of their traditional
knowledge.

While industrial innovations and newly developed products enjoy the


protection of legally enforced intellectual property rights at an international
level, e.g. patent rights (recently internationally strengthened by the GATT
agreement), the collective intellectual property of traditional local
communities and indigenous peoples is not internationally recognised. If
the wealth of experience and valuable knowledge of this part of humanity
is to be used in a fair and equitable way for the management and
sustainable use of biological resources, these rights need to be
strengthened.

Action particularly needs to be taken in the following areas:

• in the evaluation of land tenure systems to support sustainable


management practices and the transfer of vested titles to biological
diversity (keyword: privatisation),

72
Recommendations

• in the establishment of legal instruments to protect the collective


intellectual property of indigenous peoples and traditional local
communities and

• in the examination of the influence that international rules such as the


GATT and TRIPS agreements (strengthening of patent rights) might
have on the availability of environmentally acceptable technologies in
developing countries and the socio-economic and ecological effects that
they may have on the lives of small farmers and indigenous peoples.

3.4.10 Cooperation in establishing global environmental markets


through bilateral and multilateral agreements

As in the implementation of the Climate Convention (with the goal of a


reduction in the emission of CO2), where both bilateral and multilateral
conventions and agreements under public and private law have been made,
similar agreements should be made with the specific goal of biodiversity
conservation. As example that might be mentioned here is the U.S. Forest
for the Future Initiative. The participation and motivation of the private
sector should also be sought in such bilateral or multilateral agreements on
biodiversity.

73
Bibliography

4 Bibliography

4.1 Cited references


ADAMOWICZ, W. 1994 Stated preference methods for environmental
valuation. Paper presented at the Agricultural Economics Society
Annual Conference, University of Exeter.

ARROW, K.J. 1993 Report of the NOAA panel on contingent valuation.


US Federal Register 58(10):4602-4614.

AYLWARD, B.A. 1993 The economic value of pharmaceutical


prospecting and its role in biodiversity conservation. LEEC
Discussion Paper 93-05. International Institute for Environment and
Development, London.

BARBIER, E., ADAMS, W., KIMMAGE, K. 1991 Economic valuation of


wetland benefits: The Hadejiia-Jama'are floodplain, Nigeria. London
Environmental Economics Centre, Paper 91-02, London.

BARBIER, E.B., BURGESS, J.C., FOLKE, C. 1994 Paradise lost? The


ecological economics of biodiversity. Earthscan, London.

BARBIER, E.B., BURGESS, J.C., SWANSON, T., PEARCE, D.W. 1990


Elephants, economics and ivory. Earthscan, London.

BARNES, J. & PEARCE, D.W. 1991 The mixed use of habitat. Centre for
Social and Economic Research on the Global Environment, London.

BISBY, F.A. 1995 Characterization of biodiversity. In: Heywood, V. &


Watson, R. (eds.): Global biodiversity assessment, 21-106,
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

BISHOP, R.C. 1980 Endangered species: an economic perspective.


Transactions of the 45th North American Wildlife and Natural
Resources Conference, Wildlife Management Institute, Washington
D.C., 208-218.

75
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

BLAMEY, R.K. 1996 Citizens, consumers and contingent valuation:


Clarification and the expression of citizen values and issue-opinions.
In: Adamowicz, W.L., Boxall, P.C., Luckert, M.K., Phillips, W.E.,
White, W.A. (eds.): Forestry, economics and the environment. CAB
International, Guildford.

BLAMEY, R. & COMMON, M. 1993 Stepping back from contingent


valuation. Centre for Resource and Environmental Studies,
Australian National University, Canberra.

BOWES, M.D. & KRUTILLA, J.V. 1989 Multiple-use management: The


economics of public forestlands. Resources for the Future, Washington,
D.C.

BROWN, G.M. 1990 Valuation of genetic resources. In: Orians, G.H.,


Brown, G.M., Kunin, W.E., Swierbinski, J.E. (eds.): The
preservation and valuation of biological resources, 203-228.
University of Washington Press, Seattle.

BROWN, G.M., LAYTON, D., LAZO, J. 1994 Valuing habitat and


endangered species. Discussion Paper 94-1 (January). Institute for
Economic Research, University of Washington.

BROWN, G. & HENRY, W. 1989 The economic value of elephants.


LEEC Discussion Paper 89-12, London Environmental Economics
Centre.

BURRILL, G.S. & LEE, K.B. 1992 Biotech 93: Accelerating


commercialization: An industry annual report 1.

CASTRO, R. 1994 The economic opportunity cost of wildlands


conservation areas (EOCWCAs): the case of Costa Rica. Harvard
University, Mass.

CHILD, B. 1990 Economic analysis of buffalo range ranch. In: Kiss, A.


(ed.): Living with wildlife resource management with local
participation in Africa. World Bank, Washington D.C., 155-176.

76
Bibliography

DIXON, J.A. & SHERMAN, P.B. 1990 Economics of protected areas, a


new look at the benefits and costs. Earthscan, London.

DOWNES, D.R. 1993 New diplomacy for the biodiversity trade:


Biodiversity, biotechnology and intellectual property in the Convention
on Biological Diversity. Draft. Washington D.C.

ELLIS, G.M. & FISHER, A.C. 1987 Valuing the environment as input.
Journal of Environmental Management 25:149-156.

ENDRES, A. & QUERNER, I. 1993 Die Ökonomie natürlicher


Ressourcen. Wissenschaftliche Buchgesellschaft, Darmstadt.

FARNSWORTH, N.R. & SOEJARTO, D.D. 1985 Potential consequences


of plant extinction in the United States on the current and future
availability of prescription drugs. Economic Botany 39 (3):231-240.

GLOWKA, L., BURHENNE-GUILMIN, F., SYNGE, H., MCNEELY,


J.A., GÜNDLING, L. 1994 A guide to the Convention on Biological
Diversity. Environmental Policy and Law Paper no. 30, IUCN,
Cambridge.

GOLDSTEIN, J.H. 1971 Competition for wetlands in the midwest: An


economic analysis. Johns Hopkins University Press for Resources for
the Future, Baltimore - London.

GUARINO, L., RAMATHA RAO, V., REID, R. 1995 Collecting plant


genetic diversity. CAB International, Wallingford and University
Press, Cambridge

HAMPICKE, U. 1991 Naturschutz-Ökonomie. Ulmer Verlag, Stuttgart.

HARTWICK, J.M. 1977 Intergenerational equity and the investing of rents


from exhaustible resources. American Economic Review 66:972-
974.

IMMLER, H. 1993 Welche Wirtschaft braucht die Natur? Frankfurt a.M.

77
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

IMMLER, H. 1989 Vom Wert der Natur. Zur ökologischen Reform von
Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft. Natur in der ökonomischen Theorie,
Teil 3. Westdeutscher Verlag, Opladen.

KAOSARD, M. et al. 1994 Green Finance: A case study of Khao Yai.


Final report for the Natural Resources and Environment Program,
Thailand Develeopment Research Institute and Harvard Institute for
International Development.

KRAMER, R. et al. 1993 Valuing a protected tropical forest: A case study


of Madagascar. Paper prepared for the IVth World Congress of
National Parks and Protected Areas, Caracas.

KRATTIGER, A. & LESSER, W. 1994 The "Facilitator": A new


mechanism to strengthen the equitable and sustainable use of
biodiversity. In: SEI: A clearing-house mechanism to promote and
facilitate technical and scientific cooperation, Stockholm, 13-22.

KRUTILLA, J.V. & FISHER, A.C. 1975 The economics of natural


environments. Studies in the valuation of commodity and amenity
resources. Johns Hopkins University Press for Resources for the
Future, Baltimore - London - Washington D.C.

LAIRD, S. 1993 Contracts for biodiversity prospecting, In: Reid, W. (ed.):


Biodiversity prospecting: Using genetic resources for sustainable
development. World Resources Institute, Washington D.C.

LIPPKE, B. 1996 Incentives for managing landscapes to meet non-timber


goals: Lessons from the Washington Landscape Management
Project. In: Adamowicz, W.L., Boxall, P.C., Luckert, M.K., Phillips,
W.E., White, W.A. (eds.): Forestry, economics and the environment.
CAB International, Guildford.

LOUVIERE, J.J. 1994 Relating stated preference measures and models to


choices in real markets. Paper prepared for the US Department of
Energy and Environmental Protection Agency workshop "Using
contingent valuation to measure non-market values", Herndon, VA.

78
Bibliography

MARGGRAF, R. & STREB, S. 1997 Ökonomische Bewertung der


natürlichen Umwelt. Spektrum Akademischer Verlag, Heidelberg,
Berlin.

MARKL, H. 1995 Wohin geht die Biologie? Biologen in unserer Zeit


3:33-39.

MENDELSOHN, R. & BALICK, M. 1995 The value of undiscovered


pharmaceuticals in tropical forests. Economic Botany 49(2):223-228.

MOONEY, P. & FOWLER, C. 1991 Die Saat des Hungers. Rowohlt,


Hamburg.

MUNASINGHE, M. 1993 Environmental economics and sustainable


development. World Bank Environment Paper 3. Washington D.C.

MYERS, N. 1989 Loss of biological diversity and its potential impact on


agriculture and food production. In: Pimentel, D. & Hall, C.W.
(eds.): Food and natural resources. Academic Press, San Diego, 49-
68.

OECD 1998 Improving the environment through reducing subsidies, Part


I. Summary and policy conclusions. OECD, Paris.

OECD 1996 Saving biological diversity - Economic incentives. OECD,


Paris.

OECD 1987 The economic value of biological diversity amaong medicinal


plants. Environment Directorate ENV/ECO/87.8. Prepared by Principe,
P. OECD, Paris.

OLDFIELD, M.L. 1984 The value of conserving genetic resources. U.S.


Dept. of the Interior, National Park Service, Washington D.C.

PANAYOUTOU, T. 1994 Conservation of biodiversity and economic


development: The concept of transferable development rights. In:
Perrings, C. et al. (eds.): Biodiversity conservation: Policy issues and
options. Kluwer Academic Press, Amsterdam.

79
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

PAULUS, S. 1995 Marktwirtschaftliche Instrumente der Umweltpolitik in


Entwicklungsländern. GTZ, Eschborn.

PEARCE, D.W. 1990 An economic approach to saving the tropical forests.


LEEC Paper 90-06, London.

PEARCE, D.M. & MORAN, D. 1994 The economic value of biodiversity.


Earthscan, London.

PERRINGS, C. 1995 The economic valuation of biodiversity. In:


Heywood, V.H. (ed.) Global Biodiversity Assessment, UNEP,
Cambridge University Press, pp. 823-914.

PERSSON, A. 1994 Macroeconomic policies behind deforestation in


Costa Rica. In: Perrings, C., Mäler, K.-G., Folke, C., Holling, C.S.,
Jansson, B.-O. (eds.): Biodiversity conservation: Policy issues and
options. Kluwer Academic Press, Dordrecht.

PETERS, C.M., GENTRY, A.H., MENDELSOHN, R.O. 1989 Valuation


of an Amazonian rain forest. Nature 229 (26 June 1989):655-56.

PLOTKIN, M.J. 1992 Tropische Länder als Quelle neuer Produkte von
Industrie und Landwirtschaft - ein Ausblick. In: Wilson, E.O. (ed.):
Ende der biologischen Vielfalt. Springer Verlag, Heidelberg, 128-
138.

PRESCOTT-ALLEN, C. & PRESCOTT-ALLEN, R. 1986 The first


resource. Wild species in the North American economy. Yale
University Press, New Haven - London.

PRINCIPE, P. 1989 The economic significance of plants and their


constituents as drugs. In: Wagner, H., Hikino, H., Farnsworth, N.
(eds.): Economic and medicinal plant research. Academic Press,
London, 3:1-17.

RANDALL, A. 1991 The value of biodiversity. Ambio 20:64-68.

REID, W.V. et al. 1993 A new lease of life. In: Reid, W. (ed.):
Biodiversity prospecting. World Resources Institute, Washington
D.C.
80
Bibliography

REID, W.V. & MILLER, K.R. 1989 Keeping options alive: The scientific
basis for conserving biodiversity. World Resources Institute,
Washington D.C.

RUCK, C. 1990 Die ökonomischen Effekte von Nationalparks in


Entwicklungsländern. Verlag Pinus Druck, Augsburg.

RUITENBEEK, H.J. 1992 The rainforest supply price: A tool for


evaluating rainforest conservation expenditures. Ecological
Economics 6(1):57-78.

RUITENBEEK, H.J. 1989 Social cost benefit analysis of the Korup


project, Cameroon. WWF report prepared for the World Wide Fund
for Nature and the Republic of Cameroon, London.

SÁNCHEZ, V. & JUMA, C. 1994 Challenges and opportunities for south-


south-cooperation in implementing the Convention on Biological
Diversity. In: Krattiger, A.F., McNeely, J.A., Lesser, W.H., Miller,
K.R., St. Hill, Y., Senanayake, R. (eds.): Widening perspectives on
biodiversity, IUCN. Gland and International Academy of the
Environment, Geneva, 305-307.

SEDJO, R.A., SIMPSON, R.D., REID, W. 1994 Contracting for Genetic


Resources, OECD, Group on Economic and Environment Policy
Integration, Expert Group on Economic Aspects of Biodiversity,
Paris.

SOLOW, R.M. 1974 Intergenerational equity and exhaustible resources.


Review of Economic Studies, Symposium on the economics of
exhaustible resources, 29-46.

SOLOW, R.M. 1986 On the intertemporal allocation of natural resources.


Scandinavian Journal of Economics 88(1):141-149.

STEPHAN, G. & AHLHEIM, M. 1996 Ökonomische Ökologie. Springer


Verlag, Berlin, Heidelberg, New York.

STORK, N.E. & SAMWAYS, M.J. 1995 Inventorying and monitoring of


biodiversity. In: Heywood, V. & Watson, R. (eds.): Global

81
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

biodiversity assessment, 453-544. Cambridge University Press,


Cambridge.

SWANSON, T.M. 1994 Biodiversity and intellectual property rights. In:


Perrings, C., Mäler, K.-G., Folke, C., Holling, C.S., Jansson, B.-O.
(eds.): Biodiversity loss: Ecological and economic issues. Cambridge
University Press, Cambridge.

TOBIAS, D. & MENDELSOHN, R. 1991 Valuing ecotourism in a tropical


rain-forest reserve. Ambio 20:91-93.

TURNER, R.K., DENT, D., HEY, R.D. 1983 Valuation of the


environmental impact of wetland flood protection and drainage
schemes. Environment and Planning A 15:871-888.

UNEP 1993 Guidelines for country studies on biodiversity. UNEP,


Nairobi.

VITOUSEK, P. et al. 1986 Human appropriation of products of


photosynthesis. BioScience 36(6):368-373.

VOGEL, J.H. 1994 Genes for sale - Privatization as a conservation policy.


Oxford University Press, Oxford, New York.

WELLS, M. 1992 Fiduciary funds to preserve biodiversity: Green funds.


Ecologia.

WICKE, L. 1986 Die ökologischen Milliarden. Kösel, Munich.

WILLIS, K.G., BENSON, J.F., SAUNDERS, C.M. 1988 The impact of


agricultural policy on the costs of nature conservation. Land
Economics 64:147-157.

WOODRUFF, D.S. & GALL, G.A.E. 1992 Genetics and conservation.


Agriculture, Ecosystems and Environment 42:53-73.

82
Bibliography

4.2 Other references


Abramowitz, J. 1991 Investing in biodiversity: US research and
conservation efforts in developing countries. World Resources
Institute, Washington D.C.

Adamowicz, W.L., Boxall, P.C., Luckert, M.K., Phillips, W.E., White,


W.A. (eds.) 1996 Forestry, economics and the environment. CAB
International, Guildford.

Adamowicz, W., Louviere, J., Williams, M. 1994 Combining stated and


revealed preference methods for valuing environmental amenities.
Journal of Environmental Management 26.

Adamowicz, W., Asafu-Adalaye, J., Boxall, P.C., Philips, W. 1991


Components of the economic value of wildlife: An Alberta study.
The Canadian Field Naturalist. 105(3):423-429.

Adamowicz, W., Phillips, W., Pattison, W. 1986 The distribution of


economic benefits from Alberta duck production. Wildlife Society
Bulletin 14(4).

Adger, W.N., Brown, K. Cervigni, R., Moran, D. 1995 Total economic


value of forests in Mexico. Ambio 24:286-296.

Altschul, S. v. Reis 1973 Drugs and foods from little-known plants.


Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Mass. - London.

Amacher, R.C., Tollison, R.D., Willett, T.D. 1972 The economics of fatal
mistakes: Fiscal mechanisms for preserving endangered predators.
Public Policy 20:411-441.

Anderson, D. & Williams, R.H. 1994 The cost effectiveness of GEF


projects. GEF Working Paper no. 6, Washington D.C

Antonovic, J. 1990 Genetically based measures of uniqueness. In: Orians,


G.H., Brown, G.M., Kunin, W.E., Swierzinbisnki, J.E. (eds.): The
preservation and valuation of genetic resources. University of
Washington Press, Seattle, 94-118.

83
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

Appasamy, P. 1993 Role of non-timber forest products in a subsistence


economy: the case of a joint forestry project in India. Economic
Botany 47.

Arndt, U., Nobel, W., Schweizer, B. 1987 Bioindikatoren. Möglichkeiten,


Grenzen und neue Erkenntnisse. Ulmer Verlag, Stuttgart.

Arrow, K.J. & Fisher, A.C. 1974 Environmental preservation, uncertainty


and irreversibility. Quarterly Journal of Economics 88:312-319.

Asafu-Adjaye, J., Phillips, W., Adamowicz, W. 1989 Towards the


measurement of total economic value: The case of wildlife resources
in Alberta. Staff paper no. 89-16, Department of Rural Economy,
University of Alberta, Edmonton, Alberta.

Attfield, R. 1983 The ethics of environmental concern. Blackwell, Oxford.

Association of Environmental and Resource Economists Workshop 1992


Benefit transfer: procedures, problems, and research needs. Case
study synopsis.

Aylward, B. & Barbier, E. 1992 Valuing environmental functions in


developing countries. Biodiversity and Conservation 1:34-50.

Bachmura, F.T. 1971 The economics of vanishing species. Natural


Resources Journal 11:674-692.

Balandrin, M.F., Klocke, J.A., Wurtele, E.S., Bollinger, W.H. 1985


Natural plant chemicals: sources of industrial and medicinal
materials. Science 228:1154-1160.

Balick, M. & Mendelsohn, R. 1992 Assessing the economic value of


traditional medicines from tropical rainforests. Conservation Biology
6(1).

Barbier, E. 1992 Rehabilitating gum arabic systems in Sudan: economic


and environmental implications. Environmental and Resource
Economics 2:341-358.

84
Bibliography

Barbier, E. 1994 Valuing environmental functions: tropical wetlands. Land


Economics 70(2):155-173.

Barbier, E.B., Burgess, J.C., Markandya, A. 1991 The economics of


tropical deforestation. Ambio 20:55-58.

Barbier, E.B. 1989 The economic value of ecosystems: 1. Tropical


wetlands. LEEC, Gatekeeper series no. 89-02.

Barbier, E.B. 1989 Economics, natural resources scarcity and


development. Conventional and alternative views. Earthscan,
London.

Barrett, S. 1991 Economic instruments for climate change policy. In:


OECD (ed.): Environmental policy: How to apply economic
instruments. OECD, Paris, 53-110.

Barrett, S. 1991 Economic analysis of international environmental


agreements: Lessons for a global warming treaty. In: OECD (ed.):
Environmental policy: How to apply economic instruments. OECD,
Paris, 111-149.

Barstow, R. 1986 Non-consumptive utilization of whales. Ambio 15:155-


163.

Bateman, I. et al. 1992 A contingent valuation study of the Norfolk


Broads. Report to the National Rivers Authority.

Batie, S.S., Mabbs-Zeno, C.C. 1985 Opportunity costs of preserving


coastal wetlands: a case study of a recreational housing development.
Land Economics 61:1-9.

Beck, G. 1990 Naturschutz - aus ökonomischer Sicht. Dissertation at


Berlin Technical University.

Benkert, W. 1987 Die Bedeutung des Gemeinlastprinzips in der


Umweltpolitik. Zeitschrift für Umweltpolitik und Umweltrecht
9:213-229.

85
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

Bennett, E. & Reynolds, C. 1993 The value of a mangrove area in


Sarawak. Biodiversity and Conservation 2:359-375.

Bennett, E. 1978 Threats to crop plant genetic resources. In: Hawkes, J.G.
(ed.): Conservation and agriculture. Duckworth, London, 113-122.

Bennett, J. 1984 Using direct questioning to value the existence benefits of


preserved natural areas. Australian Journal of Agricultural
Economics 28(2/3):136-152.

Benson, J.F. & Willis, K.J. 1990 The aggregate value of non-priced
recreation benefits of the Forestry Commission Estate. Report to the
Forestry Commission, University of Newcastle Upon Tyne.

Bergstrom, J.C., Stoll, J.R., Titre, J.P., Wright, V.L. 1990 Economic value
of wetlands-based recreation. Ecological Economics 2:129-147.

Binswanger, H. 1989 Brazilian policies that encourage deforestation in the


Amazon. World Bank, Environment Department, Working Paper 16,
Washington D.C.

Bishop, R.C. 1982 Option value: An exposition and extension. Land


Economics 58:1-15.

Bishop, R.C. 1978 Endangered species and uncertainty: The economics of


a safe minimum standard. American Journal of Agrucultural
Economics 61:10-18.

Blab, J., Forst, C., Klär, C., Niclas, G., Wey, H., Woithe, G. 1991
Förderprogramme zur Errichtung und Sicherung schutzwürdiger
Teile von Natur und Landschaft mit gesamtstaatlich repräsentativer
Bedeutung. Natur und Landschaft 66:3-9.

Blum, E. 1993 Incentive policies and forest use in the Phillipines. In:
Repetto, R. & Gillis, M. (eds.): Public policies and the misuse of
forest resources. World Resources Institute, Washington D.C.

Blum, E. 1993 Making biodiversity conservation profitable: a case study


of the Merck/INBio agreement. Environment 35:16-20, 38-45.

86
Bibliography

Boado, E. 1989 Incentive policies and forest use in the Philippines. In:
Repetto, R. & Gillis, M. (eds.): Public policies and the misuse of
forest resources. World Resources Institute, Washington D.C.

Boadu, F.O. 1992 Contingent valuation for household water in rural


Ghana. Journal of Agricultural Economics 43(3).

Bohn, A. & Byerlee, D. 1993 The wheat breeding industry in developing


countries: An analysis of investments and impacts. Centro
Internacional de CIMMYT, Singapore.

Bonus, H. 1986 Eine Lanze für den "Wasserpfennig". Wider die


Vulgärform des Verursacherprinzips. Wirtschaftsdienst
1986/IX:451-455.

Bonus, H. 1981 Instrumente einer ökologieverträglichen


Wirtschaftspolitik. In: Binswanger, H.C., Bonus, H., Timmermann,
M. (eds.): Wirtschaft und Umwelt, Kohlkammer Verlag, Stuttgart,
84-163.

Bonus, H. 1980 Öffentliche Güter und der Öffentlichkeitsgrad von Gütern.


Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft 136:50-81.

Bowers, J. 1988 Farm incomes and the benefit of environmental


protection. In: Collard, D., Pearce, D., Ulph, D. (eds.): Economics,
growth and sustainable environments. Essays in memory of Richard
Lecomber. Macmillan, Basingstoke - London, 161-171.

Bowers, J. 1988 Cost-benefit analysis in theory and practice: Agricultural


land drainage projects. In: Turner, E.K. (ed.): Sustainable
environmental management. Belhaven Press - Westview Press,
London - Boulder, 265-269.

Bowles, I.A. & Prickett, G.T. 1994 Reframing the green window: An
analysis of the GEF pilot phase approach to biodiversity and global
warming and recommendations for the operational phase.
Conservation International, Natural Resources Defense Council,
Washington D.C.

87
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

Boyd, R. & Hyde, W. 1989 Forestry sector intervention: the impacts of


public regulation on social welfare. Iowa State University Press.

Boyle, K.J. & Bergstrom, J.C. 1992 Benefit transfer studies: myths,
pragmatism, and idealism. Water Resources Research 28(3):657-663.

Braatz, S., Davis, G., Rees, C. 1992 Conserving biological diversity: A


strategy for protected areas in the Asia-Pacific region. World Bank
Technical Paper 193. Washington D.C.

Bradley, P.N. & McNamara, K. (eds.) 1993 Living with trees: Policies for
forest management in Zimbabwe. World Bank Technical Paper 210,
Washington D.C.

Bromley, D. & Cernea, M. 1989 The management of common property


resources: Some conceptual and operational fallacies. World Bank
Discussion Paper no. 57.

Brookshire, D.S. & Neill, H.R. 1992 Benefit transfers: Conceptual and
empirical issues. Water Resources Research 28(3):651-655.

Brookshire, D.S., Eubanks, L.S., Randall, A. 1983 Estimating option


prices and existence values for wildlife resources. Land Economics
59:1-15.

Brookshire, D.S., David, S., Ives, B., Schulze, W. 1976 The valuation of
aesthetic preferences. Journal of Environmental Economics and
Management 3(3):325-346.

Browder, J.O. 1988 The social costs of rainforest destruction. Interciencia


13(2).

Browder, J.O. 1988 Public policy and deforestation in the Brazilian


Amazon. In: Repetto, R. & Gillis, M. (eds.): Public policies and the
misuse of forest resources. World Resources Institute, Washington
D.C.,

Brown, G. & Goldstein, J.H. 1984 A model for valuing endangered


species. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management
11:303-309.
88
Bibliography

Brown, K. 1992 Carbon sequestration and storage in tropical forests.


Centre for Social and Economic Research on the Global
Environment, Discussion Paper 92, University of East Anglia and
University College London, Norwich and London.

Brown, K. & Goldin, I. 1992 The future of agriculture: Developing


country implications. Development Centre Studies, OECD, Paris.

Brown, K., Pearce, D.W., Perrings, C., Swanson, T. 1993 Economics and
the conservation of biological diversity. GEF Working Paper 2.
Washington D.C.

Callicott, J.B. 1986 On the intrinsic value of nonhuman species. In:


Norton, B.G. (ed.): The preservation of species. University Press,
Princeton, 138-172.

Cameron, T.A. & Quiggin, J. 1994 Estimation using contingent valuation


data from a 'dichotomous choice with follow-up' questionnaire.
Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 27:218-234.

Carson, R. et al. 1992 A contingent valuation study of lost passive values


resulting from the Exxon Valdez oil spill. Report to the Attorney
General of the State of Alaska.

Carter, M. 1987 Economic and socio-economic impacts of the Thorns


Starfish on the Great Barriert Reef. Report to the Great Barrier Reef
Marine Park Authority, Institute of Applied Environmental Research,
Griffith University, Brisbane.

Cernea, M. 1993 The sociologist's approach to sustainable development.


Finance and Development 30(4):11-13.

Cervigni, R. 1993 Biodiversity, incentives to deforest and tradeable


development rights. GEC working paper 93-07, Centre for Social
and Economic Research on the Global Environment, University of
East Anglia, University College London.

Cervigni, R. 1993 Estimating the benefits of plant genetic resources for


food and agriculture: Suggested approaches. Centre for Social and

89
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

Economic Research on the Global Environment, University College,


London and University of East Anglia.

Cesario, F.J. 1976 Value of time in recreation benefit studies. Land


Economics 52:32-41.

Child, B. 1990 Assessment of wildlife utilization as a land use option in


the semi-arid rangelands of Southern Africa. In: Kiss, A. (ed.):
Living with wildlife. Wildlife resource management with local
participation in Africa. World Bank, Washington D.C., Annex 3:193-
204.

Chopra, K. 1993 The value of non-timber forest products: an estimate


from India. Economic Botany 47(3):251-257.

Cicchetti, C.J., Fisher, A., Smith, V.K. 1971 An econometric evaluation of


a generalized consumer surplus measure: The mineral king
controversy. Econometrica 39:813-827.

Cicchetti, C.J. & Freeman, A.M. 1971 Option demand and consumer
surplus: Further comment. Quarterly Journal of Economics 85:528-
539.

Ciriacy-Wantrup, S.V. 1952 Resource conservation economics and


politics. University of California, Division of Agricultural Sciences,
Berkeley and Los Angeles.

Clark, C.W. 1976 Mathematical bioeconomics: The optimal management


of renewable resources. John Wiley, New York.

Cleaver, K., Munasinghe, M., Dyson, M., Egli, N., Peuker, A., Wencelius,
F. (eds.) 1992 Conservation of West and Central African rainforests.
World Bank Environment Paper 1. Washington D.C.

Cline, W. 1992 The economics of global warming. International Institute


for International Economics, Washington D.C.

Collard, D., Pearce, D., Ulph, D. (eds.) 1988 Economics, growth and
sustainable environments. Essays in memory of Richard Lecomber,
Macmillan, Basingstoke - London.
90
Bibliography

Common, M. & Perrings, C. 1992 Towards an ecological economics of


sustainability. Ecological Economics 6:7-34.

Cooper, D., Vellvé, R., Hobbelink, H. (eds.) 1992 Growing diversity:


Genetic resources and local food security. Intermediate Technology
Publications, London.

Cornes, R. & Sandler, T. 1986 The theory of externalities, public goods


and club goods. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K, New
York, Port Chester, Melbourne, Sydney.

Cornia, G.A., Jolly, R., Stewart, F. (eds.) 1989 Adjustment with a human
face. Oxford University Press, New York.

Costanza, R. & Daly, H.E. 1987 Toward an ecological economics.


Ecological Modelling 38:1-7.

Costanza, R., Farber, S., Maxwell, J. 1989 Valuation and management of


wetland ecosystems. Ecological Economics 1(4):335-362.

Cummings, R.G., Brookshire, D.S., Schulze, W.D. 1986 Valuing public


goods. An assessment of the contingent valuation method. Rowman
& Allanheld, Totowa, N.J.

Danielson, L.E., Leitch, J.A. 1986 Private versus public economics of


prairie wetland allocation. Journal of Environmental Economics and
Management 13(1).

Dasgupta, A.K. & Pearce, D.W. 1978 Cost-benefit analysis, theory and
practice. Macmillan, London - Basingstoke.

Davis, S.G. (ed.) 1993 Indigenous views of land and the environment.
World Bank Discussion Paper 188. Washington S.C.

Davis, S., Castilleja, G., Poole, P.J., Geisler, C. (eds.) 1993 The social
challenge of biodiversity conservation. GEF Working Paper 1,
Washington D.C.

91
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

Deacon, R. & Murphy, P. 1992 The structure of an environmental


transaction: the debt-for-nature swap. Department of Economics,
University of California at Santa Barbara.

Decker, D.J. & Goff, G.R. (eds.) 1987 Valuing wildlife. Economic and
social perspectives. Westview Press, Boulder - London.

deGroot, R. 1992 Functions and values of protected areas: A


comprehensive framework for assessing the benefits of protected
areas to human society. Climate Change Research Centre,
Agricultural University, Wageningen.

deLacy, T. & Lockwood, M. 19zz Estimating the non-market values of


nature conservation resources Australia. Charles Sturt University,
Albury, Australia.

Desvousges, W.H., Gable, A.R., Dunford, R.W., Hudson, S. 1993


Contingent valuation: the wrong tool to measure passive-use losses.
Choices II:9-11

Dewees, P.A. 1993 Trees, land, and labor. World Bank Environment Paper
4. Washington D.C.

Diamond, A.W. & Filion, F.L. (eds.) 1987 The value of birds. ICBP
Technical Publication no. 6, IUCN, Cambridge.

Dinerstein, E. & Wikramanayake, E. 1993 Beyond hotspots: how to


prioritise investments to conserve biodiversity in the Indo-Pacific
region. Conserv. Biol. 7(1):53-65.

Dixon, J.A., Scura, L.F., van't Hof, T. 1993 Meeting ecological and
economic goals: Marine parks in the Caribbean. Ambio 22(2-3):117-
125.

Dixon, J.A. & Sherman, P.B. 1991 Economics of protected areas. Ambio
20:68-74.

Dogse, P. & von Droste, B. 1990 Debt for nature exchanges and biosphere
reserves. UNESCO, Paris.

92
Bibliography

D'Silva, E. & Appanah, S. 1993 Forestry management for sustainable


development. EDI Policy Seminar Report 32. World Bank,
Washington D.C.

Duke, J.A. 1976 Economic appraisal of endangered plant species.


Phytologica 34:21-27.

Durning, A.B. 1989 Poverty and the environment: Reversing the


downward spiral. Worldwatch Paper 92, Worldwatch Institute,
Washington D.C.

Ebenroth, C.T. & Bühler, S. 1990 Verschuldungskrise und Umweltschutz -


Debt-for-Nature-Swaps, eine Lösung für zwei Probleme? Natur und
Recht 6:260-266.

Ehrlich, P.R. & Ehrlich, A.H. 1992 The value of biodiversity. Ambio
21(3).

Eltringham, S.K. 1984 Wildlife resources and economic development.


John Wiley, Chichester.

Endres, A. 1985 Umwelt- und Ressourcenökonomie. Erträge der


Forschung 229, Wissenschaftliche Buchgesellschaft, Darmstadt.

English, J., Tiffen, M., Mortimer, M. 1993 Land resource management in


Machakos district, Kenya 1930-1990. World Bank Environment
Paper 5, Washington D.C.

Evenson, R.E. 1991 Genetic resources: assessing economic value. In:


Vincent, J., Crawford, E., Hoehn, J. (eds.): Valuing environmental
benefits in developing economies. Proceedings of a seminar series
held in February-May 1990 at Michigan State University, Special
Report no. 29.

Faeth, P., Cort, C., Livernash, R. 1994 Evaluating the carbon sequestration
benefits of forestry projects in less developed countries. World
Ressources Institute, Washington D.C.

Fankhauser, S. 1992 A point estimate of the economic damage from global


warming. Centre for Social and Economic Research on the Global
93
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

Environment. CSERGE Discussion Paper 92, University of East


Anglia and University College London, Norwich and London.

Fankhauser, S. 1994 The social costs of greenhouse gas emissions: an


expected value approach. Energy Journal 15(2).

Farber, S. & Costanza, R. 1987 The value of coastal wetlands for


protection of property against hurricane wind damage. Journal of
Environmental Economics and Management:14:143-151.

Farnsworth, N.R. 1988 Screening plants for new medicines. In: Wilson,
E.O. (ed.): Biodiversity. National Academy Press, Washington D.C.,
83-97.

Favre, D.S. 1989 International trade in endanered species. A guide to


CITES. Martinus Nijhoff, Dordrecht

Fearnside, P.M. 1990 The rate and extent of deforestation in Brazilian


Amazonia. Environmental Conservation 17:213-226.

Festl, J. 1980 Kosten-Nutzen-Analyse von Meliorationen und


Kultivierung. Dissertation, Hohenheim.

Findeisen, C. 1991 Natural products research and the potential role of the
pharmaceutical industry in tropical forest conservation. Rainforest
Alliance, New York.

Fisher, A.C. & Krutilla, J.V. 1974 Valuing long run ecological
consequences and irreversibilities. Journal of Environmental
Economies and Management 1:96-108.

Fisher, A.C. & Hanemann, W.M. 1985 Endangered species: The


economies of irreversible damage. In: Hall, D.O., Myers, N.,
Margaris, N.S. (eds.): Economies of ecosystem management. Junk
Publications, Dordrecht, 129-138.

Fitzgerald, S.G. 1986 World Bank pledges to protect wildlands.


BioScience 36:712-715.

94
Bibliography

Freeman, A.M. III 1984 The quasi-option value of irreversible


development. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management
11:292-295.

Freeman, A.M. III 1979 The benefits of environmental improvement:


Theory and practice. Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore.

French, H. 1994 Umgestaltung der Weltbank. In: Brown, L.R. (ed.): Zur
Lage der Welt 1994. Fischer, Frankfurt, 211-244

Frey, R.L. & Blöchinger, H. 1991 Schützen oder Nutzen.


Ausgleichszahlungen im Natur- und Landschaftsschutz. Rüegger,
Chur - Zürich.

Furtado, J. 1990 Biological diversity: Global conservation needs and costs.


Environment Programme Report, Centre for Integrated
Development, London.

Gámez, R. et al. 1993 Costa Rica's conservation program and National


Biodiversity Institute (INBio). In: Reid, W. et al. (eds.): Biodiversity
prospecting: Using genetic resources for sustainable development.
World Resources Institute, Washington D.C.

Gans, O. & Margraf, R. 1997 Kosten-Nutzen-Analyse und ökonomische


Politikbewertung, Vol. I: Wohlfahrtsmessung.
Betriebswirtschaftliche Investitionskriterien. Springer, Berlin, New
York, Heidelberg.

Germann, D. 1989 Erlauben die defizitären Wirtschaftsergebnisse eine


unveränderte Beibehaltung der forstpolitischen Zielsetzung? Ein
Diskussionsbeitrag - am Beispiel der Hessischen
Landesforstverwaltung. Forstarchiv 60:219-222.

Gillis, M. 1988 Indonesia: Public policies, resource management and the


tropical forest. In: Repetto, R. & Gillis, M. (eds.): Public policies and
the misuse of forest resources. World Resources Institute,
Washington D.C.

95
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

Gillis, M. 1988 Malaysia: Public policies and the tropical forest. In:
Repetto, R. & Gillis, M. (eds.): Public policies and the misuse of
forest resources. World Resources Institute, Washington D.C.

Gillis, M. 1988 West Africa: Resource management policies and the


tropical forest. In: Repetto, R. & Gillis, M. (eds.): Public policies and
the misuse of forest resources, World Resources Institute,
Washington D.C.

Global Environmental Facility 1992 Memorandum of understanding on


Norwegian funding of pilot demonstration projects for joint
implementation arrangements under the climate convention GEF.
World Bank, Washington D.C.

Godoy, R. & Bawa, K. 1993 The economic value and sustainable harvest
of plants and animals from the tropical rainforest: Assumptions,
hypotheses, and methods. Economic Botany 47(3):215-219.

Godoy, R., Lubowski, R., Markandya, A. 1993 A method for the economic
valuation of non-timber tropical forest products. Economic Botany
47(3):220-233.

Gödde, M. 1990 Unternehmen als Sponsoren. Umwelt (VDI) 20:632-634.

Goodland, R.J.A. 1988 A major new opportunity to finance the


preservation of biodiversity. In: Wilson, E.O. (ed.): Biodiversity.
National Academy Press, Washington D.C.

Goodland, R.J.A. & Webb, M. 1987 The management of cultural property


in World Bank assisted projects. World Bank Technical Paper 62.

Gradwohl, J. & Greenberg, R. 1988 Saving the tropical forests. Earthscan,


London.

Green, R.M. 1977 Intergenerational distributive justice and environmental


responsibility. BioScience 27:260-265.

Grimes, A. et al. 1993 Valuing the rainforest: The economic value of non-
timber forest products in Ecuador. Yale School of Forestry and
Environmental Studies, New Haven.
96
Bibliography

GTZ 1997 Bodenrecht und Bodenordnung. GTZ, Eschborn.

GTZ 1993 Die Rolle von Abreizen bei der Anwendung von RMSH als
Vorgehensweise. GTZ, Eschborn.

Gutierrez, B. & Pearce, D.W. 1992 Estimating the environmental benefits


of the Amazon forest: an intertemporal valuation exercise. GEC
working paper 92-44, Centre for Social and Economic Research on
the Global Environment, University College London and University
of East Anglia, London and Norwich.

Hall, P. & Bawa, K. 1993 Methods to assess the impact of extraction of


non-timber tropical forest products on plant populations. Economic
Botany 47(3):234-247.

Hampicke, U. 1991 Neoklassik und Zeitpräferenz - der


Diskontierungsnebel. In: Beckenbach, F. (ed.): Die ökologische
Herausforderung für die ökonomische Theorie. Metropolis, Marburg,
127-149.

Hampicke, U. 1990 Naturschutzfinanzierung. In: Ganzheitliche


Naturschutzpolitik statt Reservatsdenken. Dokumentation einer
Anhörung der Grünen im Bundestag, Bonn, 42-64.

Hampicke, U. 1990 Ökologische und ökonomische Probleme der


Grünlandextensivierung. Naturschutz in Nordhessen 11:31-46.

Hampicke, U. 1990 Naturschutz als eine regionalwirtschaftliche Option.


In: deHaen, H. & Isermeyer, F. (eds.): Ländlicher Raum im Abseits?
Vauk, Kiel, 178-193.

Hampicke, U. 1989 Was darf und was kann monetarisiert werden? In:
Möglichkeiten und Grenzen der Monetarisierung von Natur und
Umwelt. Schriftenreihe des IÖW 88-20, Institut für Ökologische
Wirtschaftsforschung, Berlin, 19-41.

Hampicke, U. 1989 Volks- und betriebswirtschaftliche Kosten des


Naturschutzes in der Landwirtschaft und Möglichkeiten der
Finanzierung. Laufener Seminarbeiträge 87-3:60-84.

97
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

Hampicke, U. 1988 Extensivierung der Landwirtschaft für den


Naturschutz - Ziele, Rahmenbedingungen und Maßnahmen.
Schriftenreihe Bayer. Landesamt für Umweltschutz 84:9-35.

Hampicke, U. 1987 Naturschutz als ökonomisches Problem. Zeitschrift für


Umweltpolitik und Umweltrecht 10:157-195.

Hampicke, U. 1987 Ökologische Vorgaben für die Agrarökonomie.


Umrisse einer Landwirtschaft ohne Ausrottung von Arten.
Internationales Institut für Umwelt und Gesellschaft, Berlin.

Hampicke, U. 1985 Die volkswirtschaftlichen Kosten des Naturschutzes in


Berlin. Ökonomische Begleitstudie zu den "Grundlagen für das
Artenschutzprogramm Berlin". Technische Universität, Berlin.

Hampicke, U. 1985 Die voraussichtlichen Kosten einer


naturschutzgerechten Landwirtschaft. Kali-Briefe17:701-714.

Hampicke, U. 1983 Die voraussichtlichen Kosten einer umweltgerechten


Landwirtschaft. Landschaft+Stadt 15:171-183.

Hampicke, U., Horlitz,T., Kiemstedt, H., Tampe, K., Timp, D., Walters, M.
1991 Kosten und Wertschätzung des Arten- und Biotopschutzes.
Erich Schmidt Verlag, Berlin.

Hanemann, W.M. 1991 Willingness to pay and willingness to accept: How


much can they differ? American Economic Review 81(3):663-647.

Hanemann, W.M. 1989 Welfare evaluations in contingent valuation:


Experiments with discrete responses. American Journal of
Agricultural Economics 66(3):32-34.

Hanemann, W.M 1988 Economics and the preservation of biodiversity. In:


Wilson, E.O. (ed.): Biodiversity. National Academy Press,
Washington D.C., 193-199.

Hanley, N.D. 1990 Valuation of environmental effects: final report - stage


one. Industry Department of Scotland and the Scottish Development
Agency.

98
Bibliography

Hanley, N.D. & Craig, S. 1991 Wilderness development decisions and the
Krutilla-Fisher model: the case of Scotland's flow country.
Ecological Economics 4(2):145-162.

Hanley, N.D. & Spash, C. 1993 Preferences, information and biodiversity


preservation. Discussion papers in Economics 93-12, Department of
Economics, University of Stirling.

Hanusch, H. 1987 Nutzen-Kosten-Analyse. Vahlen, Munich.

Hartje, V.J. 1986 Zur Erhaltung genetischer Ressourcen. Zeitschrift für


Wirtschafts- und Sozialwissenschaften 106:229-252.

Hausman, J.A., Leonard, G.K., McFadden, D. 1992 Assessing use value


losses due to natural resource injury. Cambridge Economics Inc.,
Cambridge, Mass.

Heath, R. 1992 Wildlife based tourism in a developing country: The


economic implications. University of Zimbabwe.

Heath, R. 1992 The growth in wildlife based tourism in Zimbabwe.


University of Zimbabwe.

Heberlein, T.A. 1986 Measuring resource values: the reliabilitiy and


validity of dichtomous contingent valuation measures. Paper
presented at the American Sociological Association Meeting, New
York.

Hecht, S., Norgaard, R., Possio, G. 1988 The economics of cattle ranching
in Eastern Amazonia. Interciencia 13(5):233-239.

Henry, C. 1974 Investment decisions under uncertainty: The


"irreversibility effect". American Economic Review 64:1006-1012.

Hof, J. & King, D. 1991 Recreational demand by tourists for saltwater


beach days: Comment. Journal of Environmental Economics and
Management 22:281-291.

99
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

Hoffmann, H. & Wohlgschaft, M. 1990 Ökonomische Betrachtungen zum


Bayerischen Kulturlandschaftsprogramm. Berichte über
Landwirtschaft 68:196-215.

Hohl, A. & Tisdell, C. 1993 How useful are environmental safety


standards in economics? - The example of safe minimum standards
for protection of species. Biodiversity and Conservation 2:168-181.

Huber, R. 1992 Case studies showing cost/benefit of tourism and protected


areas development. Paper presented at the IVth World Congress on
National Parks and Protected Areas, Caracas.

Hundloe, T.J. 1990 Measuring the value of the Great Barrier Reef.
Australian Parks and Recreation 26(3):11-15.

Hundsdorfer, M. 1989 Kostendatei für Maßnahmen des Naturschutzes und


der Landschaftspflege. Materialien 55, Bayerisches
Staatsministerium für Landesentwicklung und Umweltfragen,
Munich.

Imber, D., Stevenson, G., Wilks, L. 1991 A contingent valuation survey of


the Kakadu conservation zone. Resource Assessment Commission,
Research Paper no. 3, Canberra.

IUCN, The Nature Conservancy, WWF 1994 First global forum on


environmental funds. Cambridge, U.K.

Jansen, D.J. 1990 Sustainable wildlife utilization in the Zambezi valley of


Zimbabwe: Economic, ecological and political tradeoffs. Project
paper no. 10, WWF Multispecies Project, Harare.

Jarass, L., Niesslein, E., Obermair, G.M. 1989 Von der


Sozialkostentheorie zum umweltpolitischen Steuerungsinstrument.
Nomos, Baden-Baden.

Johansson, P.-O., Kristrom, B., Maler, K. 1989 Welfare evaluations in


contingent valuation: Experiments with discrete response data:
Comment. American Journal of Agricultural Economics.

100
Bibliography

Johansson, P.-O. & Löfgren, K.G. 1985 The economics of forestry and
natural resources. Basil Blackwell, Oxford.

Kahnemann, D., Knetsch, J.L. 1992 Valuing public goods: The purchase
of moral satisfaction. Journal of Environmental Economics and
Management 22(1):57-70.

Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J.L., Thaler, R.H. 1990 Experimental tests of the
endowment effect and the coarse theorem. Journal of Political
Economy 98(6).

Karl, H. & Klemmer, P. 1988 Ökonomische und ökologische


Agrarmarktreform und Ansatzpunkte für die Vergabe von
Bewirtschaftungsbeiträgen. Zeitschrift für Umweltpolitik und
Umweltrecht 11:339-359.

Katzman, M. & Cale, W. 1990 Tropical forest preservation using


economic incentives: A proposal of conservation easements.
BioScience 40(11):827-832.

King, K. 1993 The incremental costs of global environmental benefits.


GEF Working Paper 5. Washington D.C.

King, K. 1993 Issues to be addressed by the GEF program for measuring


incremental costs for the environment. GEF Working Paper 8.
Washington D.C.

Kling, C.L. 1988 Comparing welfare estimates of environmental quality


changes from recreational demand models. Journal of Environmental
Economics and Management 15(3):331-340.

Kling, C.L. 1987 A simulation approach to comparing multiple-site


recreation-demand models using Chesapeake Bay survey data.
Marine Resource Economics 4(2):95-109.

Klockow, S. & Matthes, U. 1991 Umweltbedingte Folgekosten im Bereich


Freizeit und Erholung. Forschungsvorhaben 101 03 110/06 des
Umweltbundesamtes. Umweltbundesamt Berlin, Texte 4/91.

101
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

Knebel, B. & Krause, M. 1989 Gesamtwirtschaftliche Analyse der


Flurbereinigung. Dissertation, Kassel.

Knetsch, J.L. & Sinden, J. 1984 Willingness to pay and compensation


demanded: Experimental evidence of an unexpected disparity in
measures of value. Quarterly Journal of Economics XCIX(3):507-
521.

Köhne, M. 1987 Auflagen zum Natur- und Wasserschutz: Rechtliche und


ökonomische Aspekte der Entschädigung. In: Landwirtschaft und
Umwelt, Schriften der Gesellschaft für Wirtschafts- und
Sozialwissenschaften 23:347-360.

Kosmo, M. 1989 Commercial energy subsidies in developing countries.


Energy Policy 17:244-253.

Kuhlmann, F. & Müller, H. 1986 Zur ökonomischen Bewertung von


Naturschutzauflagen für den Landwirtschaftsbetrieb.
Landwirtschaftsverlag Hessen, Friedrichsdorf im Taunus.

Kuliopulos, H. 1990 Amazon biodiversity. Science 248:1305.

Ledec, G. & Goodland, R. 1992 Harmonizing sustainable development


with conservation of wildlands. In: Kapoor-Vijay, P. & White, J.
(eds.): Conservation biology: a training manual for biological
diversity and genetic resources. Commonwealth Science Council,
London.

Leibundgut, H. 1983 Führen naturnahe Waldbauverfahren zur


betriebswirtschaftlichen Erfolgsverbesserung? Forstarchiv 54:47-51.

Leslie, A.J. 1987 A second look at the economics of natural management


systems in tropical mixed forests. Unasylva 39(155):46-58.

Lever, H. & Huhne, C. 1987 Debt and danger. The world financial crisis.
Penguin Books, Middle Essex.

Loehmann, E.T. & De, V.H. 1992 Application of stochastic choice


modelling to policy analysis of public goods: A case study of air

102
Bibliography

quality improvements. Review of Economics and Statistics 64:474-


480.

Loomis, J.B. 1990 Comparative reliability of the dichotomous choice and


open ended valuation techniques. Journal of Environmental
Economics and Management 18(1):78-85.

Loomis, J.B. 1989 Test-retest reliability of the contingent valuation


method: A comparison of general population and visitor response.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics 71:76-84.

Loomis, J.B. 1988 Contingent valuation using dichotomous choice models.


Journal of Leisure Research 20(1):46-56.

Lynne, G.D., Conroy, P., Prochaska, F.J. 1981 Economic valuation of


marsh areas for marine production processes. Journal of
Environmental Economics and Management 8:175-186.

Mährlein, A. 1990 Einzelwirtschaftliche Auswirkungen von


Naturschutzauflagen. Vauk, Kiel.

Mäler, K.G. 1977 A note on the use of property values in estimating


marginal willingness to pay for environmental quality. Journal of
Environmental Economics and Management 4(4):355-369.

Magrath, W. & Arens, P. 1989 The cost of soil erosion in Java: A natural
resource accounting approach. Environment Department, Working
Paper no. 18, World Bank, Washington D.C.

Mahar, D. 1989 Government policies and deforestation in Brazil's Amazon


region. World Bank, Washington D.C.

Maille, P. & Mendelsohn, R. 1993 Valuing ecotourism in Madagascar.


Journal of Environmental Management 38:213-218.

Marcondes, M. 1981 Adaptation de una metodologia de evaluacion


economica, aplicada al Parque Nacional Cahuita, Costa Rica. Centro
Agronomico Tropical de Investigacion y Ensenanza (CATIE), Serie
Tecnica no. 9.

103
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

Margulis, L. & Lovelock, J.E. 1974 Biological modulation of the earth's


atmosphere. Icarus 21:471-489.

Markandya, A. & Pearce, D.W. 1988 Environmental considerations and


the choice of the discount rate in developing countries. World Bank,
Environmental Department Working Paper no. 3.

Martinez-Alier, J. 1987 Ecological economics. Basil Blackwell, Oxford.

Mateo, C.A.Q. (ed.) 1993 Debt-for-nature swaps to promote natural


resource conservation. FAO, Rome

Mauksch, W. 1987 Der Naturschutzwert von einigen normalen agrarischen


Flurbereinigungsmaßnahmen. Landschaft+Stadt 19:136-143.

McConnell, K.E. & Strand, I.E. 1981 Measuring the cost of time in
recreation demand analysis. American Journal of Agricultural
Economics 63:153-156.

McNeely, J.A. 1989 How to pay for conserving biological diversity.


Ambio 18:303-313.

McNeely, J.A. 1988 Economics and biological diversity. Developing and


using economic incentives to conserve biological resources. IUCN,
Gland.

McNeely, J.A. & Norgaard, R. 1991 Developed country policies and


biological diversity in developing countries. Agriculture, Ecosystems
and Environments 42:194-204.

McNeely, J.A. & Tobias, R.J. 1991 Economic incentives for conserving
biological diversity in Thailand. Ambio 20(2):86-90.

Mendelsohn, R.O., Hof, J., Petersen, G., Reed, J. 1992 Measuring


recreation values with multiple destination trips. American Journal of
Agricultural Economics 74(4):926-933.

Mendelsohn, R.O. & Tobias, R.J. 1991 Valuing ecotourism in a tropical


rainforest reserve. Ambio 20(2):91-93.

104
Bibliography

Mercer, E., Kramer, R., Sharma, N. 1993 Estimating the nature tourism
benefits of establishing the Mantadia National Park in Madagascar.
Centre for Resource and Environmental Policy Research, Duke
University, NC.

Miller, J.R. & Menz, F.C. 1979 Some economic considerations in wildlife
preservation. Southern Economic Journal 45:718-729.

Milner-Gulland, E.J. & Leader-Williams, N. 1992 A model of incentives


for illegal exploitation of rhinos and elephants: Poaching pays in
Luangwa Valley, Zambia. Journal of Applied Ecology 29.

Ministry of Natural Resources, Energy and Mines, Costa Rica 1991


National study of biodiversity: Costs, benefits and needs for
financing and conservation of biological diversity in Costa Rica.

Mintzer, I.M. 1993 Implementing the framework convention on climate


change: Incremental costs and the role of the GEF. GEF Working
Paper no. 4. Washington D.C.

Mishan, E.J. 1981 Introduction to normative economics. Oxford


University Press, New York - Oxford.

Mishan, E.J. 1976 Cost-benefit analysis. Praeger, New York.

Mitchel, C. 1989 Economics and the environment: A case of small island


states. Prepared for the Caribbean Conservation Association
Conference on Economics of the Environment, Barbados.

Mitchell, R.C. & Carson, R.T. 1989 Using surveys to value public goods:
The contingent valuation method. Resources for the future,
Washington D.C.

Mittermeier, R.A., Bowles, I.A., Cavalcanti, R.B., Olivieri, S., da Fonseca,


G.A.B. 1994 A participatory approach to biodiversity conservation:
The regional priority setting workshop. Conservation International,
Washington D.C.

105
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

Montgomery, C., Brown, G.M., Adams, D. 1994 The marginal cost of


species preservation: The Northern Spotted Owl. Journal of
Environmental Economics and Management. 26(2):111-128.

Moran, D. 1994 Contingent valuation and biodiversity conservation in


Kenyan protected areas. Biodiversity and Conservation, 3.

Morey, E.R., Shaw, W.D., Rowe, R.D. 1991 A discrete-choice model of


recreational participation, site choice, and the activity valuation when
complete trip data are not available. Journal of Environmental
Economics and Management 20:181-201.

Munasinghe, M. 1992 Economic and policy issues in natural habitat and


protected areas. World Bank, Washington D.C.

Munasinghe, M., Cruz, W., Warford, J. 1993 Are economy-wide policies


good for the environment? Finance and Development 30(3):40-43.

Myers, N. 1993 Questions of mass extinction. Biodiversity and


Conservation 2:2-17.

Myers, N. 1991 Biological diversity and global security. In: Bormann,


F.H. & Kellert, S.R. (eds.): Ecology, economics, ethics: The broken
circle. Yale University Press.

Myers, N. 1991 Tropical forests: present status and future outlook.


Climatic Change 19:3-32.

Myers, N. 1991 Tropical forests and climate. Climatic Change 19:1-2.

Myers, N. 1983 A wealth of wild species, storehouse for human welfare.


Westview Press, Boulder.

Newcombe, K. & de Lucia, R. 1993 Mobilising private capital against


global warming: a business concept and policy issues. Global
Environmental Facility, Washington D.C.

NOAA (National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration) 1994 Oil


pollution act of 1990: Proposed regulations for natural resource
damage assessments, US Department of Commerce.

106
Bibliography

Nordhaus, W. 1991 To slow or not to slow: The economics of the


greenhouse effect. American Economic Review 81(2):920-937.

Nordhaus, W. 1991 A sketch of economics of the greenhouse effect.


American Economic Review 81(2):146-150.

Norgaard, R.B. 1987 The economics of biological diversity: Apologetics


or theory? In: Southgate, D.D. & Disinger, J.F. (eds.): Sustainable
resource development in the Third World. Westview Press, Boulder -
London.

Norse, E.A. (ed.) 1993 Global marine biological diversity: A strategy for
building conservation into decision making. Island Press,
Washington D.C.

Norton, B.G. 1986 On the inherent danger of undervaluing species. In:


Norton, B.G. (ed.): The preservation of species. University Press,
Princeton.

Norton, B.G. 1984 Environmental ethics and weak anthropocentrism.


Environmental Ethics 6:131-148.

Norton, B.G. 1982 Environmental ethics and nonhuman rights.


Environmental Ethics 4:17-36.

Norton, B.G. & Ulanowocz, R.E. 1992 Scale and biodiversity policy: A
hierarchical approach. Ambio 21(3):244-249.

Noss, R.F., Cline, S., Csuti, B., Scott, M. 1992 Monitoring and assessing
biodiversity. In: Lykke, E. (ed.): Achieving environmental goals: The
concept and practice of environmental performance review.
Belhaven Press, London.

Nutzinger, H.G. & Zahrnt, A. (eds.) 1989 Ökosteuern. Umweltsteuern und


-abgaben in der Diskussion. C.F. Müller, Karlsruhe.

Oberndörfer, D. 1989 Schutz der tropischen Regenwälder durch


Entschuldung. Schriftenreihe des Bundeskanzleramts, Vol. 5, Beck,
Munich.

107
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

O'Connor, S. & Langrand, O. 1992 Can wildlife pay its way in


Madagascar? World Wildlife Fund for Nature, Madagascar.

OECD 1991 Environmental policy: How to apply economic instruments.


OECD, Paris.

OECD 1991 Responding to climate change: Selected economic issues.


OECD, Paris.

OECD 1989 Environmental policy benefits: Monentary evaluation.


Prepared by Pearce, D.W. & Markandya, A. OECD, Paris.

O'Hara, S. 1984 Externe Effekte der Stickstoffdüngung. Probleme ihrer


Bewertung und Ansätze zu ihrer Verminderung aus ökonomischer
Sicht. Vauk, Kiel.

Padoch, C. & de Jong, W. 1989 Production and profit in agroforestry: an


example from the Peruvian Amazon. In: Browder, J.G. (ed.): Fragile
lands of Latin America: Strategies for sustainable development.
Westview Press, Boulder.

Pearce, D.W. 1994 Capturing global environmental values. Centre for


Social and Economic Research on the Global Environment.
University College London and University of East Anglia, Norwich
and London.

Pearce, D.W. 1992 Discounting. In: Pearce, D.W., Whittington, J.,


Georgiou, S. (eds.): Manual of environmental projects and policy
appraisal. OECD, Paris.

Pearce, D.W. 1992 Assessing the social rate of return in temperate zone
forestry. Centre for Social and Economic Research on the Global
Environment, University College London and University of East
Anglia, Norwich and London.

Pearce, D.W. 1991 Economic valuation and the natural world. Earthscan,
London.

Pearce, D.W. (ed.) 1991 Blueprint 2: Greening the world economy.


Earthscan, London.
108
Bibliography

Pearce, D.W. 1991 Economic valuation and the natural world. Centre for
Social and Economic Research on the Global Environment,
University College London and University of East Anglia, Norwich.

Pearce, D.W. 1991 Deforesting the Amazon: Toward an economic


solution. Ecodecision 1:40-49.

Pearce, D.W. 1987 Foundations of an ecological economics. Ecological


Modelling 38:9-18.

Pearce, D.W. 1986 Cost-benefit analysis. Macmillan, Basingstoke.

Pearce, D.W. et al. 1993 Mexico forestry and conservation sector review:
substudy of economic valuation of forests. Report to Latin American
Technical Department, World Bank, Washington D.C.

Pearce, D.W., Bann, C., Georgiou, S. 1992 The social costs of fuel cycles.
Centre for Social and Economic Research on the Global
Environment, University College London.

Pearce, D.W. & Barbier, E.B. 1987 Forest policy in Indonesia. World
Bank, Washington D.C.

Pearce, D.W., Barbier, E.B., Markandya, A. 1990 Sustainable


development. Oxford University Press, Oxford - New York.

Pearce, D.W., Markandya, A., Barbier, E.B. 1989 Blueprint for a green
economy. Earthscan, London.

Pearce, D.W. & Nash, C.A. 1981 The social appraisal of projects.
Macmillan, London - Basingstoke.

Pearce, D.W. & Turner, R.K. 1990 Economics of natural resources and the
environment. Harvester Wheatsheaf, New York

Pearce, D.W. & Warford, J. 1992 World without end: Economics,


environment and sustainable development. Oxford University Press,
Oxford - New York.

Pearsall, S.H. III 1984 In absentia benefits of nature preserves: A review.


Environmental Conservation 11:3-10.
109
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

Perrings, C. 1995 The economic value of biodiversity. In: Heywood, V.,


Watson, R. (eds.): Global biodiversity assessment, 823-914.
Cambridge University Press.

Perrings, C. & Pearce, D.W. 1994 Threshold effects and incentives for the
conservation of biodiversity. Environmental and Resource
Economics 4:13-28.

Peterson, G.L. & Randall, A. (eds.) 1984 Valuation of wildland resource


benefits. Westview Press, Boulder - London.

Phillips, W.E., Adamowicz, W.L., Asafu-Adjaye, J., Boxall, P.C. 1989 An


economic assessment of the wildlife resource in Alberta. Project
Report no. 89-04, Alberta Recreation, Parks and Wildlife
Foundation.

Pinedo-Vasquez, M., Zarin, D., Jipp, P. 1992 Economic returns from forest
conversion in the Reuvian Amazon. Ecological Economics 6:163-
173.

Pister, W.P. 1979 Endangered species: Costs and benefits. Environmental


Ethics 1:341-352.

Porter, R.C. 1982 The new approach to wilderness preservation through


benefit-cost analysis. Journal of Environmental Economics and
Management 9:59-80.

Posner, B. et al. 1981 Economic impact analysis for the Virgin Island
Resources Foundation. St. Thomas, US Virgin Islands.

Principe, P. 1991 Monetizing the pharmacological benefits of plants. US


Environmental Protection Agency, Washington D.C.

Randall, A. 1988: What mainstream economists have to say about the value
of biodiversity. In: Wilson, E.O. (ed.): Biodiversity. National
Academy Press, Washington D.C.

Randall, A. 1987 Resource economics. John Wiley, New York

110
Bibliography

Randall, A. 1986 Human preferences, economics and the preservation of


species. In: Norton, B.G. (ed.): The preservation of species.
Princeton University Press.

Randall, A. & Stoll, J. 1983 Existence values in a total valuation


framework. In: Row, R.D. & Chestnut, L.G. (eds.): Managing air
quality and scenic resources at national parks and wilderness areas.
Westview Press, Boulder.

Raven, P. 1988 Our diminishing tropical forests. In: Wilson, E.O. (ed.):
Biodiversity. National Academy Press, Washington D.C.

Reed, D. 1991 The global environmental facility. Sharing responses for the
biosphere. Multilateral Development Bank Program, WWF
International, Washington D.C.

Rees, C. 1993 The ecologist's approach to sustainable development.


Finance and Development 30(4):14-15.

Reid, W.V. (ed.) 1993 Biodiversity prospecting: Using genetic resources


for sustainable development. World Resources Institute, Washington
D.C.

Reid, W.V. et al. 1992 Developing indicators of biodiversity conservation.


World Resources Institute, Draft report, Washington D.C.

Repetto, R. 1990 Die Entwaldung der Tropen: ein ökonomischer


Fehlschlag. Spektrum der Wissenschaft 6:122-129.

Repetto, R. 1988 The forest for the trees? Government policies and the
misuse of forest resources. World Resource Institute, Washington
D.C.

Repetto, R. 1986 World enough and time. Yale University Press, New
Haven.

Repetto, R. & Gillis, M. (eds.) 1988 Public policies and the misuse of
forest resources. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

111
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

Rich, B. 1994 Mortgaging the earth: The World Bank, environmental


impoverishment, and the crisis of development. Beacon Press,
Boston.

Rijsberman, F. 1991 Potential costs of adapting to sea level rise in OECD


countries. In: OECD (ed.): Environmental policy: How to apply
economic instruments. OECD, Paris.

Rosenthal, D. & Nelson, R. 1992 Why existence value should not be used
in cost-benefit analysis. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management
11(1):116-122.

Ruitenbeek, H.J. 1991 Mangrove management: An economic analysis of


management options with a focus on Bintuni Bay, Irian Jaya.
Ministry of State for Population and Environment, Jakarta.

Ruitenbeek, H.J. 1990 Economic analysis of tropical forest conservation


initiatives: Examples from West Africa, WWF.

Ruitenbeek, H.J. 1990 Evaluating economic policies for promoting


rainforest conservation in developing countries. Ph.D. thesis, London
School of Economics and Political Science.

Ruitenbeek, H.J. 1990 The rainforest supply price: A step towards


estimating a cost curve for rainforest conservation. The Development
Economics Research Programme, London School of Economics.

Samples, K., Dixon, J., Gowen, M. 1986 Information disclosure and


endangered species valuation. Land Economics 62:306-312.

Samples, K., Gowen, M., Dixon, J. 1986 The validity of the contingent
valuation method for estimating non-use components of preservation
values for unique natural resources. Paper presented to the American
Agricultural Economics Association, Reno.

Schäfer, A. 1988 Kosten-Nutzen-Analyse. Ex-post-Anwendung am


Beispiel der Rebflurbereinigung im Kaiserstuhl. Dissertation, Kassel.

112
Bibliography

Scheele, M. & Isermeyer, F. 1989 Umweltschutz und Landschaftspflege


im Bereich der Landwirtschaft - Kostenwirksame Verpflichtung oder
neue Einkommensquelle? Berichte über Landwirtschaft 67:86-110.

Schily, O. 1994 Flora, Fauna und Finanzen. Hoffmann und Campe,


Hamburg.

Schkade, D. & Payne, J.W. 1994 How people respond to contingent


valuation questions: A verbal protocol analysis of willingness to pay
for an environmental regulation. Journal of Environmental
Economics and Management 26:88-109.

Schmalensee, R. 1972 Option demand and consumer's surplus: Valuing


price changes under uncertainty. American Economic Review
62:813-824.

Schmitt, G. 1989 Die volkswirtschaftlichen Kosten der Agrarpolitik.


WISU 6:358-362.

Schneider, R. 1992 Brazil: An analysis of environmental problems and


policies in the Amazon. Report no. 91-04-BR, Latin America and
Caribbean Region, World Bank, Washington D.C.

Schramm, G. & Warford, J. (eds.) 1989 Environmental management and


economic development. A World Bank Publication, Washington
D.C.

Schreiber, H. 1989 "Debt-for-nature-swap" - An instrument against debt


and environmental destruction? Zeitschrift für Umweltpolitik und
Umweltrecht 12:331-352.

Schüller, A. (ed.) 1983 Property rights und ökonomische Theorie. Vahlen,


Munich.

Schulz, W. 1985 Der monetäre Wert besserer Luft. Lang, Frankfurt a.M.
u.a.

Schulze, E.-D. & Mooney, H.A. (eds.) 1993 Biodiversity and ecosystem
function. Springer Verlag, Berlin

113
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

Schulze, W.D. et al. 1983 Economic benefits of preserving visibility on the


national parklands of the Southwest. Natural Resources Journal 23.

Schulze, W.D., D'Arge, R.C., Brookshire, D.S. 1981 Valuing


environmental commodities: Some recent experiments. Land
Economics 57(2).

Schweppe-Kraft, B., Habeck, K., Schmitz, T. 1989 Ökonomische


Bewertung von Eingriffen in Natur und Landschaft. Am Beispiel
Industriegebiet Schichauweg. Landschaftsentwicklung und
Umweltforschung 60, Technische Universität Berlin.

Sedjo, R. 1987 The economics of natural and plantation forests in


Indonesia. Resources for the Future, Washington D.C.

Setzer, A.W. & Pereira, M.C. 1991 Amazonia biomass burnings in 1987
and an estimate of their tropospheric emissions. Ambio 20:19-22.

Shamsundar, P. & Kramer, R. 1993 Does contingent valuation work in


non-market economies? Centre for Resource and Environmental
Policy Research, Duke University, Durham, NC.

Sharma, N. 1992 Managing the world's forests. Kendall and Hunt,


Dubuque, Iowa

Simberloff, D. 1987 The Spotted Owl fracas: Mixing academic, applied,


and political ecology. Ecology 68:766-772.

Simberloff, D. 1986 Are we on the verge of a mass extinction in tropical


rain forests? In: Elliott, D.K. (ed.): Dynamics of extinction. John
Wiley, New York

Simonis, U.E. (ed.) 1988 Ökonomie und Ökologie. Auswege aus einem
Konflikt. Alternative Konzepte 33. C.F. Müller, Karlsruhe.

Sittenfield, A. & Gámez, R. 1993 Biodiversity-prospecting in InBio. Reid,


W.V. (ed.): Biodiversity prospecting: Using genetic resources for
sustainable development. World Resources Institute, Washington
D.C.

114
Bibliography

Smith, N.J.H. & Schuktes, R.E. 1990 Deforestation and shrinking crop
gene-pools in Amazonia. Environment and Conservation 17:227-
234.

Smith, V.K. 1987 Non-use values in benefit-cost analysis. Southern


Economic Journal 54:19-26.

Smith, V.K. 1983 Option value: A conceptual overview. Southern


Economic Journal 49:654-668.

Smith, V.K. & Desvousges, W.H. 1986 Measuring water quality benefits.
Kluwer-Nijhoff Publishing, Boston 54:19-26.

Smith, V.K. & Kaoru, Y. 1990 Signals or noise? Explaining the variation
in recreation benefit estimates. American Journal of Agricultural
Economics 72:419-433.

Soulé, M.E. (ed.) 1986 Conservation biology. The science of scarcity and
diversity. Sinauer, Sunderland, MA.

Southgate, D.D. & Disinger, J.F. (eds.) 1987 Sustainable resource


development in the Third World. Westview Press, Boulder - London.

Steer, A. & Lutz, E. 1993 Measuring environmentally sustainable


development. Finance and Development 30(4):20-23.

Steinlin, H. 1987 Kommerzielle Nutzung und Export von Holz aus


tropischen Feuchtwäldern. Allgemeine Forst- und Jagd-Zeitung
158:50-55.

Stevens, T.H., Echeverria, J., Glass, R.J., Hager, T., More, T.A. 1991
Measuring existence value of wildlife: What do CVM estimates
really show? Land Economics 67(4):390-400.

Ströbele, W. 1987 Rohstoffökonomik. Vahlen, Munich.

Swanson, T. 1991 The economics of natural habitat utilization: a survey of


the literature and issues. London Environmental Economics Centre.

Swanson, T.M. 1994 Biodiversity and intellectual property rights. In:


Perrings, C., Mäler, K.-G., Folke, C., Holling, C.S., Jansson, B.-O.
115
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

(eds.) Biodiversity loss: Ecological and economic issues. Cambridge


University Press, Cambridge.

Swanson, T. & Barbier, E. 1992 Economics for the wilds: Wildlife,


wildlands, diversity and development. Earthscan, London.

Tampe, K. & Hampicke, U. 1989 Die voraussichtliche Belastung der


öffentlichen Haushalte durch Ausgleichszahlungen an die Land- und
Forstwirtschaft aufgrund der geplanten Novellierung des §3b
BNatSchG. Gutachten im Auftrag des Bundesministers für Umwelt,
Naturschutz und Reaktorsicherheit. Kassel.

Thibodeau, F.R. & Ostro, B.D. 1981 An economic analysis of wetland


protection. Journal of Environmental Management 12:19-30.

Thomas, D.H.L., Ayache, F., Hollis, T. 1990 Use values and non-use
values in the conservation of Ichkeul National Park, Tunisia.
Environmental Conservation 18(2):119-130.

Tisdell, C.A. 1992 Environmental economic guidelines - Inter-country and


inter-regional requests for financial support for protected areas: What
factors, especially economic factors, might be important in ranking
these. University of Queensland, Brisbane.

Tisdell, C.A. 1990 Economics and the debate about preservation of


species, crop varieties and genetic diversity. Ecological Economics
2:77-90.

Tisdell, C.A. 1989 Environmental conservation: Economics, ecology and


ethics. Environmental Conservation 16:107-112.

Tisdell, C.A. 1983 An economist's critique of the world conservation


strategy with examples from the Australian experience.
Environmental Conservation 10:43-53.

Tisdell, C.A. 1982 Wild pigs: Environmental pest or economic resource?


Pergamon Press, Sydney.

Turner, R.K. (ed.) 1991 Economics and wetland management. Ambio


20:59-63.
116
Bibliography

Turner, R.K. 1988 Wetland conservation: Economics and ethics. In:


Collard, D., Pearce, D.W., Ulph, D. (eds.): Economics, growth and
sustainable environments. Essays in memory of Richard Lecomber.
Macmillan, Basingstoke - London, 121-159.

Turner, R.K. 1988 Sustainable environmental management. Belhaven


Press & Westview Press, London - Boulder.

Turner, R.K. & Brooke, J. 1988 Management and valuation of an


environmentally sensitive area: Norfolk broadland case study.
Environmental Management 12(3).

Turner, R.K. & Jones, T. (eds.) 1991 Wetlands: Market and intervention
failures. Four case studies. Earthscan, London.

Turner, R.K. & Mendelsohn, R. 1991 Valuing ecotourism in a tropical


rainforest reserve. Ambio 20(2):91-93.

Umana, Q.A. 1989 Debt relief for energy efficiency, conservation and
sustainability. Republic of Costa Rica, Washington D.C.

Umana, Q.A. 1987 Costa Rica swap debt for trees. Wall Street Journal 3.

UNEP 1992 Biodiversity country studies, synthesis report. UNEP, Nairobi.

UNEP 1992 Uganda: Country study on costs, benefits, and unmet needs of
biological diversity conservation. UNEP, Nairobi.

UNEP 1992 Bahamas: Country study on biodiversity; census, analysis,


conservation costs, benefits and unmet needs. UNEP, Nairobi.

UNEP 1992 Indonesian country study on biological diversity. UNEP,


Nairobi.

UNEP 1992 Country study report for Nigerian costs, benefits and unmet
needs of biological diversity conservation. UNEP, Nairobi.

van Dieren, W. (ed.) 1995 Taking nature into account. Springer Verlag,
New York.

117
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

Vincent, J. 1990 Rent capture and the feasibility of tropical forest


management. Land Economics 66(2):212-223.

Vogel, H. 1988 Naturschutzprogramme mit der Landwirtschaft in der


Bundesrepublik Deutschland - Übersicht. In: ABN (ed.): Jahrbuch
Naturschutz Landschaftspflege 41:183-195.

Walsh, R.G., Johnson, D.M., McKean, J.R. 1992 Benefit transfer of


outdoor recreation demand studies 1968-1988. Water Resources
Research 28(3):

Walsh, R.G., Loomis, J.B., Gillman, R.A. 1984 Valuing option, existence,
and bequest demands for wilderness. Land Economics 60:14-29.

Walsh, R.G. & Rosenthal, R.D. 1990 Estimating the public benefits of
protecting forest quality. Journal of Environmental Management
30:175-189.

Ward, N.I. & Brooks, R.R. 1978 Gold in some New Zealand plants. New
Zealand Journal of Botany 16:175-177.

Warren, D.M. 1991 Using indigeneous knowledge in agricultural


development. World Bank Discussion Paper no. 127.

Watson, D. 1988 The evolution of appropriate resource management


systems. In: Berkes, F. (ed.): Common property resources: Ecology
and community based sustainable development. Belhaven, London.

Webb, A., Lopez, M., Penn, R. 1990 Estimates of producer and consumer
subsidy equivalents: Government intervention in agriculture 1982-
1987. US Department of Agriculture Statistical Bulletin 803,
Washington D.C.

Weinberger, M., Thomassen, G., Willeke, R. 1991 Kosten des Lärms in


der Bundesrepublik Deutschland. Erich Schmidt Verlag, Berlin.

Weinschenck, G. 1986 Der ökonomische oder der ökologischecWeg?


Agrarwirtschaft 35:321-327.

118
Bibliography

Weinscheck, G. & Werner, R. 1989 Einkommenswirkingen ökologischer


Forderungen an die Landwirtschaft. Landwirtschaftliche
Rentenbank, Frankfurt am Main.

Wells, M. 1992 A summary of the benefits, costs and risks of using


environmental trust funds for biodiversity conservation.
Environmental Policy and Research Division, World Bank.

Wells, M. 1992 Biodiversity conservation, affluence and poverty:


Mismatched costs and benefits and efforts to remedy them. Ambio
21(3):237-243.

Wells, M. & Brandon, K. 1992 People and parks: Linking protected area
management with local communities. The World Bank, World Wide
Fund for Nature, US Agency for International Development.

Wendelaar, A., Pearce, D.W., Moran, D. 1994 Determining biodiversity


conservation priorities. Centre for Social and Economic Research on
the Global Environment, University College London and University
of East Anglia, Norwich.

Westman, W.E. 1977 How much are nature's services worth? Science
197:960-964.

Whittington, D. et al. 1991 Willingness to pay for improved sanitation in


Kumasi, Ghana: A contingent valuation study. In: Valuing
Environmental Benefits in Developing Economies. Michigan State
University, Special Report no. 29.

Wicke, L. 1991 Umweltökonomie. Eine praxisorientierte Einführung.


Vahlen, Munich.

Wicke, L. 1991 Umweltökonomie und Umweltpolitik. Beck/dtv, Munich.

Wilks, L.C. 1990 A survey of the contingent valuation method. Resource


Assessment Commission, RAC Research Paper no. 2. Australian
Government Publishing Service, Canberra.

Willis, K.G. & Corkindale, J.T. (eds.) 1995 Environmental valuation. CAB
International, Wallingford.
119
The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

Willis, K.G. 1993 The national oceanic and atmospheric administration


report on contingent valuation methods: some comments.
Department of Town and Country Planning, University of Newcastle
upon Tyne.

Willis, K.G. & Benson, J.F. 1988 Valuation of wildlife: A case study on
the Upper Teesdale site of special scientific interest and comparison
of methods in environmental economics. In: Turner, R.K. (ed.):
Sustainable environmental management. Belhaven Press &
Westview Press, London - Boulder.

Willis, K.G. & Garrod, G. 1991 Landscape values: A contingent valuation


approach and case study of the Yorkshire Dales National Park.
Countryside Change Working Paper 21, University of Newcastle
upon Tyne.

World Bank 1994 Making development sustainable: The World Bank


Group and the environment. Washington D.C.

World Bank 1994 Financing innovation and instruments. Contribution of


the investment portfolio of the pilot phase of the Global Environment
Facility. Paper presented to the Regional Conference on Biodiversity
Conservation. Asian Development Bank, 6-8 June 1994. Washington
D.C.

World Bank 1994 Implementing the convention on biological diversity.


Toward a strategy for World Bank assistance. Environment
Department. Washington D.C.

World Bank 1994 Incorporating social assessment and participation into


biodiversity conservation projects. Global Environment Coordination
Division and Environment Department, Washington D.C.

World Bank 1993 The environmental data book: A guide to statistics on


the environment and development. Washington D.C.

World Bank 1992 Strategy for forest sector development in Asia. World
Bank Technical Paper 182. Washington D.C.

120
Bibliography

World Bank 1992 The World Bank and the environment: Fiscal 1992.
Washington D.C.

World Bank 1992 World Development Report 1992. Development and the
environment. Oxford University Press, New York.

World Bank 1991 A World Bank operations evaluation study: Forestry:


The World Bank's experience. Washington D.C.

World Bank 1991 The forest sector. A World Bank policy paper.
Washington D.C.

World Bank 1989 World debt tables, external debt of developing countries
1982-1987. Washington D.C.

World Resources Institute 1992 World Resources 1992-1993. Oxford


University Press, Oxford.

World Resources Institute, The World Bank, United Nations Development


Programme 1985 Tropical forests: A call for action. Washington,
D.C.

World Wide Fund for Nature 1988 Debt for nature, an opportunity.
Philippines.

Young, A.M. 1986 Eco-enterprises: Eco-tourism and farming of exotics in


the tropics. Ambio 15:361-363.

Zilinskas, R.A. & Lundin, C. 1993 Marine biotechnology and developing


countries. World Bank discussion paper 210. Washington D.C.

121
Deutsche Gesellschaft für
Technische Zusammenarbeit (GTZ) GmbH
Tropenökologisches Begleitprogramm (TÖB)
Tropical Ecology Support Program
Postfach 5180
D-65726 Eschborn
Federal Republic of Germany
Fax: +49-(0)6196-79-6190
E-Mail: TOEB@gtz.de
World Wide Web: http://www.gtz.de/toeb
Im Auftrag des Bundesministeriums für wirtschaftliche
Zusammenarbeit und Entwicklung (BMZ)

Вам также может понравиться