Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 15

The Keynesian Model: Output - Principles of Micro - RIT - Dr.

Jerey Burnette

The Keynesian Model: Output


The Keynesian Model or Short Run Model
Assumptions Each market is analyzed on an aggregate scale (One interest rate, One type of labor, One type of output) Dierences from the Classical Model The Keynesian model does not assume that markets clear in the short-run. In fact, it believes that prices are sticky downward. That is, prices may not decrease to bring the market to equilibrium. This is why it focuses on the short-run. In the short-run spending depends upon income. Whereas the classical model focused on equilibrium in the labor market determining the level of output, the Keynesian model will focus on the domestic spending of consumers.

The Keynesian Model w/out Government


Households have 2 choices for spending their income, Purchase goods and services (Consumption) or Save. Firms have 2 types of expenditures, purchase goods and services (Consumption) or purchase equipment and structures from borrowed funds (Planned Investment). In the short-run, planned investment is taken to be independent of income. There is a funds market where savings is made available to rms that wish to borrow. Disposable Income = Income - Taxes Since there is no government, taxes are equal to zero. Therefore, real income is equal to real disposable income. Y = YD

The Keynesian Model: Output - Principles of Micro - RIT - Dr. Jerey Burnette

Consumption Function - Algebraic equation that describes the relationship between consumption and real (disposable) income. There is a positively sloped relationship between real consumption and spending and real (disposable) income.

C = f (Y ) = a + bY Where the intercept a is called autonomous consumption and the slope b is called the marginal propensity to consume. Autonomous Consumption - the part of consumption spending that is independent of income. This is the intercept of the consumption function. Marginal Propensity to Consume (MPC) - The amount by which consumption spending rises when (disposable) income rises by one dollar. This is the slope of the consumption function C Y

MP C =

(1)

In the above graph, autonomous consumption is 1000 So, when there is no income the total level of consumption is $1000. This $1000 must have come out of savings. The marginal propensity to consume is 0.80. In other words, if given an additional dollar of income there would be an increase in consumption of $0.80. Likewise, if income decreases by $1 then consumption would decrease by $0.80. The Savings Function- Algebraic equation that describes the relationship between savings and real (disposable) income. There is a positively sloped relationship between real consumption and spending and real (disposable) income. 2

The Keynesian Model: Output - Principles of Micro - RIT - Dr. Jerey Burnette

Marginal Propensity to Save (MPS) - The amount by which savings rises when (disposable) income rises by one dollar. This is the slope of the savings function. MP S = Deriving the Savings Function Since savings by denition is the amount left over income after consumption has taken place, we can represent savings as a function of income. S Y (2)

C +S or S Y C

(3)

We now have savings written solely as a function of income, because we know that consumption is a function of income. If the consumption function is known deriving the savings function is just a matter of algebra.

S = Y (a + bY ) = Y a bY = a + (1 b)Y Here the intercept is the same magnitude as autonomous consumption but it has a dierent sign. This is because when we have no income and still spend on consumption 3

The Keynesian Model: Output - Principles of Micro - RIT - Dr. Jerey Burnette

we must have gotten it from savings. The slope of the savings function, the MPS, is (1 - b) or (1 - MPC). This is due to the fact that any additional dollar of real (disposable) income must be spent either on consumption or savings.

MP C + MP S = 1

(4)

Example Given the consumption function of C = 1000 + 0.8Y we would like to know the savings function. We substitute the consumption function into equation (3). This gives us

S = Y (1000 + 0.8Y ) = Y 1000 0.8Y = 1000 + 0.2Y So, we nd that when income is equal to $0, consumption is $1000 and savings is -$1000. In addition, the MPC was 0.8 and the MPS is 0.2. So if given an additional dollar of income we will spend $0.80 and save $0.20, which of course sums to $1.

Solving for Equilibrium


The Keynesian Model denes equilibrium like the Classical Model. The total amount people want to purchase should be equal to the total amount rms want to produce.

AE = Y C +I = C +S I = S One major dierence here is that since we are dealing with the short run, we do not analyze the funds market. Firms have decided the amount of planned investment based upon the current interest rate and both are held constant. In our case we will assume that planned investment is equal to zero. Solving for equilibrium can be done in one of two ways; Using the consumption function or using the savings function. In both cases we will achieve the same result due to the fact that C + I = Y simplies down to I = S. 4

The Keynesian Model: Output - Principles of Micro - RIT - Dr. Jerey Burnette

The Consumption Route To solve for equilibrium using the consumption function we will use C + I = Y. Here we havent broken income into its two components from the equilibrium condition. Substituting our consumption function, the level of planned investment into our equilibrium condition and solving we have 1000 1000 Y

C +

0.8Y -0.8Y

+ +

I 0

= = = =

Y Y -0.8Y 0.2Y 5000

We can draw a line on the consumption function graph such that every point along the x-axis, in this case income, is equal to the same point on the y-axis, in this case aggregate expenditure. Since every point along this line requires that income is equal to aggregate expenditure this line represents all possible equilibrium points. Every equilibrium point will be on this line. Due to the fact that this line bisects our graph we call it the 45 line. In our example I = 0 so, aggregate expenditure is equal consumption. We will be in equilibrium if C = Y. So, where C crosses the 45 line is our equilibrium level of output. This happens when income is equal to 5000. When income is 5000, then consumption is 1000 + 0.8(5000) = 5000. So, consumption is equal to income and we are in equilibrium if planned investment is zero. The Savings Route To solve for equilibrium using the savings function we will use the simplied equilibrium condition, I = S. Substituting our savings function, the level of planned investment into our equilibrium condition and solving we have 5

The Keynesian Model: Output - Principles of Micro - RIT - Dr. Jerey Burnette

I 0 1000 Y

= = = =

S 1000 + 0.2Y 0.2Y 5000

Here again we nd that the equilibrium level of output is 5000. If we substitute 5000 into the savings function we should nd that Savings is equal to zero. S=-1000 + 0.2(5000)=0.

In the above graph, since investment is equal to zero we nd that we have equilibrium when the savings function crosses the x-axis. Example 2 In this example we will stick with the same consumption function, but planned investment is now equal to 100. C= 1000 + 0.8Y I = 100 The Consumption Route Substituting our consumption function, the level of planned investment into our equilibrium condition and solving we have

The Keynesian Model: Output - Principles of Micro - RIT - Dr. Jerey Burnette C + + I + 100 = = = = Y Y -0.8Y 0.2Y 5500

1000 1100

0.8Y -0.8Y

In our example I = 100 so, aggregate expenditure is equal consumption plus 100. We will be in equilibrium if C + I = Y. So, where C + I crosses the 45 line is the equilibrium level of income for this situation. This happens when income is equal to 5000. When income is 5500, then consumption is 1000 + 0.8(5500) = 5400 and Investment is equal to 100. So, consumption plus planned investment is equal 5500, and 5500 is the equilibrium level of output. You should notice that aggregate expenditure has shifted up by 100 for each level of income. This is because in the short-run investment is independent of income. The Savings Route Substituting our savings function, the level of planned investment into our equilibrium condition and solving we have

I 100 1100 Y

= = = =

S 1000 + 0.2Y 0.2Y 5500

Here again we nd that the equilibrium level of output is 5500. If we substitute 5500 into the savings function we should nd that Savings is equal to 100. S=-1000 + 0.2(5500)=100, which is equal to the level of investment. 7

The Keynesian Model: Output - Principles of Micro - RIT - Dr. Jerey Burnette

In the above graph, since investment is equal to 100 we nd that we have equilibrium when the savings function crosses the investment line. This happens when income is equal to 5500.

The Investment Multiplier


Notice that when we increased planned investment from 0 to 100 the equilibrium level of output increased from 5000 to 5500. This is no accident. A change in planned investment will result in a proportional change in the equilibrium level of output. In this case an increase of 100 in investment brought about an increase of 500 to output. Therefore, the investment multiplier is 5.

Im =

1 MP S

(5)

1 In our case the multiplier is Im = 0.2 = 5. Once the multiplier has been determined we can use it to calculate the new level of equilibrium instead of solving things via the equilibrium condition.

Y = Im I YN ew = YOld + Y

(6) (7)

1 In our case the change in the equilibrium level of income is equal to 0.2 100 = 5*100 = 500. We know that the old level of equilibrium was 5000 and that when investment is increased by 100 then equilibrium output increases by 500. So, the new level of output in equilibrium is 5000 + 500 = 5500. Exactly what we calculated earlier.

The Keynesian Model: Output - Principles of Micro - RIT - Dr. Jerey Burnette

The Keynesian Model w/ Government


Adding government to the Keynesian model is very similar to the addition of government in the classical model. The addition of government means that now there are household income divided three ways; Consumption and Saving as before, and Taxes paid to the government. There is no change in the types of expenditures by rms. While it is true that government does tax rms we will make the simplifying assumption that all government income is derived via a tax on households. The funds market now has three players, households, rms and the government. In the short-run, planned investment is taken to be independent of income. In the short-run, government expenditure is taken to be independent of income. There is a funds market where savings is made available to government and rms that wish to borrow. Using the above assumptions we can now dene aggregate expenditure and aggregate output.
Aggregate Expenditure (AE) = Consumption + Planned Investment + Government Expenditure = C + I + G Aggregate Output = Aggregate Income = Y = Consumption + Savings + Taxes = C + S + T

Disposable Income = YD = Y - T So, we will have equilibrium in the classical model if

AE = Y C +I +G = C +S+T I +G = S+T The Keynesian model diers due to its focus on the consumption functions dependence on income in the short-run. The problem with our equilibrium conditions above is that consumption and savings are functions of disposable income and not total income and we are interested in the equilibrium level of total income. So, we will have to do a little substitution. This is best demonstrated by using our example. We will add government in parts. First we will focus on the impact of government expenditure, then we will examine the impact of taxes. 9

The Keynesian Model: Output - Principles of Micro - RIT - Dr. Jerey Burnette

Example 2 Cont We now modify our example but keep the same consumption function, planned investment is 100 and we will assume government expenditure to be 100. In this example since taxes are equal to zero disposable income is equal to gross income. C= 1000 + 0.8YD I = 100 G = 100 T=0 The Consumption Route Substituting our consumption function, the level of planned investment into our equilibrium condition and solving we have C C + 0.8YD -0.8Y + + + I I 100 + + + = = G G 100 -0.8YD 0.2YD 6000 = Y D = Y -T = YD - T

1000 1200

YD

In our example I = 100, and G = 100 so, aggregate expenditure is equal consumption plus 200. We will be in equilibrium if C + I + G = Y. Again, since T = 0, YD = Y. The addition of government is very similar to adding planned investment. The aggregate expenditure shifts up by another 100 above the initial level when G was equal to zero. The Savings Route Substituting our savings function, the level of planned investment into our equilibrium condition and solving we have 10

The Keynesian Model: Output - Principles of Micro - RIT - Dr. Jerey Burnette

I +G 100 + 100 1200 Y D

= = = =

S+T 1000 + 0.2Y D + 0 0.2Y D 6000

Here again we nd that the equilibrium level of output is 6000. If we substitute 6000 into the savings function we should nd that Savings is equal to 100. S=-1000 + 0.2(6000)=200.

The Government Multiplier


Notice that when we added government and it went from 0 to 100 the equilibrium level of output increased from 5500 to 6000. This is no accident. A change in government expenditure will result in a proportional change to the equilibrium level of output. In this case an increase of 100 in government expenditure brought about an increase of 500 to output. Here the government multiplier is 5. 1 MP S

Gm =

(8)

1 In our case the multiplier is Gm = 0.2 = 5. Once the multiplier has been determined we can use it to calculate the new level of equilibrium instead of solving things via the equilibrium condition.

= Gm G

(9)

1 In our case the change in the equilibrium level of income is equal to 0.2 100 = 5*100 = 500. We know that the old level of equilibrium was 5500 and that when government expenditure is increased by 100 then equilibrium output increases by 500. So, the new level of output in equilibrium is 5500 + 500 = 6000. Exactly what we calculated earlier.

Adding Taxes In the above case with government, YD = Y. So we didnt need to substitute to get the equilibrium level of income. Adding taxes is dierent from adding government or investment spending in that investment and government spending are direct injections into the economy. Taxes are more of an indirect injection in that changing taxes changes the consumption function. If the government lowers taxes only a percentage of this change in taxes will be spent due to the marginal propensity to consume. 11

The Keynesian Model: Output - Principles of Micro - RIT - Dr. Jerey Burnette C = = = = a + bYD a + b(Y-T) a + bY - bT a - bT + bY

Ocially, the consumption is a function of disposable income and not gross income, however we can rewrite it as a function of gross income to nd equilibrium. Example 2 Cont Again we modify our example we keep the same consumption function, planned investment is 100 and government expenditure is 100, but now taxes are assumed to be 100. C= 1000 + 0.8YD I = 100 G = 100 T = 100 Following the steps for substituting taxes into the consumption function we get C = 1000 = 1000 = 1000 = 1000 - 80 = 920 + 0.8YD + 0.8(Y-100) + 0.8Y - 80 + 0.8Y + 0.8Y

The Consumption Route Since we just substituted taxes into the consumption function we dont need to modify the right hand side of the equilibrium condition. C + + + I 100 + + = = G = Y 100 = Y -0.8Y 0.2Y 5600

920 1120

0.8Y -0.8Y

12

The Keynesian Model: Output - Principles of Micro - RIT - Dr. Jerey Burnette

In our example I = 100, and G = 100 so, aggregate expenditure is equal consumption plus 200. We will be in equilibrium if C + I + G = Y. Since T = 100, YD = Y - 100, and therefore the equilibrium level of disposable income is YD = 5500. The Savings Route Substituting our savings function, the level of planned investment into our equilibrium condition and solving we have

I +G 100 + 100 1100 Y D Y

= = = = =

S+T 1000 + 0.2Y D + 100 0.2Y D 5500 5600

The Tax Multiplier


Notice that when we added taxes and they went from 0 to 100 the equilibrium level of output decreased from 6000 to 5600. This is no accident. A change in taxes will result in a proportional change in the equilibrium level of output. In this case an increase of 100 to taxes brought about a decrease of 400 in output. Here the government multiplier is -4. M P C MP S

Tm =

(10)

In our case the multiplier is Tm = 0.8 = -4. Once the multiplier has been determined 0.2 we can use it to calculate the new level of equilibrium instead of solving things via the equilibrium condition. 13

The Keynesian Model: Output - Principles of Micro - RIT - Dr. Jerey Burnette

= Tm T

(11)

In our case the change in the equilibrium level of income is equal to 0.8 100 = -4*100 = 0.2 -400. We know that the old level of equilibrium was 6000 and that when taxes are increased by 100 then equilibrium output decreases by 400. So, the new level of output in equilibrium is 6000 - 400 = 5600. Exactly what we calculated earlier. There is a relationship between the government spending and tax multipliers. Like the MPC and MPS they sum to 1.

Gm + Tm = = =

M P C 1 + MP S MP S 1 MP C MP S MP S MP S (12)

Gm + Tm = 1

Okuns Law - There is a correlation between output and the unemployment rate. A 1 percentage point change in the unemployment rate is associated with a 2 percent change of output in the opposite direction.

14

The Keynesian Model: Output - Principles of Micro - RIT - Dr. Jerey Burnette

Sample Problem 1. In the Keynesian cross assume the following information: C = 1200 + 0.6 YD I = 300 G = 200 T = 100

(a) What is the equilibrium level of income, consumption, savings and disposable income? (b) Graph consumption and aggregate expenditure as a function of Y (not YD ) and demonstrate the equilibrium values of consumption and income you calculated in (a). (c) Assume that the level of output is 3200. Explain how the economy adjusts to equilibrium. Specically mention inventory levels. Demonstrate this on your graph in (a). (d) The Presidents Council of Economic Advisors anticipate private investment to decrease by $150. By how much would the government need to change taxes to prevent the looming recession? (e) What would happen to this economy if society becomes more thrifty and saves more at each level of income? Why do you suppose this result is called the paradox of thrift?

15

Вам также может понравиться