Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 26

Game Theory

Necessity Never Made

a Good Bargain.
- Benjamin Franklin

Mike Shor
Lecture 13

Economics

Allocation of scarce resources

Many buyers & many sellers


traditional markets

Many buyers & one seller


auctions

One buyer & one seller


bargaining
Game Theory - Mik

Role of Game Theory

Design non-traditional markets

Market Design, Inc.


Charles River Associates
NERA Economic Consulting
Open Options
LECG
Game Theory - Mik

The Move to GameTheoretic Bargaining

Baseball

Meet-in-the-Middle

Each side submits an offer to an arbitrator who


must chose one of the proposed results
Each side proposes its worst acceptable offer
and a deal is struck in the middle, if possible

Forced Final

If an agreement is not reached by some


deadline, one party makes a final take-it-orleave-it offer

Game Theory - Mik

Bargaining & Game Theory

Art:

Negotiation

Science:

Bargaining

CAVEAT: Limited Applicability

Game Theory - Mik

The Contribution
of Game Theory

Importance of rules:
The rules of the game
determine the outcome

Diminishing pies:
The importance of patience

Estimating payoffs:
Trust your intuition
Game Theory - Mik

Take-it-or-leave-it Offers
Consider the following bargaining
game over a cake:
I name a take-it-or-leave-it split.
If you accept, we trade
If you reject, no one eats!

Under perfect information, there is a


simple rollback equilibrium
Game Theory - Mik

Take-it-or-leave-it Offers

accept

1-p , p

reject

0,0

Game Theory - Mik

Rollback

Consider the subgame:


Accept: 1-p , p
Reject: 0 ,
0

You will accept if p>0,


reject otherwise
Rollback: I will offer the smallest
acceptable piece (i.e. almost none)

What if you make the take-it-orleave-it offer?


Game Theory - Mik

Take-it-or-leave-it Offers
Simple to solve
Unique outcome
Unrealistic

Ignore real bargaining


Assume perfect information
Not credible
If you reject my offer,
will I really just walk away?

Game Theory - Mik

10

Counteroffers and
Diminishing Pies

In general, bargaining takes on a take-itor-counteroffer procedure

If time has value, both parties prefer


trade earlier to trade later

E.g. Labor negotiations


later agreements come at a price
of strikes, work stoppages, etc.
Game Theory - Mik

11

Multi-stage Bargaining

Bargaining over division of a cake

I offer a proportion, p, of the cake


If rejected, you counteroffer
(and of the cake melts)
Payoffs:
In first period: 1-p , p
In second period: (1-)(1-p) , (1-)p

Game Theory - Mik

12

Rollback
What happens in period 2?
Since 2 is the final period, this is
just like a take-it-or-leave-it offer:

You will offer me the lowest price that I


will accept, leaving you with all of 1-
and leaving me with almost 0

What do I do in the first period?


Game Theory - Mik

13

Rollback

Give you at least as much surplus


Your surplus if you accept
in the first period is p

Accept if:

Your surplus in first period


Your surplus in second period
p 1-
Game Theory - Mik

14

Equilibrium

If there is a second stage,


you get 1- and I get 0.

You will reject any offer in the first stage


that does not offer you at least 1-.

In the first period, I offer you 1-.

Note: the more patient you are (the


slower the cake melts) the more you
receive now!
Game Theory - Mik

15

First or Second Mover


Advantage?

Are you better off being the first to


make an offer, or the second?

Game Theory - Mik

16

Example: Cold Day


If =1/5 (20% melts)
Period 2: You offer a division of 1,0

You get
I get

all of remaining cake


0

= 0.8
=0

In the first period, I offer 80%


You get
I get

80% of whole cake


20% of whole cake

Game Theory - Mik

= 0.8
= 0.2

17

Example: Hot Day


If =4/5 (80% melts)
Period 2: You offer a division of 1,0

You get
I get

all of remaining cake


0

= 0.2
=0

In the first period, I offer 20%


You get
I get

20% of whole cake


80% of whole cake

Game Theory - Mik

= 0.2
= 0.8

18

First or Second Mover


Advantage?
Who has the advantage?
Depends on the value of the future!

If players are patient:


Second mover is better off!

If players are impatient


First mover is better off!
Game Theory - Mik

19

Information
COMMANDMENT
In any bargaining setting,
strike a deal as early as possible!

Why doesnt this happen?


Time has no meaning
Lack of information about values!
Reputation-building in repeated settings!
Game Theory - Mik

20

Examples

British Pubs and American Bars

Civil Lawsuits
If both parties can predict the future jury
award, can settle for same outcome and
save litigation fees and time
If both parties are sufficiently optimistic,
they do not envision gains from trade

Game Theory - Mik

21

Uncertainty I:
Civil Trial
Plaintiff sues defendant for $1M
Legal fees cost each side $100,000
If each agrees that the chance of the
plaintiff winning is :

Plaintiff: $500K-$100K = $ 400K


Defendant:
-$500K-$100K = $-600K

If simply agree on the expected


winnings, $500K, each is better off
Game Theory - Mik

22

Civil Trial
What if both parties are too
optimistic?
Each thinks that their side has a
chance of winning:

Plaintiff:
Defendant:

$750K-$100K = $ 650K
-$250K-$100K = $-350K

No way to agree on a settlement!


Game Theory - Mik

23

Uncertainty II:
Non-monetary Utility

Labor negotiations are often a simple


game of splitting a known surplus

Company will profit $200K


how much of this goes to labor?

Rules of the bargaining game uniquely


determine the outcome if money is the
only consideration
Game Theory - Mik

24

Non-monetary Utility

Each side has a reservation price


Like in civil suit: expectation of winning

The reservation price is unknown


One must:

Consider non-monetary payoffs


Probabilistically determine best offer
But probability implies a chance that no
bargain will be made
Game Theory - Mik

25

Lessons

Rules of the game uniquely


determine the bargaining outcome

Which rules are better for you


depends on patience, information

Delays are always less profitable:


Someone must be wrong
Game Theory - Mik

26

Вам также может понравиться