Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 49

Chapter Four

Consumer
Choice

Consumer Choice
In this chapter, we examine four main
topics.
Preferences
Utility
Budget constraint
Constrained consumer choice

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

42

Preferences
To explain consumer behavior,
economists assume that consumers
have a set of tastes or preferences that
they use to guide them in choosing
between goods. These tastes differ
substantially among individuals.

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

43

Properties of Consumer
Preferences
Economists make three critical
assumptions about the properties of
consumers preferences. For brevity,
these properties are referred to as
completeness, transitivity, and more is
better.

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

44

Completeness
The completeness property holds that,
when facing a choice between any two
bundles of goods, a consumer can rank
them so that one and only one of the
following relationships is true: The
consumer prefers the first bundle to the
second, prefers the second to the first,
or is indifferent between them.

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

45

Transitivity
The transitivity (or what some people refer to
as rationality) property is that a consumers
preferences over bundles is consistent in the
sense that, if the consumer weakly prefers
Bundle z to Bundle y (like z at least as
much as y ) and weakly prefers Bundle y to
Bundle x , the consumer also weakly prefers
Bundle z to Bundle x .

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

46

More is Better
The more-is-better property holds that,
all else the same, more of a commodity
is better than less of it (always wanting
more is known as nonsatiation).

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

47

Properties of Consumer
Preferences
good
a commodity for which more is preferred to
less, at least at some levels of
consumption

bad
something for which less is preferred to
more, such as pollution

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

48

Preference Maps
One of the simplest ways to summarize
information about a consumers
preferences is to create a graphical
interpretationa mapof them.

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

49

Preference Maps
indifference curve
the set of all bundles of goods that a
consumer views as being equally desirable

indifference map (or preference map)


a complete set of indifference curves that
summarize a consumers tastes or
preferences

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

410

Indifference Curves
All indifference curve maps must have
four important properties:
Bundles on indifference curves farther from
the origin are preferred to those on
indifference curves closer to the origin.
There is an indifference curve through
every possible bundle.
Indifference curve cannot cross.
Indifference curves slope downward.
2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

411

Figure 4.1 Bundles of Pizzas and


Burritos Lisa Might Consume
(a)

(b)
A

25

20
15
10

c
f

20
e

15

e
d

25

a
b

10

a
b

I1

5
B
15

25 30
Z, Pizzas per semester

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

15

25 30
Z, Pizzas per semester

412

Figure 4.1 Bundles of Pizzas and


Burritos Lisa Might Consume (contd)
(c)

25

c
f

20
15
10

I2

e
d

I1

I0
15

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

25
30
Z, Pizzas per semester

413

Figure 4.2
Impossible Indifference Curves
(a) Crossing

(b) Upward Sloping

b
a

I1
I0

Z, Pizzas per semester

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Z, Pizzas per semester

414

Figure 4.2 Impossible Indifference


Curves (contd)
(c) Thick

b
a

Z, Pizzas per semester

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

415

Willingness to Substitute Between


Goods
Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS)
the maximum amount of one good a
consumer will sacrifice to obtain one more
unit of another good

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

416

Willingness to Substitute Between


Goods
The marginal rate of substitution of burritos
for pizza is

B
MRS
Z

where Z is the number of pizzas Lisa will


give up to get B more burritos or vice versa
and pizza (Z) is on the horizontal axis. The
marginal rate of substitution is the slope of
the indifference curve.

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

417

Curvature of Indifference Curves


An indifference curve doesnt have to
be convex, but casual observation
suggests that most peoples
indifference curves are convex. When
people have a lot of one good, they are
willing to give up a relatively large
amount of it to get a good of which they
have relatively little. However, after that
first trade, they are willing to give up
less of the first good to get the same
amount more of the second good.
2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

418

Curvature of Indifference Curves


This willingness to trade fewer burritos
for one more pizza as we move down
and to the right along the indifference
curve reflects a diminishing marginal
rate of substitution: The marginal rate of
substitution approaches zero as we
move down and to the right along an
indifference curve.

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

419

Figure 4.3 Marginal Rate of


Substitution
(a) Indifference Curve Convex to the Origin

3
2

3
5

(b) Indifference Curve Concave to the Origin

b
1
2

d
1

1
3

c
1
1

3 4 5 6
Z, Pizzas per semester

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

c
1

3 4 5 6
Z, Pizzas per semester

420

Curvature of Indifference Curves


Perfect Substitutes
goods that a consumer is completely
indifferent as to which to consume

Perfect Complements
goods that a consumer is interested in
consuming only in fixed proportions

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

421

Figure 4.4 Perfect Substitutes, Perfect


Complements, Imperfect Substitutes
(a) Perfect Substitutes

(b) Perfect Complements

4
3

1
I1

I2

I3

d
a

I3
I2
I1

I4

1
2
3
4
Pepsi, Cans per week

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

2
3
Pie, Slices per week

422

Figure 4.4 Perfect Substitutes, Perfect


Complements, Imperfect Substitutes
(contd)
(c) Imperfect Substitutes

I
Z, Pizzas per semester

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

423

Application (Page 83) Indifference


Curves Between Food and Clothing

I4

I3
I2
I1
Clothing per year
2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

424

Utility
Utility
a set of numerical values that reflect the
relative rankings of various bundles of
goods

Utility Function
the relationship between utility values and
every possible bundle of goods

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

425

Ordinal Preferences
If we know only consumers relative
rankings of bundles, our measure of
pleasure is ordinal rather than cardinal. An
ordinal measure is one that tells us the
relative ranking of two things but not how
much more one rank is than another.
Because utility is an ordinal measure, we
should not put any weight on the absolute
differences between the utility associated
with one bundle and another. We care only
about the relative utility or ranking of the
two bundles.
2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

426

Utility and Marginal Utility


Marginal Utility
the extra utility that a consumer gets from
consuming the last unit of a good

Thus marginal utility is the slope of the


utility function
U
MU Z
Z

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

427

Figure 4.5
Utility and
Marginal Utility

(a) Utility
350

Utility function, U (10, Z )

250
230

Z =1

U = 20

(b) Marginal Utility

7
8
9
10
Z, Pizzas per semester

130

20
0
2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

MUZ
1

7
8
9
10
Z, Pizzas per semester
428

Utility and Marginal Rates of


Substitution
The marginal rate of substitution (MRS)
is the slope of the indifference curve.
The marginal rate of substitution can
also be expressed in terms of marginal
utilities.
The marginal rate of substitution can be
written as
(4.1)

B
MU Z
MRS

Z
MU B

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

429

Budget Constraint
Consumers maximize their well-being
subject to constraints. The most
important constraint most of us face in
deciding what to consume is our
personal budget constraint.
For simplicity, we assume that each
consumer has a fixed amount of money
to spend now, so we can use the terms
budget and income interchangeably.
2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

430

Budget Constraint
If Lisa spends all her budget, Y, on pizza and
burritos, then

p B B pZ Z Y

(4.2)

where pB B is the amount she spends on


burritos and pZ Z is the amount she spends
on pizzas.

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

431

Budget Constraint
Budget Line (or Budget Constraint)
the bundles of goods that can be bought if
the entire budget is spent on those goods
at given prices

Opportunity Set
all the bundles a consumer can buy,
including all the bundles inside the budget
constraint and on the budget constraint

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

432

Slope of the Budget Constraint


Marginal Rate of Transformation (MRT)
the trade-off the market imposes on the
consumer in terms of the amount of one
good the consumer must give up to obtain
more of the other good

The marginal rate of transformation is


the rate at which Lisa can trade burritos
for pizza in the marketplace:
pZ
B
MRT

Z
pB
2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

(4.5)
433

Table 4.1 Allocations of a $50


Budget Between Burritos and Pizza

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

434

Figure 4.6 Budget Constraint

25 = Y/p B
20

10

a
b
L1 (p Z = $1, Y = $50)
c
Opportunity set
d

10

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

30

50 = Y/p Z
Z, Pizzas per semester

435

Effect of A Change in Price on


Consumption
If the price of pizza doubles but the
price of burritos is unchanged, the
budget constraint swings in toward the
origin in panel a of Figure 4.7.

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

436

Figure 4.7 Changes in the


Budget Constraint
(a) Price of Pizza Doubles

(b) Income Doubles

50

25

L3 ( Y = $100)
L1 (p Z = $1)
25
Loss

Gain
L1 (Y = $50)

L 2 (p Z = $2)
0

25
50
Z, Pizzas per semester

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

50
100
Z, Pizzas per semester

437

Effect of a Change in Income on


Consumption
If the consumers income increases, the
consumer can buy more of all goods.
The budget constraint shifts outward
away from the originand is parallel to
the origin constraint in panel b of Figure
4.7.
A change in income affects only the
position and not the slope of the budget
line. The slope is determined solely by
the relative prices of pizza and burritos.
2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

438

Page 91 Solved Problem 4.2


Quota

Budget line

A
0

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

B
10
12
Water, Thousand gallons per month

439

The Consumers Optimal Bundle


The optimal bundle must be on the budget
constraint. Bundles that lie on indifference
curves above the constraint, such as those
on I3, are not in the opportunity set.
For any bundle inside the constraint (such
as d on I1), there is another bundle on the
constraint with more of at least one of the
two goods, and hence she prefers that
bundle. Therefore, the optimal bundle
must lie on the budget constraint.
2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

440

The Consumers Optimal Bundle


Bundles that lie on indifference curves that cross
the budget constraint (such as I1, which crosses
the constraint at
and )aare lessc desirable
than certain other bundles on the constraint.
Thus the optimal bundle must lie on the budget
constraint and be on an indifference curve that
does not cross it. Such a bundle is the
consumers optimum.
The optimal bundle must lie on an indifference
curve that touches the budget constraint but
does not cross it.
2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

441

Figure 4.8
Consumer
Maximization

(a) Interior Solution


Budget line

g
25

20

10

A
0

10

30

(b) Corner Solution

25

I3
I2
I1

50
Z, Pizzas per semester

I3
I2
Budget line

I1
50
Z, Pizzas per semester

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

442

Interior Solution
For the indifference curve I2 to touch the
budget constraint but not cross it, it must be
tangent to the budget constraint: The budget
constraint and the indifference curve have the
same slope at the point e where they touch.
MU Z
pZ
MRS

MRT
MU B
pB

Rearranging terms, this condition is


equivalent to
MU Z MU B

pZ
pB
2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

(4.6)
443

Page 95 Solved Problem 4.3


Corner Solution
1

eN

l
LB

LN

eB
1
SUVs per decade

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

444

Figure 4.9 Optimal Bundles on Convex


Sections of Indifference Curves
(a) Strictly Concave Indifference Curves

(b) Concave and Convex Indifference Curves

e
Budget
line

Budget
line
d

e
I1

I2

I3

Z, Pizzas per semester

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

I2
I1
Z, Pizzas per semester

445

Buying Where More is Better


If both goods are consumed in positive
quantities and their prices are positive, more
of either good must be preferred to less.
In summary, we do not observe consumer
optima at bundles where indifference curves
are concave or consumers are satiated.
Thus we can safely assume that indifference
curves are convex and that consumers
prefer more to less in the ranges of goods
that we actually observe.

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

446

Page 98 Solved Problem 4.4


LF

LA

a
I1

I2

American meals per year


2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

447

Food Stamps
Cash preferred to food stamps
Poor people who receive cash have more
choices than those who receive a
comparable amount of food stamps.

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

448

Figure 4.10 Food Stamps


Versus Cash
Budget line with cash

Y + 100

f
C

I3

I2

I1
B
A

Original
budget line
100

Budget line with


food stamps

Y + 100
Food per month

2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

449

Вам также может понравиться