Вы находитесь на странице: 1из 109

THE ORDINAL THEORY: Indifference Curve Approach (CONSUMER CHOICE)

UNIT 8

The Theory of Consumer Choice


Is utility measurable? Cardinal theory says that it is measurable just as price and quantities are. We can assign a number of units to each commodity. For example, an orange=5 units & an apple= 6 units. The Ordinal theory says that utility is not measurable like prices & quantities. We can only say whether the utility of an orange is less than, equal to, or greater than the utility of an apple.

The Budget Constraint

The budget constraint depicts the consumption bundles that a consumer can afford.
People consume less than they desire because

their spending is constrained, or limited, by their income.

The Budget Constraint

It shows the various combinations of goods the consumer can afford given his or her income and the prices of the two goods.

The Budget Constraint


Pints of Pepsi 0 50 100 150 200 250 300 350 400 450 500 Number of Pizzas 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 Spending on Pepsi Spending on Pizza Total Spending

The Budget Constraint


Pints of Pepsi 0 50 100 150 200 250 300 350 400 450 500 Number of Pizzas 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 Spending on Pepsi $ 0 100 200 300 400 500 600 700 800 900 1,000 Spending on Pizza $1,000 900 800 700 600 500 400 300 200 100 0

The Budget Constraint


Pints of Pepsi 0 50 100 150 200 250 300 350 400 450 500 Number of Pizzas 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 Spending on Pepsi $ 0 100 200 300 400 500 600 700 800 900 1,000 Spending on Pizza $1,000 900 800 700 600 500 400 300 200 100 0 Total Spending $1,000 1,000 1,000 1,000 1,000 1,000 1,000 1,000 1,000 1,000 1,000

The Budget Constraint Line

Any point on the budget constraint line indicates the consumers combination or trade-off between two goods. For example, if the consumer buys no pizzas, he can afford 500 litres of Pepsi. If he buys no Pepsi, he can afford 100 pizzas.

The Budget Constraint Line


Quantity of Pepsi 500

250

50

100

Quantity of Pizza

The Budget Constraint Line


Quantity of Pepsi 500

250

50

A 100

Quantity of Pizza

The Budget Constraint Line


Quantity of Pepsi 500

250

Consumers budget constraint


A 100

50

Quantity of Pizza

The Budget Constraint Line

Alternately, the consumer can buy 50 pizzas and 250 litres of Pepsi.

The Budget Constraint Line


Quantity of Pepsi 500

250

Consumers budget constraint


A 100

50

Quantity of Pizza

The Budget Constraint Line

The slope of the budget constraint line equals the relative price of the two goods, that is, the price of one good compared to the price of the other.

The Budget Constraint Line

It measures the rate at which the consumer will trade one good for the other.

Preferences: What the Consumer Wants

A consumers preference among consumption bundles may be illustrated with indifference curves.

Preferences: What the Consumer Wants

An indifference curve shows bundles of goods that leave the consumer equally satisfied. Indifference Curve Approach developed by Hicks and Allen.

Indifference Curves
Quantity of Pepsi

Quantity of Pizza

Indifference Curves
Quantity of Pepsi

Indifference curve, I1 0 Quantity of Pizza

Indifference Curves

The consumer is indifferent, or equally happy, with the combinations shown at points A, B, and C because they are all on the same curve.

Indifference Curves
Quantity of Pepsi

Indifference curve, I1 0 Quantity of Pizza

Indifference Curves
Quantity of Pepsi C

A 0

Indifference curve, I1 Quantity of Pizza

The Marginal Rate of Substitution

The slope at any point on an indifference curve is the marginal rate of substitution. It is the rate at which a consumer is willing to trade one good for another. It is the amount of one good that a consumer requires as compensation to give up one unit of the other good.

Indifference Curves
Quantity of Pepsi

Indifference curve, I1 0 Quantity of Pizza

Indifference Curves
Quantity of Pepsi

Slope Indifference curve, I1 0 Quantity of Pizza

The Marginal Rate of Substitution


Quantity of Pepsi

Indifference curve, I1 0 Quantity of Pizza

The Marginal Rate of Substitution


Quantity of Pepsi

MRS 1 Indifference curve, I1 0 Quantity of Pizza

Properties of Indifference Curves

Higher indifference curves are preferred to lower ones.

Indifference curves are downward sloping. Indifference curves do not cross. Indifference curves are bowed inward.

Higher indifference curves are preferred to lower ones.

Consumers usually prefer more of something to less of it. Higher indifference curves represent larger quantities of goods than do lower indifference curves.

Indifference Curves
Quantity of Pepsi

Indifference curve, I1 0 Quantity of Pizza

Indifference Curves
Quantity of Pepsi

I2 Indifference curve, I1 0 Quantity of Pizza

Indifference Curves
Quantity of Pepsi C

B I2 A 0 Indifference curve, I1 Quantity of Pizza

Indifference Curves
Quantity of Pepsi C

D I2 A Indifference curve, I1 Quantity of Pizza

Indifference curves are downward sloping.

A consumer is willing to give up one good only if he or she gets more of the other good. If the quantity of one good is reduced, the quantity of the other good must increase. For this reason, most indifference curves slope downward.

Indifference curves are downward sloping.


Quantity of Pepsi

Indifference curve, I1 0 Quantity of Pizza

Indifference curves do not cross.

In order for preference rankings to be consistent, indifference curves cannot intersect or cross. If indifference curves were to cross the assumption that more is preferred to less would be violated.

Indifference curves do not cross.


Quantity of Pepsi

C A B

Quantity of Pizza

Indifference curves are bowed inward.

People are more willing to trade away goods that they have in abundance and less willing to trade away goods of which they have little. These differences in a consumers marginal substitution rates causes his or her indifference curve to bow inward.

Indifference curves are bowed inward.


Quantity of Pepsi

Quantity of Pizza

Indifference curves are bowed inward.


Quantity of Pepsi

Indifference curve 0 Quantity of Pizza

Indifference curves are bowed inward.


Quantity of Pepsi 14

Indifference curve 0 2 3 Quantity of Pizza

Indifference curves are bowed inward.


Quantity of Pepsi 14 MRS = 6 8 A 1

Indifference curve 0 2 3 Quantity of Pizza

Indifference curves are bowed inward.


Quantity of Pepsi 14 MRS = 6 8 A 1

4 3 0 2 3 6 7

B Indifference curve Quantity of Pizza

Indifference curves are bowed inward.


Quantity of Pepsi 14 MRS = 6 8 A 1

4 3 0 2 3

MRS = 1

1
6 7

Indifference curve Quantity of Pizza

Extreme Indifference Curves


Perfect substitutes Perfect complements

Perfect Substitutes

Two goods with straight-line indifference curves are perfect substitutes. The marginal rate of substitution is constant.

Perfect Substitutes
10-cent coins
6

2 I1 0 1 I2 2 I3 3 20-cent coins

Perfect Complements

Two goods with right-angle indifference curves are perfect complements.

Perfect Complements
Left Shoes

7 5

I2 I1

Right Shoes

Optimisation: What the Consumer Chooses

Consumers want to get the combination of goods on the highest possible indifference curve. However, the budget constraint may restrict or limit the consumer to a lower indifference curve.

Optimisation: What the Consumer Chooses

Combining the indifference curve and the budget constraint determines the consumers optimal choice.

The Consumers Optimal Choice

Consumer optimum occurs at the point where the highest indifference curve and the budget constraint are tangent.

The Consumers Optimal Choice

The consumer chooses consumption of the two goods so that the marginal rate of substitution equals the relative price.

The Consumers Optimal Choice

The consumers valuation of the two goods equals the markets valuation.

Changes in Income Affect Consumer Choices

An increase in income shifts the budget constraint outward. The consumer is able to choose a better combination of goods on a higher indifference curve.

Changes in Income Affect Consumer Choices


Quantity of Pepsi

Quantity of Pizza

Changes in Income Affect Consumer Choices


Quantity of Pepsi

I1 0 Quantity of Pizza

Changes in Income Affect Consumer Choices


Quantity of Pepsi

I1 0 Quantity of Pizza

Changes in Income Affect Consumer Choices


Quantity of Pepsi New budget constraint

I1 0 Quantity of Pizza

Changes in Income Affect Consumer Choices


Quantity of Pepsi New budget constraint

I2

I1 0 Quantity of Pizza

Changes in Income Affect Consumer Choices


Quantity of Pepsi New budget constraint

New optimum

I2

I1 0 Quantity of Pizza

Changes in Income Affect Consumer Choices


Quantity of Pepsi New budget constraint 1. An increase in income shifts the budget constraint outward New optimum

I2

I1 0 Quantity of Pizza

Changes in Income Affect Consumer Choices


Quantity of Pepsi New budget constraint 1. An increase in income shifts the budget constraint outward New optimum

I2

I1 0 2. raising pizza consumption Quantity of Pizza

Changes in Income Affect Consumer Choices


Quantity of Pepsi New budget constraint 1. An increase in income shifts the budget constraint outward New optimum 3. and Pepsi consumption. I2

I1 0 2. raising pizza consumption Quantity of Pizza

Normal versus Inferior Goods

If a consumer buys more of a good when his or her income rises, the good is called a normal good. If a consumer buys less of a good when his or her income rises, the good is called an inferior good.

An Inferior Good
Quantity of Pepsi

Quantity of Pizza

An Inferior Good
Quantity of Pepsi

I1 0 Quantity of Pizza

An Inferior Good
Quantity of Pepsi

Initial budget constraint I1 0 Quantity of Pizza

An Inferior Good
Quantity of Pepsi

Initial optimum

Initial budget constraint I1 0 Quantity of Pizza

An Inferior Good
Quantity of Pepsi New budget constraint

Initial optimum

Initial budget constraint I1 0 Quantity of Pizza

An Inferior Good
Quantity of Pepsi New budget constraint

Initial optimum

Initial budget constraint I1 0 I2 Quantity of Pizza

An Inferior Good
Quantity of Pepsi New budget constraint

Initial optimum New optimum Initial budget constraint I1 0 I2 Quantity of Pizza

An Inferior Good
Quantity of Pepsi New budget constraint

Initial optimum

1. When an increase in income shifts the budget constraint outward...

New optimum Initial budget constraint I1 0 I2 Quantity of Pizza

An Inferior Good
Quantity of Pepsi New budget constraint

Initial optimum

1. When an increase in income shifts the budget constraint outward...

New optimum Initial budget constraint I1 0 2. ... pizza consumption rises, making pizza a normal good... I2 Quantity of Pizza

An Inferior Good
Quantity of Pepsi New budget constraint

3. ... but Pepsi consumption falls, making Pepsi an inferior good.


Initial budget constraint

Initial optimum

1. When an increase in income shifts the budget constraint outward...

New optimum

I1 0

I2 Quantity of Pizza

2. ... pizza consumption rises, making pizza a normal good...

Changes in Prices Affect Consumer Choices

A fall in the price of any good rotates the budget constraint outward and changes the slope of the budget constraint.

Changes in Prices Affect Consumer Choices


Quantity of Pepsi

Quantity of Pizza

Changes in Prices Affect Consumer Choices


Quantity of Pepsi

500

I1 0 100 Quantity of Pizza

Changes in Prices Affect Consumer Choices


Quantity of Pepsi

500

Initial budget constraint 0

I1 100 Quantity of Pizza

Changes in Prices Affect Consumer Choices


Quantity of Pepsi

500
Initial optimum I1 100 Quantity of Pizza

Initial budget constraint 0

Changes in Prices Affect Consumer Choices


Quantity of Pepsi

500

1. A fall in the price of Pepsi rotates the budget constraint outward

Initial budget constraint 0

I1 100 Quantity of Pizza

Changes in Prices Affect Consumer Choices


Quantity of Pepsi 1,000 New budget constraint

500

1. A fall in the price of Pepsi rotates the budget constraint outward

Initial budget constraint 0

I1 100 Quantity of Pizza

Changes in Prices Affect Consumer Choices


Quantity of Pepsi 1,000 New budget constraint

500

1. A fall in the price of Pepsi rotates the budget constraint outward

Initial budget constraint 0

I1 100

I2 Quantity of Pizza

Changes in Prices Affect Consumer Choices


Quantity of Pepsi 1,000 New budget constraint

New optimum

500

1. A fall in the price of Pepsi rotates the budget constraint outward

Initial budget constraint 0

I1 100

I2 Quantity of Pizza

Changes in Prices Affect Consumer Choices


Quantity of Pepsi 1,000 New budget constraint

New optimum

500

1. A fall in the price of Pepsi rotates the budget constraint outward

Initial budget constraint 0

I1

I2

Quantity of Pizza 100 2. reducing pizza consumption

Changes in Prices Affect Consumer Choices


Quantity of Pepsi 1,000 New budget constraint

New optimum

500
3. and raising Pepsi consumption. Initial budget constraint 0 I1

1. A fall in the price of Pepsi rotates the budget constraint outward

I2

Quantity of Pizza 100 2. reducing pizza consumption

Income and Substitution Effects

A price change has two effects on consumption. An income effect A substitution effect

The Income Effect

The income effect is the change in consumption that results when a price change moves the consumer to a higher or lower indifference curve. The consumer is... ...worse off when prices increase. ...better off when prices decrease.

The Substitution Effect

The substitution effect is the change in consumption that results when a price change moves the consumer along an indifference curve to a point with a different marginal rate of substitution.

The Substitution Effect

When the price of a good increases, the amount of other goods that must be given up increases.

A Change in Price: Substitution Effect

A price change first causes the consumer to move from one point on a indifference curve to another on the same curve. Illustrated by movement from point A to point B.

A Change in Price: Income Effect

After moving from one point to another on the same curve, the consumer will move to another indifference curve. Illustrated by movement from point B to point C.

Income and Substitution Effects


Quantity of Pepsi

Quantity of Pizza

Income and Substitution Effects


Quantity of Pepsi

Initial budget constraint


0

I1 Quantity of Pizza

Income and Substitution Effects


Quantity of Pepsi

Initial optimum A

Initial budget constraint


0

I1 Quantity of Pizza

Income and Substitution Effects


Quantity of Pepsi

Initial optimum A

Initial budget constraint


0

I1 Quantity of Pizza

Income and Substitution Effects


Quantity of Pepsi

B A

Initial optimum

Initial budget constraint


0

I1 Quantity of Pizza

Income and Substitution Effects


Quantity of Pepsi

B Substitution effect A

Initial optimum

Initial budget constraint


0 Substitution effect

I1 Quantity of Pizza

Income and Substitution Effects


Quantity of Pepsi

New budget constraint

B Substitution effect A

Initial optimum

Initial budget constraint


0 Substitution effect

I1 Quantity of Pizza

Income and Substitution Effects


Quantity of Pepsi

New budget constraint

B Substitution effect A

Initial optimum

Initial budget constraint


0 Substitution effect

I1 Quantity of Pizza

Income and Substitution Effects


Quantity of Pepsi

New budget constraint

B Substitution effect A

Initial optimum

Initial budget constraint


0 Substitution effect

I2 I1 Quantity of Pizza

Income and Substitution Effects


Quantity of Pepsi

New budget constraint

C New optimum B Substitution effect A I2 I1 0 Substitution effect Quantity of Pizza Initial optimum

Initial budget constraint

Income and Substitution Effects


Quantity of Pepsi

New budget constraint

Income effect Substitution effect

C New optimum B A I2 I1 0 Substitution effect Income effect Quantity of Pizza Initial optimum

Initial budget constraint

How do wages affect labour supply?

If the substitution effect is greater than the income effect for the worker, he or she works more. If income effect is greater than the substitution effect, he or she works less.

Conclusion

A consumers budget constraint shows the possible combinations of different goods he or she can buy given his or her income and the prices of the goods. Indifference curves represent a consumers combinations of preferences between two goods.

Conclusion

Consumers prefer higher indifference curves to lower indifference curves. The consumer optimises by choosing the point on his budget constraint that lies on the highest indifference curve.

Conclusion

Income effect is the change in consumption that arises because a lower price makes the consumer better off. Substitution effect is the change in consumption that arises because a price change encourages greater consumption of the good that has become relatively cheaper.

Conclusion

Income effect is reflected by the movement from a lower to a higher indifference curve. Substitution effect is reflected by a movement along an indifference curve to a point with a different slope.

Exercise

Q.1. Illustrate properties of an indifference curve with help of diagrams. Q.2. Draw the indifference curves: (a). between perfect substitutes like 250 ml Pepsi bottles and 1 litre Pepsi bottles. (b). between perfect complementary like left shoe and right shoe. Q.3. Illustrate income effect for normal and inferior goods (Pizza and Pepsi) with a diagram.

Harcourt

Вам также может понравиться